View original document

The full text on this page is automatically extracted from the file linked above and may contain errors and inconsistencies.

FRBSF

WEEKLY LETTER

May 4,1990

Japan's Experience
with Flexible Exchange Rates
Many expected the introduction of generalized
floating exchange rates in the early 1970s to
increase the degree to which national economies
would be insulated from foreign disturbances,
particularly foreign monetary disturbances. However, the subsequent high correlation among
output fluctuations in different countries has
called this assumption into question. At the same
time, it is commonplace to note that the nature of
the shocks the world economy faced in the 1970s
and 1980s departed from those faced in the
1950s and 1960s. This change in the nature of
the underlying disturbances may have played a
more important role than any apparent shortcomings in the flexible exchange regime.
To examine this possibility, this Letter focuses on
japan's experience under flexible exchange rates.
Among the major industrial economies, japan
offers the greatest prima facie evidence that the
shift in exchange rate regimes provided greater
insulation from foreign shocks because its economy became less volatile after exchange rates
began to float. However, the simple observation
that the japanese economy became less volatile
does not by itself prove that floating rates were
the causal factor. What remains unresolved is
whether the move to flexible rates or a change in
the nature of domestic and foreign disturbances
was primarily responsible for dampened output
fluctuations in japan.
Under fixed exchange rates, japan had the
largestHuetuati0fls-in0utputitm0f1 g-the-majerindustrial countries, while under flexible rates,
japan has had the smallest, as the chart shows.
Some have argued that the switch to floating
rates permitted japan to pursue more stable
monetary policy, which, in turn, increased output stability. Proponents of this view point to the
fact that the variability in japanese money growth
declined markedly beginning in the mid-1970s,
and that this decline coincided with the reduction in japanese output volatility.

Real GNP Growth for
Japan and the Group of 10*

Percent
(Log Scale)

25

5
3

58 60 62 64 66 68 70 72 74 76 78 80 82 84 86 88
* The countries comprising the G-l0 group are:
The United States; United Kingdom, Germany, Japan, France,
Canada, Italy, The Netherlands, Belgium, Sweden, and Switzerland,

A different view
An alternative explanation is that diminished
nonmonetary domestic economic disturbances
primarily may account for more stable output
growth in japan. According to this view, real
output and monetary disturbances in japan during the fixed-rate period were predominantly of
domestic origin, associated with japan's so-called
"high growth period:' During this period, the
japanese economy experienced double-digit real
growth rates, fundamental, sectoral demand and
supply shifts, and rapid technological innovation.
The abrupt end of this high growth period in the
early 1970s (for reasons unrelated to the change
in exchange rate regimes), therefore, may account for the subsequent increase in output
stability.
During the first three decades of the post-war
period, japan was a semi-industrialized country
in the process of catching up with the more advanced countries of Europe and North America.
For most of this period labor was an abundant
resource, but there were shortages of capital
equipment, raw materials, and technical expertise. Postwar economic policy was therefore
designed strategically to give priority to plant
and equipment investment and to the export

FRBSF
sector as a means of securing imported raw
materials. Elements of this policy included tight
trade and exchange rate management, protection
of industry, tax treatment favoring saving and investment, and credit subsidies to priority sectors.

exchange rate period is correct hinges crucially
on whether the nature of the underlying disturbances has changed or whether the exchange rate
system has affected the manner in which Japan
has adjusted to these disturbances.

The rapid growth in the investment and export
sectors of the Japanese economy and the consequent double-digit growth rates in overall output
during this period are well documented. Sectoral
output and resource shifts (particularly, the absorption of latent unemployment in agriculture
and low-productivity traditional services into
the rapidly growing investment and export sectors) characterized the Japanese economy during
the "high-growth" period. Economists Denison
and Chung, for example, found that five factors
contributed to faster growth in Japan than in
other industrial countries: increased labor inputs,
increased capital stock, advances in knowledge,
reallocation of resources away from agriculture,
and economies of scale.

To shed light on this issue, we measured the
extent to which Japanese economic disturbances during both the fixed and the flexible rate
periods could be attributed to domestic versus
foreign sources. In our analysis, movements in
Japanese real GNP that are not attributable to
movements in U.S. real GNP and/or changes
in the nominal U.S. money supply (Ml) or to
changes in the real world price of oil are interpreted as arising from domestic Uapanese)
disturbances.
Our results indicate that under fixed exchange
rates, domestic shocks contributed much more
significantly to the volatil ity of Japanese real
GNP than did foreign shocks. Specifically, under
fiva~ I'')t.o.c
IIA.\....U

The financial system and monetary policy played
a fairly passive role during this period. The financial system was highly concentrated and extensively regulated to ensure that resources flowed
to priority sectors. Similarly, the stance of monetary policy during the period was generally
expansionary; its fundamental purpose was to
support the rapid growth of the economy and
to provide high priority sectors with subsidized
credit.

I Ul.\....

J,

tho.
n'ln.rJnl Cllnnactc th""t rlrUYlL:lct;r
U I\.... IIIVU\....1 ..:JU65LJlJ 1I1CH U V l l l L J l I L

shocks accounted for between 89 percent (at
the one-quarter horizon) and 68 percent (at the
30-quarter forecast horizon) of the variance in
Japanese real GNP. In contrast, the proportion
of Japanese real GNP variation associated with
foreign shocks ranged from only 11 percent in
the short term to 32 percent in the longer term.
In the flexible rate period, domestic shocks
were of secondary importance. Instead, foreign
shocks accounted for 77 percent of Japanese
GNP variation in the short term and 65 percent
in the longer run. Thus, it appears that shocks of
foreign origin played a much smaller role in generating Japanese output instability during the
period of fixed exchange rates than during the
period of flexible rates.

The "low growth" period in Japan is usually
identified as beginning in the early 1970s. By
this time, Japan largely had "caught up" with
the West, and the greater part of the sectoral
transformation of the Japanese economy had
been completed. The sectoral reallocation of resources stabilized, sectoral shifts dampened in
.magnitude and frequency, and average economic ---Ourresults.-are-consistenLw.itb the-h-ypotbesis
growth dropped to half its previous rate. Average
that major sectoral shifts and the rapid industrial
trend real GNP growth in Japan was 9.4 percent
transformation of the Japanese economy during
a year during the high growth period and 4.2
the greater part of the fixed exchange rate period
percent during the low growth period. These
were primarily responsible for the large observed
developments may be the primary reason for the
output fluctuations, and that foreign factors
reduction in the variability of output during this
played a secondary role. These results seem to
period, playing a much larger role than the
contradict the standard view that the shift in the
change in the exchange rate regime.
exchange rate regime has been the main reason
Japan has enjoyed greater economic stability in
the latter period. Otherwise, the switch to flexAn empirical question
Which of the two competing interpretations of
ible exchange rates should have insulated Japan
Japan's reduced output variability in the floating
from these foreign shocks. In fact, our results

indicate that foreign shocks have been more
important under flexible exchange rates.

economy from foreign shocks. This effect, however, was swamped by the reduction in the role
played by domestically originating disturbances.

Changing disturbances
Nonetheless, one cannot conclude on this basis
that the flexible exchange rate regime provided
no insulation (or worse, that it may have intensified the impact of foreign shocks on the Japanese economy). Rather, foreign shocks may have
dominated domestic shocks during the flexible
rate period simply because the nature and pattern of the shocks facing the economy changed.
Perhaps more importantly, the move to floating
rates also may have freed monetary policy to engage in policies designed to offset the impact of
domestic disturbances. To examine these possibilities, we calculated the estimated variances
of the disturbances under the two exchange rate
regimes.
Not surprisingly, the variance of real oil shocks
in the pre-1973 period of fixed rates was estimated to have been less than half of that during
the flexible rate regime. The variance of
monetary shocks also was significantly smaller
GNP
in the pre-1973 period, although real
shocks were somewhat larger in the fixed rate
period. Nonetheless, by far the largest change
occurred in the variance of domestic Japanese
shocks. During the period prior to 1973, the variance of such disturbances was three times its
value in the period after the shift to flexible rates.

u.s.
u.s.

These results indicate that the nature and magnitude of the underlying disturbances facing the
Japanese economy under the two exchange rate
regimes were quite different. They also suggest
that although foreign shocks account for relatively
more of the forecast error variance of Japanese
real output under flexible exchange rates, this
probably is attributable to the greatly reduced
magnitude of underlying domestic disturbances,
and not to the switch to flexible exchange rates
per se. In fact, we find some evidence that flexible rates did help to insulate the domestic

Our results also cast doubt on the standard argument that Japan's output stability resulted from
the monetary stabi! ity ach ieved under floati ng
rates. Under fixed exchange rates, Japan's monetary instability was not an independent source of
economic fluctuations; the money supply simply
responded to domestic and foreign disturbances
in order to maintain the exchange rate. Consequently, greater monetary stability after the shift
to floating rates cannot, by itself, account for the
reduced importance of domestic Japanese
disturbances.

Shocks, not regimes
We have focused on Japan in part because,
on the surface, it appears to fit the traditional
theory regarding the superior insulating properties of flexible exchange rates: since the move
to flexible exchange rates in February 1973 Japanese output variance has fallen markedly. Our
research suggests, however, that a more plausible
alternative explanation is simply that domestic
disturbances were more frequent and their magnitude much greater during the period of Japan's
transition to a mature industrial economy.
In the case of Japan, it appears that the changing
nature of the fundamental disturbances to the
economy, rather than the switch in exchange rate
regime, is primarily responsible for the remarkable stability in real output growth since the
mid-1970s.

Carl E. Walsh
Michael Hutchison
Visiting Scholar, FRBSF
Economist
and Associate Professor,
Bank for Int'l
Univ. of Calif.,
Settlements
Santa Cruz
and Assistant Professor,
Univ. of Calif.,
Santa Cruz

Opinions expressed in this newsletter do not necessariiy reflect the views of the management of the Federal Reserve Bank of
San Francisco, or of the Board of Governors of the Federal Reserve System.
Editorial comments may be addressed to the editor (Barbara Bennett) or to the author.... Free copies of Federal Reserve
publications can be obtained from the Public Information Department, Federal Reserve Bank of San Francisco, P.O. Box 7702,
San Francisco 94120. Phone (415) 974-2246.

Research Department

Federal Reserve
Bank of
San Francisco
P.O. Box 7702
San Francisco, CA 94120