View original document

The full text on this page is automatically extracted from the file linked above and may contain errors and inconsistencies.

FRBSF WEEKLY LETTEA
November 21, 1986

Interest Checking and Ml
Over the past two years, the M 1 monetary
aggregate has grown at a historically high

checking accounts, although institutions are free
to impose their own minimum balance

anllLJalfateolaOoLJf T2percerit,yet there has

reqUiremellt5.

not been a resurgence of the inflation that would
normally be associated with such rapid money
growth. Many economists argue that this signifies that the traditional relationship between
M 1 and the economy no longer holds. One theory posits that the deregulation of deposit rates
on personal checking accounts, which came
about through the authorization of NOW (Negotiable Order of Withdrawal) and Super NOW
accounts at banks and thrifts, has altered the
behavior of M 1.
In last week's Letter, we showed how the
deregulation of deposit rates on personal checking accounts resulted in interest being paid on
over 70 percent of personal checking account
deposits -or over 30 percent of M1. We also
argued that, although the new NOW and Super
NOW accounts attracted a large fraction of their
deposits from pre-existing checking accounts,
they also attracted funds from nontransaction,
savings-type, accounts.
The shift of nontransaction balances into NOWs
and Super NOWs and the payment of interest on
balances in the two accounts raise the possibility
that deregulated deposits will behave less like
. transactions money and more like other financial assets, and thereby change the behavior of
M1. In this Letter, we examine the behavior of
the NOW and Super NOW components of M 1
along with that of M1 to see whether deregulation can explain the aggregate's recent unusual
behavior.
Deregulation of personal checking
The deregulation of personal checking accounts
began in earnest with the nationwide authorization of NOW accounts on December 31, 1980.
NOW accounts could pay interest up to a maximum of 5V4 percent. The Super NOW account
was authorized about two years later on January
5, 1983 and was ceiling-free, although it was
subject to regulatory minimum balance requirements. On January 1, 1986, both the minimum
balance requirement on Super NOWs arid the
ceiling on NOWs were eliminated. Thus, there
are now no regulatory deposit rate or minimum
balance restrictions on interest-bearing personal

Even though all demand deposit accounts are
still prohibited from paying interest, individuals
can easily avoid this restriction by.choosing a
NOW or Super NOW account. Businesses,
however, are still limited to holding non-interest
bearing demand deposits.
Behavior of deregulated accounts
Some economists expected balances in these
new deregulated accounts to respond much differently to economic changes than balances in
regulated accounts and thereby change M 1's
behavior. In fact, the behavior of NOWs and
Super NOWs has differed markedly from that of
the other components of M1 (mainly currency
and demand deposits).
As shown in Chart 1, in each year since 1982
(well after the initial large shift into NOWs was
completed in early 1981), NOWs plus Super
NOWs have grown much faster than the regulated components of M 1. If the new accounts
had behaved more like traditional checking
accounts (demand deposits) before deregulation,
M1 's growth would have been much lower over
the same period. Thus, on the surface, it appears
that deregulation has increased M 1's rate of
growth.
Lowered opportunity· costs
One explanation for the interest-bearing
accounts' different behaviors is the higher effective yields they offer depositors. Deposit rate
deregulation had the effect of increasing this
effective yield by eliminating the inefficiencies
of nonprice competition. Even though depositors
received some implicit interest in the form of
free or underpriced services on their demand
deposits (which were and still are prohibited
from paying explicit interest), the implicit plus
explicit interest on NOW accounts was significantly higher.
Similarly, since Super NOWsi unlike NOWs,
were completely free of interest ceilings, they
offered even higher total yields than NOWs.
Indeed, it is the higher yields that explain the
massive shifts of funds, first from demand

FABSF

Chart 1
Growth Rates of M1 and Its Components
Annual

Percent

Growth

35
I!lIII
~

deposits to NOWs, and then from NOWs to
Super NOWs when the latter were introduced.
With a much higher yield, the foregone interest,
or opportunity cost, of holding funds in the new
accounts (instead of in higher-yielding nontransaction assets) was much smaller than that of
holding funds in traditional demand deposits,
which paid no explicit interest at all.
Moreover, even though the deposit rate on the
fully deregulated Super NOW was free to move,
it did not vary closely with the open market
interest rate, at least in the short run. As a result,
a given percentage change in the open market
rate would cause a much larger percentage
change in the opportunity cost of these new
accounts than that of traditional zero-interest
checking accounts. For example, if the Super
NOW rate were constant at 9 percent, a 10 per~
cent increase in the open-market rate from 10 to
11 percent would translate into a 100 percent
increase in the opportunity cost (from 1 to 2 percent) of holding a Super NOW but only a 10
percent increase in the opportunity cost of holdinga zero-interest account (from 10 to 11
percent).
To illustrate this point, the monthly percentage
changes in opportunity costs for the Super NOW
and demand deposits are plotted in Chart 2. The
opportunity cost is defined as the difference
between the 3-month Treasury bill yield and the
explicit yield on the-deposit account (as reported
in the Bank Rate Monitor). This chart shows that
the typical monthly percentage change in the
opportunity cost of holding Super NOWs was
several times as large as that of demand
deposits. Although not shown in the chart, the
percentage change in the opportunity costs of
NOW accounts was between that of demand
deposits and Super NOWs because the total
yield on NOWs was between that on demand
deposits and Super NOWs.
According to the inventory theory of money
demand, percentage changes in account balances are inversely related to percentage
changes in the opportunity cost of holding them.
Thus, one might expect deposit balances in
deregulated accounts to be much more variable
than balances in regulated accounts.
In fact, we found that balances in deregulated
accounts were several times more sensitive to
changes in open-market interest rates than bal-

[SI
[iii

30

M1
Currency
Demand Deposits
Interest
Checking

25

20

II
15

10

5

o

1982

1983

1984

1985

1986'

* Preliminary estimates using first 9 months of 1986

ances in regulated accounts. Specifically, we
found that the percentage change in Super
NOW deposits to a given percentage change in
the 3-month Treasury bill rate was several times
larger than the response of demand deposits
prior to the nationwide authorization of NOW
accounts. That is, when short-term interest rates
fell, deposits in Super NOWs increased proportionately several times more than funds in
demand deposits. NOW deposits were less sensitive than Super NOWs but still more sensitive
than demand deposits. And, as other researchers
have found, currency was the least sensitive.

Implications for Ml
It appears that as one moves across the spectrum
of transactions media from the most regulated
(currency) to the least regulated (Super NOWs),
one finds an increasing sensitivity to changes in
the open market rate. This pattern has several
implications for the behavior of M1. First, during
periods when open market interest rates are
declining (and for some time thereafter because
of lags in depositors' responses), the growth rates
of NOWs and Super NOWs should exceed
those of either demand deposits or currency.
This partly explains the more rapid growth of
NOWs plus Super NOWs depicted in Chart 1.
Second, as deregulated accounts grow in popularity over time, we would expect the M1 aggregate to behave more like them and less like its
traditional components (mainly currency and
demand deposits) simply because deregulated
accounts would constitute a greater share of M1.

A simulation
One way to see just how much the behavior of
M1 has been altered by deposit rate deregula-

Chart 2
Super NOWs' Opportunity Costs*
are More Variable than
b~~;;~
Demand Deposit Accounts'

Billions
of Dollars

50

700

40

650

30

Chart 3
Actual vs. Simulated M1 *

I

Now accounts
authorized nationwide

12-31-80

600

Super NOW

550

""
Iii

~ ....'
,:1,iI

500

/\...'
f!

450

,""

,-'Simulated M1 based
on behavior before
12-31-80

400
350
300

-40
-50 '--_ _---l...
1983

...l.-_ _----'-

1984

1985

--'

1986

,. Three·month Treasury bill yield minus
explicit yield on deposit account.

tion is to compare how M1 would have been
predicted to behave based on its relationship to
economic factors before the nationwide authorization of NOWs with how it has actually
behaved since then.
In Chart 3, we compare M1 's actual behavior
with its predicted (simulated) behavior for the
period January 1975 through June 1986. The
simulation of M1, based on its historical relationship to economic factors prior to the introduction of NOWs, seriously underpredicts M 1's
actual behavior beginning in early 1982. This
underprediction coincides with the dramatic
drop in interest rates that began in November
1981, and is thus consistent with the notion that
the interest-sensitivity of M1 began to increase
after NOWs were authorized nationwide.
Moreover, estimates based on M1 's historical
relationship to economic factors between January 1981 and June 1986 - after NOWs were
introduced - indicated that M1 had become
three times more sensitive to interest rates (in the
short run).
Together, these results suggest that deregulation
increased the interest-sensitivity of M 1. They
also suggest that, beginning in early 1982,
deregulation caused M1 to grow much faster

250 '----'------'_--'------'-_-'-----'--_L---'------'-_...L----'
1976 1977 1978 1979 1980 1981 1982 1983 1984 1985 1986
,oNot seasonally adjusted.

than it otherwise would have, largely in
response to the decline in interest rates that
began in late 1981.

Conclusions
The payment of interest has reduced the cost of
holding checking accounts and simultaneously
increased the percentage variation in their
opportunity costs. The latter has, in turn,
increased the responsiveness of balances in
interest-paying checking accounts to changes in
the open-market interest rate.
Because interest-bearing accounts now comprise
over 30 percent of M1, deposit rate deregulation
has changed the behavior of M1 by making it
more sensitive to interest rate changes. Moreover, the continuing shift of funds into deregulated accounts may continue to increase the
interest-sensitivity of M1.
These changes raise questions for monetary policy under virtually any view of what money is
and how money is related to the economy. In
particular, they raise the question of whether a
monetary aggregate comprised of both interestbearing and noninterest-bearing components
with different behaviors and changing returns is
useful for policy purposes.

Michael C. Keeley and Gary C. Zimmerman

Opinions expressed in this newsletter do not necessarily reflect the views of the management of the Federal Reserve Bank of San
Francisco, or of the Board of Governors of the Federal Reserve System.
Editorial comments may be addressed to the editor (Gregory Tong) or to the author ..•. Free copies of Federal Reserve publications
can be obtained from the Public Information Department, Federal Reserve Bank of San Francisco, P.O. Box 7702, San Francisco
94120. Phone (415) 974-2246.

uo~6u!4S0m

040PI

4o~n

!tomoH O!UJoJ!l0)

U060JO
ouoz!J~

0POl\0U
o~sol~

O)SI)UOJ:I UOS

JO ~U08
aAJaSa~ IOJapa:l
~uaw~Jodaa lpJOaSa~
BANKING DATA-TWELFTH FEDERAL RESERVE DISTRICT
(Dollar amounts in millions)

Selected Assets and Liabilities
Large Commercial Banks
Loans, Leases and Investments' 2
Loans and Leases' 6
Commercial and Industrial
Real estate
Loans to Individuals
Leases
u.s. Treasury and Agency Securities2
Other Secu rities 2
Total Deposits
Demand Deposits
Demand Deposits Adjusted 3
Other Transaction Balances4
Total Non-Transaction Balances 6
Money Market Deposit
Accounts-Total
Time Deposits in Amounts of
$100,000 or more
Other Liabilities for Borrowed MoneyS

Two Week Averages
of Daily Figures

Change
from
10/22/86

Amount
Outstanding
10/29/86
201,558
181,027
49,312
66,842
39,636
5,588
12,639
7,892
202,830
50,682
35,473
17,448
134,699

-

-

-

-'-

46,344
33,153
25,944
Period· ended
10/20/86

1,070
1,005
759
189
172
4
13
53
566
466
510
182
81

Change from 10/39/85
Dollar
Percent?

-

-

-

4,506
2,920
1,557
1,351
1,731
185
926
660
3,311
3,089
8,158
3,503
3,281

144

59
12
48

-

36
491

5,359
2,433

Period ended
10/06/86
36
24
12

1 Includes loss reserves, unearned income, excludes interbank loans
2 Excludes trading account securities

Excludes U.S. government and depository institution deposits and cash items
ATS, NOW, Super NOW and savings accounts with telephone transfers
S Includes borrowing via FRB, TI&L notes, Fed Funds, RPs and other sources
6 Includes items not shown separately
7 Annual ized percent change
3
4

-

947

Reserve Position, All Reporting Banks
Excess Reserves (+ )jDeficiency (-)
Borrowings
Net free reserves (+ )jNet borrowed(-)

-

2.2
1.6
3.0
2.0
4.5
3.4
7.9
9.1
1.6
6.4
18.6
25.1
2.3
2.0

-

13.9
10.3