View original document

The full text on this page is automatically extracted from the file linked above and may contain errors and inconsistencies.

FRBSF

WEEKLY LETTER

Number 93-13, April 2, 1993

The Lonesome Twin
The first half of the 1980s saw the emergence of a
large federal budget deficit and an equally large
trade deficit. Indeed, the association between
them was so close that the two were popularly
labeled "twin deficits."
Economic theory suggests that this association
is likely when financial capital crosses international borders easily. Policies that produce a
larger budget deficit put temporary upward pressure on domestic interest rates, which in turn
induces net inflows of capital from abroad. These
inflows reduce the pressure on domestic interest
rates and cause the dollar to appreciate, which
in turn produces a "twin" trade deficit.
However, in the last half of the 1980s, the trade
deficit shrank almost to nothing even though
the federal budget deficit persisted. This Weekly
Letter explores the reasons for the appearance
and subsequent disappearance of this "twin"
trade deficit, and also argues that it is likely to
appear again in significant proportions.

Emergence of the "twin deficits"
The tax reductions and government spending
increases that were initiated in 1981, together
with the continuing growth of social insurance
outlays and the increase in interest on the national debt, caused the federal budget deficit to
rise sharply in the first half of the 1980s-from
$60 billion in 1980 to $135 billion in 1982 to
. $201 billion in 1986. Thus, by 1986 it amounted
to 5.5 percent of the net national product (NNP),
an increase of 3 percentage points from the start
of the decade. Since then it has ranged betwE:en
3 and 6 percent of NNP.
At first the rise in the budget deficit was paralleled by an increase in the trade deficit, which
jumped from $15 billion in 1980 to $132 billion
in 1986. This was equal to an increase of 2.9 percentage points of the net national product. But
by 1991 the trade deficit had shrunk to only a
shadow of its former self, at $22 billion.
While the budget deficit and the trade deficit are
thought of as "twins:' there is another deficit sibling to consider as well, namely, the deficit in net

foreign investment. Our net foreign investment
is the net amount of financial capital flowing to
foreign countries from the U.S. As an identity in
our balance of payments, net foreign investment
equals net exports plus unilateral transfer payments. Since transfer payments are relatively
small and change only slowly, the emergence of
the trade deficit implied a similar change in net
foreign investment.
Net foreign investment declined from a positive
balance equal to 0.2 percent of NNP in 1980
to a negative balance (that is, a net inflow offinancial capital from abroad) of 3.8 percentage
points in 1986. Up to this point, the increase in
the federal budget deficit was financed, either
directly or indirectly, entirely by borrowing from
abroad, with net foreign investment falling by
somewhat more than the increase in the budget
deficit. But by 1991 net foreign investment had
shifted from a large deficit to a small surplus.
Thus, both "twin deficits"-trade and net
foreign investment-disappeared in the late
1980s and early 1990s, while the budget deficit

persisted.

Relationships with national
saving and investment
The appearance and subsequent disappearance
of both the trade deficit and the deficit in net foreign investment is most easily analyzed in terms
of the overall balance between the nation's saving and investment. The amount of government
saving (dissaving) is measured by the amount of
the government's budgetary surplus (deficit). As
shown in Figure 1, saving by state and local governments, mostly for pension funds, has been
positive and fairly steady at about 1 percent of
the net national product. In contrast, federal government saving has shown both strong cyclical
and policy-induced fluctuations. As a percent of
NNP, federal government saving dropped sharply
in the 1974-1975, the 1980, and 1981-1982
recessions. But because of budgetary policy
changes, it has never fully recovered from those
lows. Net private saving (net of depreciation) by
individuals and corporations has displayed relatively little cyclical variation as a percent of NNp,
but has trended downward since the early 1970s.

FRBSF
Figure 1: Net National Saving
Percent
of NNP
H~

10

either significantly increasing net private saving
or decreasing net private domestic investment. In
fact, net private domestic investment rose in response to a business cycle upswing. The larger
budget deficit at first put upward pressure on
interest rates relative to foreign interest rates.
But by the mid-1980s the subsequent net inflows
of capital associated with the decline in net foreign investment both reduced the interest rate
differential (Figure 3) and put upward pressure
on the dollar.

u.s.

Figure 3: Real Bond Rates

5

Percent

10

o

i1

·5

Federal Gov't 1m
Ml
·
SaVlng
@!

74
77
80
83
86
89
92
Shaded areas are periods of recession, as dated by
the National Bureau of Economic Research.

o
-2
-4

Uncoupling the "twin deficits"

Percent
of NNP

rtf]

15

11
'..;. ·....11

10
5

~£~

t.rJ .. ~'
$;r"

:::;"

o
-5

74
77
80
83
86
89
92
Net foreign investment equals net exports of goods and
services plus unilateral transfer payments received
by the U.S.

4
2

Figure 2: Net National Investment

It

6

-10

National investment is made up of net private
domestic investment (also net of depreciation)
plus net foreign investment (Figure 2). Thus,
national saving can be either invested in domestic capital formation or invested abroad.
Moreover, national saving must always equal
national investment.

Net Private
Domestic
Investment

8

·10

In the first half of the 1980s, the policy-induced
reduction in government saving produced a similar decline in net foreign investment, without

To understand why the large deficits in the trade
balance and in net foreign investment disappeared while the budget deficit remained, it is
helpful to look at other elements of saving and
investment.
The sum of both state and local government saving and net private saving changed very little as a
percent of NNP after 1986 (Figure 1). In contrast,
net private domestic investment dropped sharply
(Figure 2). In fact, the decline as a percent of NNP.
after 1986 is almost a "mirror image" of the increase in net foreign investment. So the increase in
net foreign investment was clearly quite closely
associated with a similar decline in net private
domestic investment. But which caused which?
Increased net foreign investment could have
caused net private domestic investment to decline if, as a result of the large amount of previous capital inflows, foreign portfolios had
become saturated with doilar-denominated assets.
In that case, foreigners would have desired to accumulate fewer dollar-denominated assets than
before. This would have generated more net foreign investment, a lower dollar, and higher interest rates in the U.S. relative to those abroad. The
higher U.S. interest rates would have reduced net

private domestic investment. The trouble with
this hypothesis, however, is that it does not appear to be consistent with all the facts.
The differential between u.s. and foreign real
bond rates rose in the early 1980s as the budget
deficit generated a higher level of u.s. government borrowing (Figure 3). But then in the
mid-1980s the subsequent net inflows offoreign
capital reduced the interest rate differential to a
near-zero normal level. After the mid- 1980s the
differential between u.s. and foreign real bond
rates was quite stable, whereas a large shortfall of
foreign capital inflows would have tended to increase it significantly. So the behavior of interest
rates seems inconsistent with this hypothesis.
So does the behavior of the value of the dollar.
Although it declined sharply from 1984 to 1987,
this decline was produced by the decline in the
differential between u.S. and foreign real bond
rates, as well as by the sharp decline of oil prices
in 1986 (see Throop 1992). After 1987, the value
of the dollar changed very little, which isinconsistent with a growing aversion of foreign
investors to U.S. assets.
The alternative hypothesis-that a business
cycle-induced decline in net private domestic
investment caused an increase in net foreign investment-is more consistent with the evidence.
Net private domestic investment has a strong
cyclical component, which tends to cause significant changes in the other components of saving and investment. But private investment itself
is not strongly affected by these other components. As seen in Figure 2, net private domestic
investment dropped sharply as a percent of NNP
in the 1974-1975, 1980, and 1981-1982 recessions. Then in the most recent cycle it fell from
nearly 6 percent of NNP in 1988 to around 2
percent in 1991-1992.
This recent drop in net private domestic investment produced both a reduction in government
saving and an increase in net foreign investment.
As in previous recessions, government saving was
reduced as the recession lowered incomes and
tax receipts. Also as in previous cycles, net foreign investment rose because the decline in net
private domestic investment reduced the demand for domestic saving. Since financial capital
is highly mobile internationally, this decline in
the demand for domestic saving encouraged a

net outflow of financial capital from the u.S. with
only a small change in the interest rate differential. In other words, with fewer investment opportunities in the u.s. more capital flowed out
and less flowed in. As a result, netforeign investment and the trade balance strengthened in
concert with the decline in net private domestic
investment. This inverse association between net
private domestic investment and net foreign investment (and the trade balance) is evident in the
three previous recessions as well (see Figure 2).

Conclusion
In the early 1980s, a large u.s. trade deficit
and a net foreign investment deficit emerged as
"twins" of the large u.s. budget deficit. But by
1991 both had almost entirely disappeared,
though a large budget deficit remained.
The uncoupling of the other deficits from the
budget deficit was caused by the behavior of net
private domestic investment, which competes
with the government for private saving. An uncoupling occurred in the late 1980s because
private domestic investment dropped sharply,
as u.s. growth slowed and a recession followed.
This resulted in a decline in the private demand
for saving that exceeded a simultaneous drop
in government saving. So net capital outflows
increased, or net foreign investment rose. As a
result, the other deficits disappeared, while the
government deficit persisted.
The outlook is for a reemergence of the two other
deficits, however. As the economy continues to
recover from the 1991-1992 recession, private
domestic investment has already begun to rise as
a percent of the net national product; and this is
bringing with it a deterioration in net foreign investment. Furthermore, the Clinton administration's fiscal program would do little to diminish
the budget deficit in the near term. As a result,
even with a recovery of moderate proportions,
the deficits in net foreign investment and the
trade balance could come close to their highs
of 1986 in a few years.

Adrian w. Throop
Research Officer
Reference
Throop, Adrian W 1992. "The Dollar: Short-Run Volatility and Long-Run Adjustment!' Federal Reserve
Bank of San Francisco Weekly Letter (October 9).

Opinions expressed in this newsletter do not necessarily reflect the views of the management of the Federal Reserve Bank of
San Francisco, or of the Board of Governors of the Federal Reserve System.
Editorial comments may be addressed to the editor or to the author.... Free copies of Federal Reserve publications can be
obtained from the Public Information Department, Federal Reserve Dank of San Francisco, P.O. Box 7702, San Francisco 94120.
Phone (415) 974-2246, Fax (415) 974-3341.

~

'V

1%\
~

·S>jU! ueaqAos 4l!M
Jaded papAoa, uo palu~d

Ollt6 V)

'O:>SPUI?J:I UI?S

lOLL XOll'O'd

O)SPUOJj UOS

JO
'HIP:) 'O:lSPUPJJ UPS

aAJaSa~

ZSL 'ON llWMld
OIVd
l~V1S0d

~U08

IOJapaj

sn

11VW HVM )ll(}S

~uaw~Jodaa 4)JOaSa~

Index to Recent Issues of FRBSF Weekly Letter

DATE NUMBER TiTlE
10/9
10/16
10/23
10/30
11/6
11/13
11/20
11/27
12/4
12/11
12/25
1/1
1/8
1/22
1/29
2/5
2/12
2/19
2/26
3/5
3/12
3/19
3/26

92-35
92-36
92-37
92-38
92-39
92-40
92-41
92-42
92-43
92-44
92-45
93-01
93-02
93-03
93-04
93-05
93-06
93-07
93-08
93-09
93-10
93-11
93-12

AUTHOR

The Dollar: Short-Run Volatility and Long-Run Adjustment
The European Currency Crisis
Southern California Banking Blues
Would a New Monetary Aggregate Improve Policy?
Interest Rate Risk and Bank Capital Standards
NAFTA and
Banking
A Note of Caution on Early Bank Closure
Where's the Recovery?
.
Diamonds and Water: A Paradox Revisited
Sluggish Money Growth: japan's Recent Experience
Labor Market Structure and Monetary Policy
An Alternative Strategy for Monetary Policy
The Recession, the Recovery, and the Productivity Slowdown
Banking Turnaround
Competitive Forces and Profit Persistence in Banking
The Sources of the Growth Slowdown
GDP Fluctuations: Permanent or Temporary?
The Twelfth District Agricultural Outlook
Saving-Investment Linkages in the Pacific Basin
A Single Market for Europe?
Risks in the Swaps Market
On the Changing Composition of Bank Portfolios
Interest Rate Spreads as Indicators for Monetary Policy

u.s.

u.s.

Throop
Glick/Hutchison
Zimmerman
Motley
Neuberger
Laderman/Moreno
Levonian
Cromwell/Trenholme
Schmidt
Moreno/Kim
Huh
Motley/judd
Cogley
Zimmerman
Levonian
Motley
Moreno
Dean
Kim
Glick/Hutchison
Laderman
Neuberger
Huh

The FRBSF Weekly Letter appears on an abbreviated schedule in june, july, August, and December.