View original document

The full text on this page is automatically extracted from the file linked above and may contain errors and inconsistencies.

March 26, 1976

H erpetology
After the relative calm of late 1975,
foreign-exchange markets have
been rocked since January by a
wave of speculative attacks on a
number of key European curren­
cies. Downward pressures on the
Italian lira, Spanish peseta, British
pound, French franc and Belgian
franc were accompanied by consid­
erable upward pressures on the
German mark and the Swiss franc,
while the dollar remained relatively
unchanged on a trade-weighted
basis. Although the crisis began
elsewhere, in Italy and the U.K., it
eventually centered on the "snake"
bloc currencies of Western Europe.
A knowledge of herpetology—the
science of snakes—might help
explain the failure of these curren­
cies to wiggle together, but there
are rational economic explanations
as well for this phenomenon. Some
perceive these strains to be the
result of destabilizing private spec­
ulation, while others feel that
differentials in inflation rates and
trade patterns are responsible. In
addition, many central bankers are
concerned that the situation could
deteriorate into one of competitive
depreciations reminiscent of the
1930's.
Destabilizing speculation

The popular view among most
European central bankers is that the
situation reflects the destabilizing
forces of private speculation. The
inability of central banks to restore
“ orderly market conditions," in
turn, is perceived as a failure on
their part to coordinate interven­
tion policy effectively. In late
1




January and early February, for
example, it appeared that central
banks in the snake bloc countries
had succeeded, through massive
joint interventions, in resisting a
major currency realignment. The
victory was short lived, however, as
the French franc, Belgian franc, and
Danish krone came under renewed
pressure in mid-March, following
sharp declines in the Italian lira and
the British pound.
On March 15, French Finance
Minister Fourcade announced that
France was provisionally withdraw­
ing the franc from the snake “ to
protect French currency reserves."
Support operations reportedly cost
the French central bank more than
$1.5 billion in the preceding week,
and considerably more than $3
billion since the beginning of the
year. Belgian authorities meanwhile
abandoned efforts to maintain
margins within the narrower Bene­
lux “ worm" bloc due to substantial
losses of foreign exchange reserves.
In announcing the French with­
drawal from the snake, Finance
Minister Fourcade indicated that the
franc's plight was an indirect con­
sequence of the sharp drop in
sterling, as well as continued de­
clines in the lira. Close to one-fifth
of France's trade is with Britain,
Italy, and Spain, and the French
apparently believe that these cur­
rencies could continue to pull the
franc down if their situation is not
brought under control. Some
French analysts have even suggest­
ed that British authorities were
responsible for the pound's sudden
(continued on page 2)

Opinions expressed in this newsletter do not
necessarily reflect the views of the management of the
Federal Reserve Bank of San Francisco, nor of the Board
of Governors of the Federal Reserve System.

collapse in early March. The Bank
of England reportedly sold sterling
when there was a tendency for it to
appreciate, setting off a subsequent
selling spree by private investors
who interpreted the action as a sign
that British authorities wished to
see sterling lower. The lira's decline
in March, moreover, was attributed
to the unwillingness of Italian
authorities to intervene to maintain
the franc-lira rate.
This argument implies that British
and Italian authorities have not
intervened forcefully enough, or
undertaken sufficient measures, to
prevent currency depreciation.
There is no evidence, however, to
indicate that either country has
deliberately tried to drive down the
exchange rate. If anything, Europe­
an central banks have strongly
resisted exchange-rate changes,
even when market factors indicated
that changes could be warranted.
Inflationary pressures

An alternative explanation of the
crisis is that private investors per­
ceived large differentials in infla­
tion rates and trade patterns be­
tween the two groups of European
countries, and thus anticipated that
changes would be made in their
relatively fixed exchange rates.
Inflation rates in Belgium (13%),
France (10%), Italy (11%), Spain
(16%), and the United Kingdom
(24%), are from two to four times

2




higher than in Germany (6%) and
Switzerland (7%), and differentials
have widened in recent months. This
situation, in turn, has contributed
to divergences in the trade
positions of the two groups of
countries.
The situation is further complicated
by the use of the dollar as the
principal intervention currency.
With the U.S. inflation rate (9%)
between the German-Swiss rates
and other European countries'
inflation rates, one would expect
the mark and Swiss franc to appre­
ciate against the dollar, and the
other currencies to depreciate
relative to the dollar—and this has
been precisely the case.
Some observers argue that, to the
extent that the present strains
reflect differences in inflation rates
rather than destabilizing specula­
tive pressures, a different light may
be cast on the desirability of
central-bank interventions. Under
these circumstances, if a central
bank intervened to prevent a
desirable currency depreciation,
the action would tend to postpone
necessary market adjustments.
Hence, in this view, official inter­
ventions themselves could become
a source of instability.
The persistence of inflation differ­
entials also raises questions about
the viability of a joint European
float. Fixed exchange rates among

Common Market countries are
clearly desirable for maintaining
stable trade patterns, given the
importance of intra-bloc trade
among these countries. The basic
issue, however, is whether fixed
exchange rates can be maintained
when countries do not follow
identical monetary policies and
when they differ over desired
inflation-unemployment trade-offs.
According to many outside observ­
ers, the more divergent monetary
policies are in snake countries, the
greater is their need for increased
exchange-rate flexibility. In this
view, the current snake problems
primarily reflect a failure of central
banks to coordinate monetary
policy, rather than a failure to
coordinate intervention policy.
Competitive depreciation?

How real is the threat of competi­
tive depreciations? Those observers
who are skeptical about floating
exchange rates have worried about
this threat ever since the managedfloat system was initiated in March
of 1973. To lessen the prospects,
international financial authorities
developed voluntary guidelines for
the “ interim period,, of interna­
tional monetary reform, whereby
central banks would refrain from
selling their domestic currencies to
drive down their value. At the same
time, central banks were encour­
aged to smooth unnecessary
exchange-rate fluctuations by “ lean­
ing against the wind.”

Until March of this year, all of the
European central banks strongly
resisted exchange-rate changes.
Then came the British and Italian
initiatives. Yet despite the criticism
of their actions, there is no evi­
dence that they have violated the
guidelines. Moreover, to the extent
that pressures on these currencies
reflect inflationary forces, the Brit­
ish and Italian central-bank actions
in not strongly resisting exchangerate depreciation would be entirely
appropriate.
Finally, the existence of double­
digit inflation in most European
countries should act as an impor­
tant constraint on the possibility of
future competitive depreciations.
While depreciation would tend to
enhance a country's employment
situation, it would also tend to
exacerbate inflationary pressures by
bidding up prices of imported
goods and import substitutes. This
consideration of course was less
important in the 1930’s, when high
unemployment was accompanied
by price deflation.
In sum, European countries today
are encountering many of the same
problems which plagued the inter­
national monetary system in the
late 1960;s and 1970's. Their dilem­
ma is one of maintaining relatively
fixed exchange rates in the face of
differential inflation rates, in a world
where capital remains highly mobile.
Nicholas Sargen

3




UO!§UmSB/V\ • l|Bin • UO§0JO • epeA3N • Ol)Ep|
J jB M B H

.

B jU J O p |B 3

.

BUOZUV

•

*l!le3 '0 3 S J 3 U B J J U B S
ISA ON llWU3d

aivd

3DVlSOd s n
1IVW SSV13 ISdlJ

BANKING DATA—TWELFTH FEDERAL RESERVE DISTRICT
(Dollar amounts in millions)
Amount
Outstanding
3/10/76

Change
from
3/03/76

Loans (gross, adjusted) and investments*
Loans (gross, adjusted)—total
Security loans
Commercial and industrial
Real estate
Consumer instalment
U.S. Treasury securities
Other securities
Deposits (less cash items)—total*
Demand deposits (adjusted)
U.S. Government deposits
Time deposits—total*
States and political subdivisions
Savings deposits
Other time deposits^
Large negotiable C D ’s

87,561
65,932
2,057
23,043
19,497
10,614
8,834
12,795
87,512
24,430
364
61,287
6,381
24,960
27,407
12,242

+ 1,152
+ 1,107
+ 1,153
1
+
20
7
155
+ 200
+ 1,191
+ 765
237
+ 802
130
+ 102
+ 609
+ 788

Weekly Averages
of Daily Figures

Week ended
3/10/76

Selected Assets and Liabilities
Large Commercial Banks

Member Bank Reserve Position
Excess Reserves
Borrowings
Net free(+)/Net borrowed (-)
Federal Funds—Seven Large Banks
Interbank Federal fund transactions
Net purchases (+)/Net sales (-)
Transactions of U.S. security dealers
Net loans (+)/Net borrowings (-)

+

9
0
9

Change from
year ago
Dollar
Percent
+
+
+
+
+
+
+
+
-

1,287
676
208
1,114
367
737
1,950
13
2,740
1,282
75
1,425
376
5,854
3,274
4,574

Week ended
3/03/76

+

+
+
+
+
+
+
+
+
-

1.49
1.01
9.18
4.61
1.85
7.46
28.33
0.10
3.23
5.54
17.08
2.38
5.56
30.64
10.67
27.20

Comparable
year-ago period

88
3
85

+

48
0
48

+ 1,352

+ 1,502

+ 2,004

+

+

+ 1,574

547

148

♦Includes items not shown separately, individuals, partnerships and corporations.

Editorial comments may be addressed to the editor (William Burke) or to the author. . . .Information
on this and other publications can be obtained by calling or writing the Public Information Section,
Federal Reserve Bank of San Francisco, P.O. Box 7702, San Francisco 94120. Phone (415) 544-2184.




B>)SE| v