View original document

The full text on this page is automatically extracted from the file linked above and may contain errors and inconsistencies.

lPJ.':9;;:§,<E;$\lfdb

Cl::lTI\
ft

, §@lill
January 28, 1983

How l o w Can Interest RatesBe Pushed?
The U.S. economy is in the worst recession
in 40 years. While the broadesteconomic
measure, real Gross National Product, hit its
low point for this recessionin the first quarter
of 1982, there has been little sustained
recovery since then. As a result of this
anemic economic performance the unemployment rate rosethroughout 1982 and
stood at 10.8 percent in December,the highest level since 1941.
But in spite of the depressedstateof the
economy, there were some encouraging
signs. These consisted largely of the sharp
drop in interest ratessince the middleof 1982
that subsequentlyspurred a strong recovery
in the two previously most depressedindustries-housing and automobiles. The
economic forecasting fraternity is virtually
unanimous in expecting 1983 to be better
than 1982. What can the FederalReserve
do to aid an economic recovery?

Fedpolicy issues
The key policy issuesnow facing the Federal
Reserveare two: whether interest rateshave
declined sufficiently to provide for a sustainable recovery in real output, and whether the
recent surge in M1 hasbeen sufficiently large
to create concern about reigniting future
inflation. With respectto the second issue,
the unexpected collapse in the velocity of M1
in 1982 (some 5 percent below its originally
forecasted value) and, more recently, the
wave of interest rate deregulation hascalled
into question the usefulnessof M1 as a guide.
to pol icy, at least through the first half of
1983. With M1, the FederalReserve's
primary monetary guideline temporarily
"out of order", the major focus of policy must
be directed toward the broader monetary
aggregatesand/or interest rates.This Weekly
wi II focus on interest rates.
In evaluating the effect of interestrateson the
economy, one must consider not only the
market rate but the real interestrate. This is

the market interest rate adjustedfor the expected rate of inflation. Long-terminterest
rates playa key role in influencing the
economy, and they probably playa more
significant role than short-term interestrates.
But, in this Weekly, we will (ocus on shortterm interest ratesfor two reasons.First,the
Federal Reserve'sinstrumentsof monetary control, the discount rate and open market
operations, have their major impact on shortterm interest rates.The FederalReservehas
I ittle or no direct impact on long-term interest
rates, which are dependent primarily on the
productivity of capital and long-run inflation
expectations, Second, it is easier to measure

real interest rates in the short-termmarket
than in the long-term market becauseshortrun inflation expectations are closely related
to the most recent actual inflation rate, while
long-run inflation expectations(over the next
five to ten years)are not necessarilyrelatedto
past inflation.
One reasonablemeasureof the real shortterm interest rate is-thedifference between
the market interest rate and the inflation rate.
In Chart I, we compared the 3-month Treasury bill rate and the inflation rate (measured
on a 12-month basis).SinceSeptember1982,
the Treasurybill rate has averagedclose to 8
percent and the inflation rate 5% percent,
giving a risk-freereal short-term interest rate
of about 2V, percent. This is down substantially from the Treasury bill rate of as recent
a month asJune 1982 when it was 12% percent. Althat time, the inflation rate was about
6 percent and therefore the risk-free real
short-term interestrate was about 6% percent. Indeed, in the 1% yearsthrough June
1982, the real Treasurybill rate had been
extraordinarily high, in the 5-7 percent range,
and was a major causeof the weaknessin the
economy in 1981 and 1982.

Alternativeviews
Should, then, the Federal Reserveattempt to
push the real short-term interest ratesdown

If If©\!ill<Cli

(G)

Opinions expressed in this newsletter do not
necessarilv reflect the views of the management
of the Federal Reserve Bank of San Franc'isco,
or of the Board of Governors of th" Federal

Reserve SYstem.
between 1955 and 1979. From 1 979-1 983, it
rose from 21 percent to 25 percent. The most
recent rise is partly due to the relatively
weak economy. However, even if G N P grew
strongly between now and 1 985 the spending share is expected to decline only modestly. The reason is that in spite of public
perceptions to the contrary, the Reagan
administration did not reduce the trend in
government spending; it only changed the
mix of spending. Thus, with the continued
rise in the ratio of government spending to
GN P, the cost to the economy of financing
government has continued to rise.

further to stimulate growth? There are two
approaches to answering this question. The
first is that, given the depths of the recession,
we should allow real interest rates to become
negative, that is, market interest rates should
be pushed below the inflation rate to encourage a recovery. Once the economy had
started to show a sustained recovery, the appropriate policy would be to raise the interest
rate above the inflation rate to ensure thatthe
growth in aggregate demand was not excessive, that is, did not reignite inflation.
Experience indicates that this flexible approach to interest rates is particularly important. In the 1 974-75 recession, the Treasury
bill rate fell below the inflation rate and the
real interest rate was minus 2-3 percent. FollOWing the 1 974-75 recession, however, the
Treasury-bill rate never rose above the inflation rate, and the real interest rate was kept
close to zero for four years (mid-1 975 to mid1 979) as the economy grew rapidly and
added 11 million people to the employment
roles. (The reluctance to raise the real interest
rate in this expansion period was probably
due to the unemployment rate, which remained well above 6 percent.)

There are only three ways in which increased
government spending can be financed: first,
by higher tax receipts; second, by the in,
creased issuance of government bonds,
which the public can be induced to hold only
with higher real interest rates; and third, by
printing money, which i ncreasesthe inflation
rate. Cutting taxes without cutting government spend ing does not reduce the cost of the
government, it merely redistributes it from
one source of financing to another.
In the 1 960 s, the rise in the trend of government spending was financed by tax revenues
generated by a rapidly growing real economy. In the period from 1 960-69, we had
the longest continuous period of economic
expansion in our history (real growth averaged 4.3 percent per year) and this generated
tax receipts that financed the growth in
government spending even when tax rates
were reduced.

The alternative approach argues that we
cannot now let interest rates fall much below
current levels because government deficits
are more dangerous than they were in
1 974-75. The recent deficits require a higher
real interest rate to finance. In 1 974-75,
government deficits were largely induced
by the business cycle. In that recession, the
decline in tax receipts increased the deficit,
while the subsequent economic expansion
increased receipts and reduced the deficit.
In 1 982-83, the business cycle deficit has,
superimposed on it, a structural deficit that
will not disappear when the economy and tax
receipts increase.

In the 1970s, the continued growth in government spending as a share of GN P was
financed by a higher inflation rate. Real GN P
did not grow very rapidly (averaging 2.9 percent per year), but nominal income, because
of inflation, grew at an average rate of 1 0
percent per year, which pushed most people
into higher tax brackets. This form of "inflation tax" financed the increased government
spending.

Roleof deficits
To understand this consideration, it is useful
to review the history of government spending
and structural deficits (Chart 2). The government spending share of GN P moved gradually from about 1 7 percent to 21 percent

In the 1 980s the Reagan administration has
cut tax rates sufficiently to stop "bracket
2

Chart 1

Percent

Chart 2

16
14

Percent

'·iV.
...

.I

Treasury bill

12

.

10

30

.

GovernmentSpending
as Share 01<?NP

25

\

20
15

\

10

Deficit as Share

of GNP

5
0
4

o'1973\974

'1976I

\978 '

'1980!

-5
1955

'1982'

"'"

1965

1970

1975

1980

1985

creep" (and thus tax receiptsas a percentage
of GNP will stabilize around 20 flercent in
1984, down modestly from 20.5 percent in
1980). The Federal Reservehas cut the inflation rate from over 10 percent in 1980 to 5
percent in 1982. If thesegains are not to be
reversed, the only method left of financing
the continued rise in govemment spendingas
a share of GNP is to increasethe govemment
issuing of bonds. This is the primary sourceof
what has been called the structuraldeficits. In
the Reaganadministration, it looks as if the
deficits will averageclose to 5 percent of
GNP, the highest in our history outside of a
major war.

Conclusion
This country has had no experiencewith
deficits of this size, and therefore,no clear
idea of how high real interestratesmustgo to
finance them. In the 1960s the Treasurybill
rate was approximately 1 to 1h percent
above the inflation rate, which suggeststhat
a real interest rate of 1-1h percentwas necessary to fi nance the much lower deficits that
accrued in those years without inflation
financing. The current real Treasurybill rate
of 2 h percent may be about as low as that
interest rate can go and still finance the much
larger deficits that are currently being produced without inflation financing.

Deficits and savings
To focus more closely on the effectsof deficits
on interestratesand financial markets, we
must look at deficits as a shareof net private
savingsof the economy. Net private savings
equals grossprivate savingslessdepreciation
allowances to maintain the existing capital
stock. In the 1960s, the deficit averaged
about 10 percent of net private savings,leaving 90 percent available for private use. In the
1970s,the deficits varied from year to year,
but averagedjust over 20 percent of net private savings.In 1982, deficits consumed 80
percent of net private savings.

While this analysis is rather speculative,one
thing is clear, further reductions in short-term
interest rates would require the Federal
Reserveto increase the rate of growth of the
money supply. The San FranciscoBank's
money market model estimatesthat for every
1 percent reduction in interestrates,M1 will
need to grow 5 percent faster(atannual rates)
than it otherwise would have over the next
three months.
If the financial markets interpret further
reductions in short-term interestratesas an
attempt by the Fed indirectly to print money
to finance the deficit, long-run inflation
expectations and long-term interestratesmay
rise. Should policymakers decide that the
recession is suffiCiently severeto warrant
further reductions in short-term interestrates,
they should consider the effect it would have
on the long-term bond markets.A rise in
long-term interest rates is a signal that the
financial markets perceive monetary policy
to be too easy.

Most analystsdo not expect things to change
significantly in the yearsahead. In 1983, the
cashdeficitwill consumebetween 70 and 90
percent of net savings.The range depends
upon whether the tax incentives for savings
substantially increasesavingsor not. By
1985, the deficit is not expected to decline
significantly, but the economy is assumedto
grow rapidly, reducing the deficit's shareof •
net private savingsto between 60 and 70
percent.

Michael Keran

3

S S"' O .LSl:lI:l

!!E'Ml?H

41?ln• uoSaJO• epeA<3N
• oyepl
E'!UJoJ!leJ • euozpv • e>jSl?JV

Jr
'Mle::>
IO:>spUI?J:I
lIeS
lS" 'ON
OIVd39VlS Od's-n
llVWSS VUlS BU
OUB09Bd

:tJ1\lJ@\\lill:tJ
ollW!<dl@<1
J] '"lI;:))ollW!@\B@(ill

BANKINGDATA-TWELFTHFEDERAL
RESERVE
DISTRICT
(Dollar amountsin millions)

SelectedAssetsand Liabilities
large Commercial8anks
Loans(gross,adjusted)
andinvestments*
loans(gross,adjusted)- total#
Commercialand industrial
Realestate

loansto individuals
Securitiesloans
U.S.Treasury
securities*
Othersecurities"
Demanddeposits- total#
Demanddeposits- adjusted
Savingsdeposits- total
Time deposfts,- total#
Individuals,part.& corp.
(large negotiableCO's)
WeeklyAverages
of Daily Figures
MemberBankReserve
Position
ExcessReserves(+ )/Deficiency (-)
Borrowings

Netfreereserves
(+ l/Net borrowed(
-)
-*

Amount
Outstanding
1/12/83
163,305
142,480
57,586
23,973
2,597
7,395
13,430
41,153
28,951
53,395
82,186
72,656
28,215

Change
from
1/5/83

Changefrom

yearago
Dollar

-1,137
-1,076
- 907
1
44
- 154
- 9
52
-3,689
-1,178
3,577
-2,638
-2,514
- 926

-

Percent

6,124
6,544
3,124
1,317
288
515
1,550
1,970
844
1,070
22,247
7,714
8,265
7,366

3.9
4.8
7.5
2.3
1.2
24.7
26.5
12.8
2.0
3.6
71.4
8.6
10.2
20.7

-

-

Weekended

Weekended

Comparable

1/12/83

1/5/83

year-agoperiod

108
33
75

144
20
124

68
131
63

Excludes
tradingaccountsecurities.

# Includesitemsnotshownseparately.
Editorialcommentsmaybeaddressed
to theeditor(GregoryTong)or to theauthor.••• Freecopiesof this
andotherFederalReserve
publications
canbeobtainedbycallingor writingthePublicInformationSection,
FederalReserve
Bankof SanFrancisco,
P.O.80x 7702,SanFrancisco
94120. Phone(415)974 2246.
M