View original document

The full text on this page is automatically extracted from the file linked above and may contain errors and inconsistencies.

FRBSF Economic Letter
2019-19 | July 15, 2019 | Research from the Federal Reserve Bank of San Francisco

Why Is Inflation Low Globally?
Òscar Jordà, Chitra Marti, Fernanda Nechio, and Eric Tallman
A hot economy eventually boosts inflation. Such is the simple wisdom of the Phillips curve.
Yet inflation across developed countries has been remarkably weak since the 2008 global
financial crisis, even though unemployment rates are near historical lows. What is behind this
recent disconnect between inflation and unemployment? Contrasting the experiences of
developed and developing economies before and after the financial crisis shows that broader
factors than monetary policy are at play. Inflation has declined globally, and this trend
preceded the financial crisis.

The world economies have mostly recovered from the 2008 financial crisis. In the United States, United
Kingdom, and Germany, for example, the unemployment rate is now below 4%, lower than it has been in
decades. Tight labor markets are usually a symptom of a healthy economy and thus a rising demand for
goods and services. To satisfy such demand, businesses usually raise prices—the basic mechanism
underlying the standard economic relationship known as the Phillips curve. Yet, 10 years after the financial
crisis, inflation has held remarkably steady. Some researchers therefore argue that the Phillips curve is no
longer a useful descriptor of inflation dynamics (Coibion and Gorodnichenko 2015).
In this Economic Letter, we investigate whether the financial crisis has changed the long-standing inner
workings of the Phillips curve. We extend the analysis in our previous Economic Letter (Jordà et al. 2019) to
include developing economies and analyze three components of the Phillips curve to assess where the links
appear to be broken.
Our analysis suggests that news of the death of the Phillips curve in developed economies appears
premature. Fluctuations in labor market conditions have been largely offset with appropriate interest rate
changes by central banks. Under such conditions, the influence of past inflation has faded, and expectations
for future inflation have gravitated toward the central bank’s stated target. On the surface, inflation appears
stable at all levels of labor market slack, and the Phillips curve link appears broken. Underneath, however,
the Phillips curve could still be at work. The inflation dynamics that we observe could also be explained by a
central bank that successfully offsets fluctuations in slack to keep inflation at the target. In less developed
economies, central banks often operate under constraints that prevent full monetary policy offsets, which has
given a bigger role to feedback from past inflation. That said, inflation has been trending down for the past
two decades across developed and developing economies alike. The inevitable conclusion is that there are
global forces putting downward pressure on inflation, and it is not just the result of better monetary policy.

FRBSF Economic Letter 2019-19

July 15, 2019

What drives inflation?
To assess how well the Phillips curve explains inflation, we treat the financial crisis as a quasi-natural
experiment. Because the crisis was mostly unexpected, we can use the time before the crisis as the control or
baseline for the Phillips curve relationship to examine what happened after the crisis.
We estimate a Phillips curve model that explains inflation as a function of three components. First, we
measure the demand-pull factors, using slack in the labor market. Specifically, we use the unemployment
gap, which is the gap between the unemployment rate and its natural rate, or the rate at which prices would
remain stable. The unemployment gap is a common proxy measure for aggregate demand conditions
because higher demand usually means more hiring.
Second, we use feedback from past inflation, which we measure with the headline consumer price index
(CPI) inflation. This acknowledges that prices tend to adjust slowly, so where inflation has been can
influence where it is headed. That is, businesses take some of their pricing cues from previous periods,
therefore making inflation persistent.
Third, we include expectations of future inflation based on survey data for the United States and data
provided by the Organisation for Economic Co-operation and Development (OECD) for all other countries. If
the central bank can credibly commit to an inflation target, then businesses will choose to price their
products in a manner consistent with the stated target. In such a setting, fluctuations in the unemployment
gap and past deviations of inflation from its target have a much more muted effect on actual inflation.
Credibility is therefore a precious commodity.
In the decade since the global financial crisis, the relationship between the unemployment gap and inflation
appears to have weakened, as shown in Figure 1. Each point in Figure 1 represents the average of the
unemployment gap, along the horizontal axis, and headline CPI inflation, on the vertical axis, across all
OECD countries for a particular quarter. In the two decades before the crisis, there was a clear negative
relationship between unemployment and
Figure 1
inflation (yellow and green lines), such
Phillips curve across OECD countries by decade
that when unemployment was high,
inflation was low, and vice versa. The
CPI inflation (%)
8
current decade (red line) shows that
7
relationship has all but disappeared. Even
with the unemployment gap below zero—
6
meaning that on average the
5
1989-1998
unemployment rate is lower than its
1999-2008
4
natural rate—inflation averages around or
3
below 2%.
2

However, Figure 1 provides only a simple
correlation. Our next step is to formally
estimate how each component of the
Phillips curve—slack, persistence, and
2

1
0

2009-2018
-2

-1.5

-1

-0.5

0
0.5
1
Unemployment gap

1.5

2

2.5

FRBSF Economic Letter 2019-19

July 15, 2019

expectations—contributes to inflation, and how those contributions changed around the decade before and
after the global financial crisis.

What is new since the global financial crisis?
We move beyond simple correlations and formally estimate the contribution of each of the three components
of the Phillips curve: the unemployment gap, to measure slack; past inflation, to measure persistence; and
inflation expectations. We also remove variation in inflation due to fluctuations in oil prices; this accounts
for the fact that oil prices represent a classic supply factor that is outside the control of the monetary
authority. We focus first on OECD economies that experienced the financial crisis. Figure 2 summarizes
estimates for each of these components over two periods, before and after the financial crisis.
The first pair of bars in the figure shows
the slack component. The bars are
negative because more slack means lower
inflation, thus subtracting from the total.
Although the contribution of slack has
dissipated since the crisis, it is clear that
slack played a small role in explaining
inflation dynamics before the crisis.
Given the magnitude of our estimates,
even large values of the unemployment
gap would have only a small effect on
total inflation.

Figure 2
Contributors to Phillips curve changes: OECD countries
1
0.8

1999:Q1-2008:Q3
2008:Q4-2018:Q3

0.6
0.4
0.2
0

The second and third pairs of bars refer to
-0.2
Slack
Persistence
Expectations
persistence and expectations
components, respectively. Since the crisis,
the estimate of the persistence term has declined by as much as the estimate of the expectations term has
increased. Less persistence means that a perturbation to inflation today feeds into tomorrow’s inflation to a
lesser degree. The increase in the estimate of the expectations term means that consumers are likely to
dismiss such perturbations as transitory. In our previous Letter, we documented a similar pattern in the
United States and argued that well-anchored expectations are a natural consequence of credible monetary
policy.

Non-OECD countries and non-crisis trends
Even before the financial crisis, several other global trends were taking shape that probably affected global
inflation. As a starting point for assessing the influence of these trends, Figure 3 displays average inflation
across countries since 1998, divided into OECD developed economies and a sample of 23 non-OECD
developing economies.
Figure 3 indicates that inflation for developing and developed economies has gradually converged over the
years. By the end of the sample, average inflation in both groups was virtually the same. In part, the decline
observed in developing economies may reflect increased credibility of central bank policies. However, both
3

FRBSF Economic Letter 2019-19
groups of economies share a common
trend in inflation, suggesting that global
factors may be keeping inflation at bay
everywhere.

July 15, 2019
Figure 3
Average consumer price index inflation
Percent
10
9

To better understand what might be
happening globally, we repeat our
estimation of the Phillips curve with the
three components using the sample of 23
non-OECD developing economies in the
decade before and after the global
financial crisis. Figure 4 summarizes the
results.

8
7
6

Non-OECD

5
4
3
2

OECD

1

The first pair of bars shows that the
unemployment gap exerted as little
influence on inflation in developing
economies as it did in developed
economies. The persistence and
expectations terms are more interesting.
In contrast with what happened in
developed economies, the persistence
term was much larger and, if anything,
has increased since the crisis. That is,
perturbations in inflation today tend to
play a larger role in how inflation will
develop in the future. Also, the effects of
expectations in developing economies
have diminished to a larger degree
relative to their developed peers as well as
relative to the decade leading up to the
crisis.

0
1998

2003

2008

2013

2018

Figure 4
Contributors to Phillips curve changes: Non-OECD countries
1
0.8

1999:Q1-2008:Q3
2008:Q4-2018:Q3

0.6
0.4
0.2
0
-0.2

Slack

Persistence

Expectations

Since the three components of inflation reflect different experiences among developed and developing
countries after the crisis, those elements cannot explain the global decline in inflation being low globally.
Rather, the answer appears to lie in some other common underlying factors, which could be related to
increasing trade openness, global supply chains, and greater capital and investment flows across countries.
Such factors began reducing costs of production and investments and putting downward pressure on prices
around the globe even before the crisis (International Monetary Fund 2006).

Conclusion
The global financial crisis upended our understanding of inflation dynamics, particularly when viewed
through the lens of the Phillips curve. Low inflation has persisted despite very low unemployment in
developed countries. Yet something similar has taken place in some non-OECD developing countries: despite
4

FRBSF Economic Letter 2019-19

July 15, 2019

the fact that nearly all of these countries have escaped the financial crisis, inflation has remained low there as
well. Interestingly, for developing economies, the role of past inflation in explaining current inflation
remains dominant, in contrast to the pattern among more advanced economies. However, because all
countries have experienced a similar decline in inflation, other global factors must have played an important
role in recent subdued inflation.
Òscar Jordà is vice president in the Economic Research Department of the Federal Reserve Bank of San
Francisco.
Chitra Marti is a research associate in the Economic Research Department of the Federal Reserve Bank of
San Francisco.
Fernanda Nechio is deputy governor in International Affairs and Corporate Risk Management with the
Central Bank of Brazil.
Eric Tallman is a research associate in the Economic Research Department of the Federal Reserve Bank of
San Francisco.
The views expressed do not necessarily reflect the views of the Central Bank of Brazil, the Federal Reserve
Bank of San Francisco, or the Federal Reserve System.

References
Coibion, Olivier, and Yuriy Gorodnichenko. 2015. “Is the Phillips Curve Alive and Well After All? Inflation Expectations
and the Missing Deflation.” American Economic Journal: Macroeconomics 7(1), pp. 197–232.
International Monetary Fund. 2006. “How Has Globalization Affected Inflation?” Chapter III in World Economic
Outlook, April. https://www.imf.org/en/Publications/WEO/Issues/2016/12/31/Globalization-and-Inflation
Jordà, Òscar, Chitra Marti, Fernanda Nechio, and Eric Tallman. 2019. “Inflation: Stress-Testing the Phillips Curve.”
FRBSF Economic Letter 2019-05 (February 11). https://www.frbsf.org/economic-research/publications/economicletter/2019/february/inflation-stress-testing-phillips-curve/

Opinions expressed in FRBSF Economic Letter do not necessarily reflect the views of the management of
the Federal Reserve Bank of San Francisco or of the Board of Governors of the Federal Reserve System.
This publication is edited by Anita Todd with the assistance of Karen Barnes. Permission to reprint portions
of articles or whole articles must be obtained in writing. Please send editorial comments and requests for
reprint permission to Research.Library.sf@sf.frb.org

Recent issues of FRBSF Economic Letter are available at
https://www.frbsf.org/economic-research/publications/economic-letter/
2019-17

Fernald /
Li

Is Slow Still the New Normal for GDP Growth?
https://www.frbsf.org/economic-research/publications/economic-letter/2019/june/is-slow-still-newnormal-for-gdp-growth/

2019-16

Foerster /
Leduc

Why Is the Fed’s Balance Sheet Still So Big?
https://www.frbsf.org/economic-research/publications/economic-letter/2019/may/why-is-fedbalance-sheet-still-so-big/

2019-15

Barnichon

Is the Hot Economy Pulling New Workers into the Labor Force?
https://www.frbsf.org/economic-research/publications/economic-letter/2019/may/is-hot-economypulling-new-workers-into-labor-force/