View original document

The full text on this page is automatically extracted from the file linked above and may contain errors and inconsistencies.

October 11,1974

Potential causes of the world's ab­
normal rates of inflation are easier
to come by than potential cures.
Still, part of the problem of devis­
ing solutions stems from the difficul­
ties of diagnosis. Dozens of com­
peting explanations have been
advanced in the recent past, ranging
from the workings of the interna­
tional oil cartel to the now-famous
disappearance of the Peruvian an­
chovies. However, an increasing
amount of research is now being
devoted to monetary explanations
of the worldwide upsurge in prices.
Expansion of monetary base
Monetary analysts link the domestic
inflation since the late 1960's with
the rapid growth of the U.S. mone­
tary base and thus the U.S. money
supply. These analysts also argue
that the expansion of the U.S. mone­
tary base has been an important
determinant in inflation rates in
foreign countries because it led to
expansion in the monetary bases of
these countries. The rapid growth
of the U.S. monetary base has
tended to increase U.S. prices and
diminish the value of the dollar
on foreign-exchange markets. To
maintain dollar exchange rates
within predetermined bands, for­
eign central banks had entered ex­
change markets periodically to
purchase dollars. These dollar pur­
chase operations had the same
effect as domestic Federal Reserve
open market operations, leading to
increasing the monetary bases of
foreign countries and thereby their
domestic money supplies.

1




The liabilities of foreign central
banks (another name for the mone­
tary base) are matched by both
domestic government debt and for­
eign-exchange reserves. In fact,
changes in foreign-exchange re­
serves have dominated the move­
ments of the monetary base in most
industrial countries during the
period of fixed exchange rates.
Under a fixed exchange-rate system
surplus countries (other than the
U.S.) had an undesirable choice—
either revalue the currency, thereby
hampering the export sector by
making export goods more expen­
sive, or accept the impact of the
reserve inflow on the monetary
base, adding further to money
growth and inflationary pressure.
Central banks can sterilize such
reserve inflows in the short-run if
they are relatively small. However,
if the inflows are large or continue
for a long period of time, they
will affect the domestic money
supply.
Given that in each country domestic
currency growth determines domes­
tic prices, it follows that the course
of world prices depends closely on
the rate of growth of the world
money supply. However, they now
have to face the question of whether
floating exchange rates— albeit
managed to some degree by central
banks— will diminish the inflation­
ary pressures on world prices. This
question is related to the fixedvs- floating exchange-rate
controversy.

(continued on page 2)

Opinions expressed in this newsletter do not
necessarily reflect the views of the management of the
Federal Reserve Bank of San Francisco, nor of the Board
of Governors of the Federal Reserve System.

Expanding world base
Monetarists contend that control
over the money supply, interna­
tionally as well as domestically, de­
pends on control over the monetary
base. Consequently, they are now
giving close attention to alternative
measures ot a world monetary base.
One such measure is published in
the annual report of the Italian cen­
tral bank, Banca d'ltalia, and is
called the international liquidity
base. The sources of the world
liquidity base include monetary
gold, IMF ordinary and special draw­
ing rights, unused credit lines at
the IMF and the Federal Reserve
Bank of New York— and most im­
portantly, U.S. and U.K. liquid liabili­
ties to official holders. (The total
does not include domestic assets
held by central banks.)
The world liquidity base has grown
spectacularly since the late 1960's,
and has supported the vast increase
in the world money supply. The
sharpest growth— almost $22 billion
— came in 1971, when it expanded
more than in the preceding three
years put together. Two-thirds of
that 1971 upsurge was due to a
sharp increase in foreign official
holdings of dollars, associated

2




mainly with the severe monetary
crisis which culminated in the de­
valuation of the dollar.
Official foreign-exchange reserves
— a primary component of the world
liquidity base— have soared from
$32 billion in 1969 to almost $138
billion in mid-1974. At the same time,
a sharp discrepancy— $7 billion in
1969, but $48 billion in 1973 — has
appeared between this total and U.S.
-U.K. liabilities to official foreign
institutions. The discrepancy indi­
cates that foreign-exchange reserves
are being “ created" without an off setting U.S. or U.K. official liability.
The source of this unexpected inter­
national-reserve creation is the
Eurocurrency market. In that market,
the funds deposited by foreign cen­
tral banks expand through Eurocur­
rency loans and later reappear as
official foreign-exchange reserves.
The process has been noted re­
cently, of course, in connection with
the placement of the flood of dol­
lars from the oil-exporting countries.
In its annual review of the Euro­
currency market, the Bank for Inter­
national Settlements noted the ex­
pansionary influence in 1973 of $8­
10 billion in deposits by official

monetary authorities, mainly attrib­
utable to the "fairly sharp expansion
of the reserves of the developing
countries." That influence will bur­
geon in 1974 and later years.
Dollars and floating rates
The future of the dollar in foreignexchange markets will depend not
only on the supply of dollars, but
also on official and private demands.
Some analysts contend that the sys­
tem of floating exchange rates will
affect official and private demands
differently. The official demand for
dollars should decline under this re­
gime, but private demands could in­
crease, because other currencies
would then be less perfect substi­
tutes for dollars, the primary inter­
national-trading currency.
The system of floating rates allows
countries to insulate their domestic
money supplies from outside mone­

tary movements, by permitting ex­
change rates to appreciate or depre­
ciate. The question still remains,
however, how much countries will
allow their exchange rates to move
in order to secure control of domes­
tic money growth and their domes­
tic rates of inflation. Nor will it be
costless for monetary authorities to
pursue policies to reduce rates of
money growth.
While flexible exchange rates may
provide the mechanism for coun­
tries to determine to some extent
their domestic rates of inflation,
money growth still has a large
short-run impact on output and
employment. Coincident reductions
in money growth across the globe
will possibly mean a reduction in
the rate of growth of world output.
But apparently, little choice remains
if inflation is to be curtailed to any
significant degree.

C

=

3

o

Joseph Bisignano

Business Review
The current (September) issue of the Business Review carries the
recent testimony of John J. Balles, President of the Federal Reserve Bank
of San Francisco, before the House Banking and Currency Committee.
In his testimony, Mr. Balles presents four major policy recommendations
concerning ways of fighting inflation and high interest rates. Another
feature of this issue is an analysis of the inflation-unemployment trade-off
by Larry Butler, entitled "The Relation Between Income Growth and
Unemployment." See page 4 for information on obtaining copies of this
issue.

3




m

o c=

3

uo;Su!i]se/v\ • q e ifi • uo S a jo • ppBAafsj . oqepi
H E M EH

•

E jU J O p | E 3

*

EU O ZU y

BANKING DATA—TWELFTH FEDERAL RESERVE DISTRICT
(Dollar amounts in millions)
Amount
Outstanding
9/25/74

Change
from
9/18/74

Change from
year ago
Dollar
Percent

Loans (gross) adjusted and investments*
Loans gross adjusted—
Securities loans
Commercial and industrial
Real estate
Consumer instalment
U.S. Treasury securities
Other Securities
Deposits (less cash items)— total*
Demand deposits adjusted
U.S. Government deposits
Time deposits— total*
Savings
Other time I.P.C.
State and political subdivisions
(Large negotiable CD's)

83,472
66,990
1,583
23,955
19,914
9,557
3,965
12,517
80,444
22,146
899
55,936
17,697
28,814
5,984
15,600

918
848
731
—
90
+ 36
+ 40
—
65
—
5
654
— 510
+ 58
+ 363
+ 24
+ 157
+ 39
+ 335

+7,783
+8,516
+ 428
+3,490
+2,298
+ 716

Weekly Averages
of Daily Figures

Week ended
9/25/74

Selected Assets and Liabilities
Large Commercial Banks

-

-

-

+
+
+
+
+
+

1,164

—

+ 431
+6,436
+1,029
—

+
+
+

182

—

+5,280
+ 51
+5,018
—

+
+
+

201

—

+3,295

Week ended
9/18/74

+

10.29
14.56
37.06
17.05
13.04
8.10
22.69
3.59
8.77
4.87
16.84
10.42
0.29
21.09
3.25
26.78

Comparable
year-ago period

Member Bank Reserve Position
Excess Reserves
Borrowings
Net free ( + ) / Net borrowed ( —)

-

102
147
45

54
204
-2 5 8

-

+ 521

+ 1,362

-9 9 6

+ 945

+ 1,064

+ 150

-

23
88
65

Federal Funds— Seven Large Banks
Interbank Federal fund transactions
Net purchases ( + ) / Net sales ( - )
Transactions: U.S. securities dealers
Net loans ( + ) / Net borrowings ( —)
* Includes items not shown separately.

Information on this and other publications can be obtained by calling or writing the
Administrative Services Department, Federal Reserve Bank of San Francisco, P.O. Box 7702,
San Francisco, California 94120. Phone (415) 397-1137.




.

E>|SE|V