View original document

The full text on this page is automatically extracted from the file linked above and may contain errors and inconsistencies.

FRBSF

WEEKLY LETTER

Number 95-05, February 3, 1995

What Are the Lags in Monetary Policy?
The economist's adage about monetary policy
actions is that they affect the economy with "long
and variable" lags. This Letter considers some
empirical evidence on how long and how variable those lags may have been in the past. To the
extent that past effects will be similar to those today, such estimates may shed light on the magnitude and timing of the effects of the tightening of
monetary policy last year.
This Letter reviews empirical estimates from four
models that are based on particular theoretical
structures of the economy; in addition, I examine
estimates from a purely statistical model. All of
these estimates use movements in short-term
interest rates to identify the stance of monetary
policy. Such an identification is now widely accepted (for example, see any of the references
cited below), in part, because recent financial
innovation has reduced the reliability of traditional measures of the money supply to indicate
policy actions.
Overall, all the models appear to provide fairly
consistent evidence that a monetary tightening
or loosening has the greatest effect on the growth
of output during the first eight quarters, and that
this effect is fairly evenly distributed between the
first and second years. Nevertheless, it should be
stressed that there is substantial uncertainty associated with the models' estimates of the dynamic
response of output to any particular monetary
policy episode.

Structural model estimates
An estimate of the effect of a monetary policy
action on output can be easily obtained from
a structural macroeconometric model. Simply
measure the difference between two dynamic
simulations of the model-one with and one
without the policy action. This section examines
the responses of four different structural models: (1) the MPS model, which is maintained by
the staff of the Federal Reserve Board (see Mauskopf 1990); (2) the DRI model, which is a commercially available product (see Probyn and
Cole 1994); (3) the FAIR model, which is maintained at Yale University by Ray Fair (see Fair

1994); and (4) an FRBSF model, which was
developed at this Bank.
These four models vary considerably in size,
ranging from about 30 stochastic equations in the
FRBSF and FAIR models to almost 1,000 equations
in the DRI model. However, all of the models
specify the structure of the economy in fairly
similar traditional Keynesian terms. In each
model, the short-term interest rates most closely
associated with monetary policy actions are
linked to long-term interest rates via a backwardlooking term structure equation. Thus, changes
in short rates are assumed to change expectations
about future short rates only gradually; hence,
short rate changes become embedded with a
lag in long rate. These changes in long and short
nominal interest rates generally imply changes
in real rates as well, because wage and price expectations are assumed to adjust only sluggishly.
These interest rate movements also affect household financial wealth in the models because of
an arbitrage among bond, equity, and other asset
prices. In addition, for two of the models-MPS
and DRI-the foreign exchange rate also responds to interest rate movements.
In the models, these financial market repercussions of monetary policy actions affect all categories of real economic activity. Typically, inventory
investment is linked most closely to short rates,
business fixed investment and residential construction are linked to long rates, household
spending on durable goods depends on financial
wealth as well as interest rates, and net exports
are tied to the exchange rate. However, the response of production and real spending to the
changes in the financial environment is modeled
with a lag that reflects, for example, the delay
from new spending plans to new orders and contracts and finally to new construction and production. The length of this lag varies with the
category of spending but is typically at least several quarters in duration.
The first four lines of the table display the lagged
monetary policy responses of output in the structural models. The fifth line gives the average

FRBSF
Table 1
The Effect on GDP Growth of a 1 Percentage
Point Increase in Short-Term Interest Rates
(In Percentage Points)

1st year

2nd year

3rd year

Structural Models
MPS

-.20

-.70

-1.10

ORI

-.47

-.53

-.13

FAIR

-.24

-.25

+.03

FRBSF

-.55

-.19

+.04

Average

- .37

- .42

-.29

-.26

+.08

Nonstructural Model
VAR

-.64

response. Each line shows the estimated effect
on the four-quarter growth rates of output during
each of the first three years after a 1 percentage
point increase in short-term interest rates.
Overall, the responses of the models to a monetary shock are fairly similar during the first eight
quarters. Averaging across the models, the 1 percentage point increase in the short rate slows
output growth by about four-tenths of a percentage point in each of the succeeding two years.
Thus, two years after a tightening, the level of
real GDP is about three-quarters of a percent
lower than it would have been otherwise. The
average effect of a monetary shock on the growth
of output for these models is greatest during the
first eight quarters. However, the models do differ
significantly in describing the effect of a monetary shock past two years, with the MPS model
showing a further significant reduction in the
growth of output and the other models showing
little further response.

Nonstructural model estimates
In the last decade, most empirical research on
the dynamic response of output to monetary
policy has eschewed structural models. Instead,
researchers have investigated the effects of policy
using vector autoregressions (VARs), which are small, purely statistical models. These VARs typically contain no more than half a dozen variables and are constrl:Jcted simply by regressing
each variable, in turn, on all of the other vari-

abies. The VARs contain essentially no theoretical
economic structure, and, in particular, they take
no stand on the nature of a monetary transmission mechanism. However, VARs are particularly
adept at summarizing the dynamic correlations
found in the data; hence, they can provide useful
information on the response of output to movements in interest rates. (For an introduction and
references to the literature, see Balke and Emery
1994.)
The bottom row in the table gives the response of
output to a tightening of monetary policy as estimated from a VAR. (The VAR used is fairly typical
of those in the literature and contains four variables: real GOp' the GOP deflator, a commodity
price index, and the federal funds rate.) A 1 percentage point positive shock to short-term interest rates shaves about six-tenths of a percentage
point off the growth of GOP in- the first year after
the shock and another quarter of a percentage
point in the second year. The VAR's"overali response is broadly in line with the estimates from
the structural models; however, in the VAR, the
bulk of the impact on output growth occurs a bit
earlier than for the structural models.

Uncertainty about the estimates
The imprecision associated with the above numerical estimates should not be underestimated.
Uncertainty about the effect of policy arises because the specification of the model is not known
to be correct. At the very least, there is uncertainty about the appropriate variables to be included in the model as well as the appropriate
values of the parameters in the equations of the
model.
For example, to appreciate the degree of uncertainty surrounding the estimates in the table, we
can begin by considering the uncertainty in the
models' parameter estimates. Taking into account such model uncertainty for the VAR, a 90
percent confidence interval for the effect of the
policy shock on output growth during the first
four quarters is about half a percentage point in
size and ranges from -0.9 to -0.4 of a percentage point. In the second and third years after the
policy action, the ranges are even larger-about
six-tenths of a percentage point in size. Similar
confidence intervals incorporating parameter
uncertainty are harder to obtain for the structural
models' estimates. However, based on a related
investigation in Fair (1994), it appears likely that
such estimates also are plagued by about the
same amount of imprecision from parameter
uncertainty.

Assessing the effects of other types of model misspecification is more difficult. For the structural
models, some of this uncertainty can be gauged
from the range of estimates presented in the table.
For example, in the second year after the increase in interest rates, the four models give a
range of estimates of the effect on output growth
of about one-half of a percentage point in size.
Given that these models share a similar intellectual framework, this range should be viewed as
just a starting point regarding the effect of structural uncertainty.
For the VAR, one area of structural uncertainty
involves the number of lags of variables to be included in the equations. The VAR in the analysis
above used six lags. Letting the number of lags
vary from four to eight, the 90 percent confidence interval for the second-year effect on
growth is boosted in size to about eight-tenths of
a percentage point (including parameter uncertainty), while the first- and third-year confidence
intervals are little affected. However, some modest experimentation suggests that all of the confidence intervals would be enlarged by varying the
variables included or the estimation sample
period.

history from the models is in bond yields. The
term structure equations in the structural models,
which imply that long-term rates react with a
lag to changes in the short rate, are an important
element in the models' lagged output responses.
In contrast, during the past year, the actual increases in short rates have been matched contemporaneously and, at times, even have been
anticipated by equivalent increases in long rates.
This deviation from the models suggests caution
in relying on the structural model estimates.
For the VAR, there is a more subtle caveat. The
VAR output effects shown in the table are in response to a positive innovation in interest rates,
which is defined as an (exogenous) change in
rates that is not in response to changes in any
other variable. An endogenous change in interest
rates, that is, one which is typical of past changes
and is predictable, might well be followed by an
output path that was much different from the one
given in the table. Thus, any assessment of the
effect of recent pol icy on output with a VAR requires a decomposition of recent interest rate
increases into exogenous and endog~nous
changes. Such decompositions are modeldependent and are likely to be contentious.

The lags in recent policy
The level of short-term interest rates rose by
about 2Y2 percentage points during 1994 as a result of a monetary tightening. This increase was
fairly evenly distributed over the year. Can the
above results aid in assessing the timing of the effects of these policy actions? Taken at face value
and ignoring their imprecision, the model estimates suggest that as a rough average approximation, over half of the total effect of the increase in
rates will be felt in 1995, with the residual impact
fairly evenly distributed in 1994 and 1996. However, several important caveats are in order.
For the structural models, the applicability of
the results depends crucially on the validity of the
models' specifications. However, these models
may not be accurate guides to judging the timing
of the effects of the most recent policy tightening.
Perhaps the most significant departure of recent

Glenn Rudebusch
Research Officer

References
Balke, Nathan S., and Kenneth M. Emery. 1994. "Understanding the Price Puzzle;' Economic Review,
Federal Reserve Bank of Dallas (fourth quarter)
pp.15-26.
Fair, Ray. 1994. Testing Macroeconometric Models.
Cambridge, Mass.: Harvard University Press.
Mauskopf, Eileen. 1990. "The Transmission Channels
of Monetary Policy: How Have They Changed?"
Federal Reserve Bulletin (December) pp. 985-1008.
Probyn, Christopher, and David Cole. 1994. "The New
Macroeconomic Model:' DRJ/McGraw-HiI/
Review Uuly) pp. 39-49.

u.s.

Opinions expressed in this newsletter do not necessarily reflect the views of the management of the Federal Reserve Bank of
San Francisco, or of the Board of Governors of the Federal Reserve System.
Editorial comments may be addressed to the editor or to the author..•. Free copies of Federal Reserve publications can be
obtained from the Public Information Department, Federal Reserve Bank of San Francisco, P.O. Box 7702, San Francisco 94120.
Phone (415) 974-2246, Fax (415) 974-3341.

Research Department

Federal Reserve
Bank of
San Francisco
P.O. Box 7702
San Francisco, CA 94120

Printed on recy~led paper ~ ~
with soybean inKS.
'..:I ~

Index to Recent Issues of FRBSF Weekly Letter

DATE

NUMBER TITLE

AUTHOR

7/22
8/5
8/19
9/2
9/9
9/16
9/23
9/30
10/7
10/14
10/21
10/28
11/4
11/11
11/18
11/25
12/9
12/23
12130
1/6
1/13
1/20
1/27

94-26
94-27
94-28
94-29
94-30
94-31
94-32
94-33
94-34
94-35
94-36
94-37
94-38
94-39
94-40
94-41
94-42
94-43
94-44
95-01
95-02
95-03
95-04

Levonian
Walsh
Walsh
Throop
Sherwood-Call
Glick
Huh/Kim
Huh/Kim
Trehan
Laderman
Kasa
Zimmerman
Moreno
Gabriel
Kasa
Zimmerman
Booth/Chua
Mattey
Spiegel
Trehan
Parry
Levonian
Furlong/Zimmerman

Interstate Banking and Risk
A Primer on Monetary Policy Part I: Goals and Instruments
A Primer on Monetary Policy Part II: Targetsand Indicators
Linkages of National Interest Rates
Regional Income Divergence in the 1980s
Exchange Rate Arrangements in the Pacific Basin
How Bad is the "Bad Loan Problem" in japan?
Measuring the Cost of "Financial Repression"
The Recent Behavior of Interest Rates
Risk-Based Capital Requirements and Loan Growth
Growth and Government Policy: Lessons from Hong Kong and Singapore
Bank Business Lending Bounces Back
Explaining Asia's Low Inflation
Crises in the Thrift Industry and the Cost of Mortgage Credit
International Trade and u.s. Labor Market Trends
EU + Austria + Finland + Sweden + ?
TheDevelopment of Stock Markets in China
Effects of California Migration
Gradualism and Chinese Financial Reforms
The Credibility of Inflation Targets
A Look Back at Monetary Policy in 1994
Why Banking Isn't Declining
Economy Boosts Western Banking in '94

The FRBSF Weekly Letter appears on an abbreviated schedule in june, july, August, and December.