View original document

The full text on this page is automatically extracted from the file linked above and may contain errors and inconsistencies.

FRBSF

WEEKLY LETTER

December 6, 1985

Measuring the Dollar's Strength
Ever since the adoption of floating exchange rates
in 1973, the value of the dollar relative to other
currencies has been the subject of much discussion. In recent years, the strong dollar has been
blamed for the decline in the competitiveness of
u.s. products, which, in turn, has engendered a
wave of protectionist sentiment in the United
States. By contrast, the weak dollar of the late
1970s was the cause of much resentment abroad.
Clearly, the exchange value of the dollar is a matter
of worldwide concern.
Discussions of the dollar's value assume the existence of an accurate measure of changes in its
strength. While such a measure may exist for comparing the dollar to a particular currency, it is much
more difficult to derive when dealing with several
currencies at once. If the dollar appreciates one
percent in relation to the japanese yen, but depreciates one percent in relation to the German
mark, has the dollar on balance strengthened or
weakened? To answer this question, we need
some means of determining the relative importance to the U.S. of changes in the value of the
japanese yen in comparison to changes in the German mark. Specifically, we need some criteria for
weighting the different exchange rates in order to
obtain an appropriate average value of the U.s.
dollar. The resulting measure is known as the effective exchange rate.

involves the selection of the currencies to be
included in the "basket" and the assignment of
weights to the individual exchange rates.
On selecting currencies to be included in the
index, it might appear that more currencies would
make the index more meaningful. In the extreme,
one might ask, why not include all currencies?
Aside from the cost involved in keeping track of a
large number of exchange rates, there are at least
two reasons that a more selective approach is
preferable. First, in the case of certain primary commodities, the world pricl::!s of which are determined
by producers' cartels unrelated to domestic costs
of production, changes in the exchange value of
the primary producing countries' currencies have
little impact on the international competitiveness
of u.s. goods and services. A prime example is
crude petroleum. Because its world price is quoted
in U.s. dollars, a depreciation of theSaudian riyal,
for instance, against the dollar would have no
effect onthe U.S. dollar price of crude petroleum.

This Letterwill discuss the principal indices of
effective exchange rates in use and how each is
constructed. Ultimately, the value of an index must
depend on its empirical usefulness. judging from
that criterion, there is little evidence to suggest
that anyone index is the best.

Second, very large depreciations in the currencies
of a number of countries, e.g., many Latin American nations, against the U.S. dollar have occurred
because of high inflation rates in those countries.
These large depreciations have a smaller effect on
the international competitiveness of u.s. goods
and services than might be suggested by their
importance in U.s. or world trade. In the ideal case,
this situation argues for calculating an index of real
exchange rates - Le., exchange rate changes
adjusted for relative changes in respective national
price levels. However, a much simpler method is to
exclude those countries known to have high inflation.

Index construction
An effective exchange rate index is essentially a
price index. As with all price indices, it measures
the weighted average level of the prices of a
basket of goods in different periods relative to that
in a base period. The "basket" in this case is a collection of selected currencies, the prices of which
are stable in terms of the U.s. dollar. Thus, the construction of an effective exchange rate index

The selection of currencies is inseparably related to
the assignment of weights to individual exchange
rates. For an effective exchange rate index to
reflect changes in the international competitiveness of U.S. goods and services caused by
exchange rate changes, the criteria for currency
selection and weight assignment must take into
accountthe relative importance of the respective
countries' products in both the U.s. export market

FRBSF
and in U.s. marketsthat compete with imports.
Broadly speaking, there are three approaches to
weighting: bilateral trade weights, multilateral
trade weights, and model simulation weights.

Bilateral trade weights
The method of bilateral trade weights selects those
countries with which the United States has the
largest total trade (value of exports plus imports)
and assigns weights to the dollar exchange rates of
their currencies in proportion to their shares in the
U.S. bilateral total trade during a base period. The
approach is based on the considerations that these
weights measure the respective countries'relative
importance to total U.S. foreign trade during the
base period, and that the relative effects of
individual exchange rate changes on u.s. output,
employment/and prices should bein rough proportion totheir weights during the same period.
A problem with this approach is thatthe focus on
bilateral trade does not take into consideration
competition in "third" markets - i.e., markets outsidethe U.S. and the foreign countries included in
the index. For instance,although Sweden and the
United States trade relatively little with each other,
they are both major participants in the world
marketfor telecommunications equipment. A depreciation in the Swedish kronor in relation to the
u.s. dollar therefore may have significant effects on
the u.s. trade balance by affecting U.s.competitiveness in third markets, such as the United
Kingdom. A bilateral trade-weighted index, which
focuses on the importance of u.s. trade with
Sweden within the context of total U.s. foreign
trade, would not capture this effect-Neither does it
consider the relative sensitivity of u.s. exports and
imports to changes in the different exchange rates.

Multilateral trade weights
To emphasize the significance of the effects of
exchange rate changes on a country's trade competitiveness in the world market (including the
third markets), the multilateral approach assigns
weights according to each country's share in total
world trade during a base period. The presumption
is that the larger a country's share in world trade,
the more its products compete with other nations'
products. An index so constructed emphasizes
effects on world competitiveness, rather than
those on the domestic economy.

Theweakness of multilateral trade-weighting is
that it cannot account for trading patterns specific
to a country. For example, the multilateral weighting scheme implicitly assumes that if the U.S. currency depreciated with respect to the Canadian
dollar and thereby reduced the demand for automobile imports from Canada, automobiles from
other major trading countries such as Italy would
act as an important substitute and dampen the favorable effects on the U.S. trade balance. The
weighting neglects that Canadian automobile
exports to the u.s. are not easily replaced by Italian
automobiles. Multilateral weighting would tend to
overstate the importance of Italy to the U.S. trade
balance by focusing exclusively on the size of
Italy's external sector without regard to the specific
products traded. Moreover, like bilateral tradeweighting, it too does not consider the market
responsiveness of u.s. trade to changes in different
exchange rates.

Model simulation weights
The model simulation approach seeks to account
for the relative sensitivity of U.S. foreign trade to
changes in different exchange rates by explicitly
modeling the effects of exchange rate changes on
both the demand and supply of U.S. exports and
imports and by distinguishing among commodity
groups and major trading partners.
By considering supply responsiveness, the
approach includes the effects of domestic price
changes that follow exchange rate changes. And
by explicitly modeling price competition among
various countries' products in different regions, it
encompasses both the "own-markets" and the
"third markets" effects. The interaction of all these
effects is used to simulate the impact of a change
in a country's exchange rate on the u.s. trade bal"
ance. The impact, in turn, determines the weight
assigned to the country's currency in calculating an
index of the effective exchange rate for the u.s.
dollar.
This approach obviously requires the construction
of very large econometric models of world trade.
The International Monetary Fund's (IMF)
Multilateral Exchange Rate Model (MERM), for instance, contains 2,400 product demand functions.
It serves as the basis for the IMF's indices of the
effective exchange rates of its member countries'

Effective Exchange Rate of the Dollar
1973=100

165
Federal Reserve Board
(Multi-lateral trade-weighted)

160
155
150
145
140
135
130
125
120
115
110

L:.L.J...J....L..L...L-.L....ww...J.....L.LL...L.J....L.l-l-L.L..L.L...L.J....J....J.....wl-W

JFMAMJJASONDJFMAMJJASONDJFMAMJJ

1983

1984

1985

currencies. Although the approach in concept is
more general than either the bilateral and the
multilateral trade-weighted approaches, its
application has required simplifying assumptions
about the demand for and supply of u.s. exports
and imports that are not necessarily less arbitrary
than those underlying either of the other two
approaches.

Comparison of the results
Each of the three approaches has been used in
widely cited indices: the bilateral approach by the
Morgan Guaranty Trust Co., the multilateral
approach by the Federal Reserve Board (FRB), and
. the model-simulation approach by the IMF, (See
Chart.) All three use only the exchange rates of
industrial countries. Because the countries included
differ from case to case, the resulting weights are
not strictly comparable. However, on the whole,
the Morgan and the IMF indices forthe U.S. dollar
both assign considerably larger weights to Canada
and japan (major u.s. trading partners) than the FRB
index, which gives the largest weights to Germany
and japan (the largest world trading nations outside the U.s.)
How do these differences in weights and ran kings
affect the resulting indices? A comp~rison of the
movement of the indices since 1976 reveals the
following:

larger) than the bilateral or the IMF index. Thus, we
may infer that the multilateral index assigns a larger
weight to currencies that fluctuated relatively
more in relation to the u.s. dollar. In particular,
both the bilateral and the IMF indices assign larger
weights to the currencies of Canada and japan,
whose value in relation to the U.S. dollar has been
comparatively stable. Because the German mark
has weakened considerably with respect to the
dollar, its larger weight in the FRB index accounts
for the stronger recorded rise in the dollar under
that approach.
2. The correlation coefficients among the three
indices all exceed 99 percent, although the
bilateral Morgan and IMF indices were more
closely correlated to each other than they were to
the FRB index. The close correlation indicates that,
notwithstanding differences in average levels, as
well as in the size of the swings, all indices tended
to move in the same direction. It also implies that
although the indices represent differenttheoretical
approaches, the differences do not matter much in
practice as long as the user does not switch among
indices indiscriminately.

Conclusion
The three approaches described in this article
emphasize different criteria for constructing an
index of the U.S. dollar's effective exchange rate.
Although the model-simulation approach is more
general in concept, its application also involves
many arbitrary assumptions. Moreover, for the
years since 1980, the movements of an index using
this approach have been very close to those
obtained from the much simplerbilateral tradeweighted approach. Ultimately, the usefulness of
an effective exchange rate index is its ability to
explain changes in other economic variables (such
as exports, imports, output, prices). The close correlations among the indices reviewed here imply
that it makes little difference which index is used,
as long as it is used consistently. Each index, based
on a differentmethod of weighting, should explain
economic activities just as well.

Ramon Moreno and Hang-Sheng Cheng,
Economist and Vice President,
International Studies

1. The multilateral trade index employed by the
FRB shows wider swings (its standard deviation is

Opinions expressed in this newsletter do not necessarily reflect the views of the management of the Federal Reserve Bank of San
Francisco, or of the Board of Governors of the Federal Reserve System.
Editorial comments may be addressed to the editor (Gregory Tong) or to the author .... Free copies of Federal Reserve publications
can be obtained from the Public Information Department, Federal Reserve Bank of San Francisco, P.O. Box 7702, San Francisco
94120. Phone (415) 974-2246.

uo~6U!4S0m

040PI

!!omoH

4o~n

O!UJO~!I0)

U060JO
ouoz!J~

0pOA0U
o}jsol~

O)SI)UOJ::J UOS

JO

~uo8

al\Jasa~ IOJapa::J

~uaw~Jodaa lpJOaSa~
BANKING DATA-TWELFTH FEDERAL RESERVE DISTRICT
(Dollar amounts in millions)

Selected Assets and Liabilities
Large Commercial Banks
Loans, Leases and Investments 1 2
Loans and Leases 1 6
Commercial and Industrial
Real estate
Loans to Individuals
Leases
U.S. Treasury and Agency Securities 2
Other Securities 2
Total Deposits
Demand Deposits
Demand Deposits Adjusted 3
Other Transaction Balances4
Total Non-Transaction Balances 6
Money Market Deposit
Accounts-Total
Time Deposits in Amounts of
$100,000 or more
Other Liabilities for Borrowed MoneyS

Two Week Averages
of Daily Figures

Amount
Outstanding
11/13/85

197,229
178,423
51,203
65,572
37,814
5,398
11,602
7,204
202,863
50,393
31,795
14,428
138,042

Change
from
11/6/85

-

45,769
38,552
24,142
Period ended
11/4/85

Change from 11/14/84
Dollar
Percent?

81
42
102
125
31
4
176
52
1,343
1,432
1,492
187
97

-

195

-

10,179
9,899
985
4,015
7,100
333
34
248
10,569
4,653
2,258
1,963
3,952
6,431

-

8
589

2,397
1,270

Period ended
10/21/85

Reserve Position, All Reporting Banks
Excess Reserves (+ )/Deficiency (-)
Borrowings
Net free reserves (+ )/Net borrowed( ~)

25
17
8

52
54
2

1 Includes loss reserves, unearned income, excludes interbank loans
2

3
4
5
6
7

-

Excludes trading account securities
Excludes U.s. governmentand depository institution deposits and cash items
ATS, NOW, Super NOW and savings accounts with telephone transfers
Includes borrowing via FRB, TI&L notes, Fed Funds, RPs and other sources
Includes items not shown separately
Annualized percent change

5.4
5.8
1.8
6.5
23.1
6.5
0.2
3.5
5.4
10.1
7.6
15.7
2.9
16.3

-

5.8
5.5