View original document

The full text on this page is automatically extracted from the file linked above and may contain errors and inconsistencies.

FRBSF WEEKLY LETTER
September 6, 1985

Geographic Deposit Competition
In this Letter, we summarize several pieces of
empirical evidence on the geographic scope (j.e.,
the size) of deposit markets for money market deposit accounts (MMDAs) and Super NOW
accounts. In particular, we focus on whether the
competition for these two types of deposit
accounts is statewide or confined within
metropolitan areas.
Knowing a deposit market's geographic scope is
important because it is a key influence on the
degree of competition for deposits, and thus the
level of depositrates, in a market. If markets were
small in scope - limited to metropolitan areas or
towns, for example - competition might be
limited, at least in areas with very few banks.
However, if deposit markets were statewide in
scope, deposit competition in states with a large
number of banks likely would be intense even in
towns with only a few banks because each bank
would be in competition with every other bank in
the state.

The definition of a market

However, even if depositors found only banks near
them to be good substitutes, deposit markets
would not necessarily be small. Entry and threat of
entry by banks not currently in the area, competition by nondepository institutions (such as money
funds) offering substitute services, or competition
by institutions on the border of a region may result
in a significant degree of competition among local
areas even though these local"markets" are somewhat insulated from one another. Thus, the
behaviors of both banks and depositors play key
roles in determining the size of deposit markets.
For some types of deposits, such as those with a
large transaction service component (e.g., the
Super NOW), a depositor may consider only banks
within a small region to be good substitutes.
Markets for transaction accounts are likely to be
smaller than for other types of accounts because of
the high value depositors may place on the convenience of local banks' check clearing, depositing,
and cashing services. Thus, the supply of these
types of deposits may be local. However, as discussed above, a local supply of deposits alone
does not mean the deposit market itself is
necessarily local.

In a geographic deposit market, the forces of supply and demand interact to determine the deposit
interest rate, fees or other nonrate terms, service
levels, and the quantity of deposits in that market.
Depositors supply deposit funds to earn interest
(and to receive services) and banks demand funds
to make loans. Within a deposit market, arbitrage
will tend to force banks' deposit rates toward
uniformity. Thus, if two regions were in the same
market, interest rates in the two areas would tend
to be equal.

Most previous researchers studying competition in
retail banking have assumed that deposit markets
are local - a local market being proxied by a
metropolitan area. However, at least in states that
permit unrestricted branching, we think that competition for some types of deposits may take place
in statewide markets.

A market includes the suppliers (depositors) and
demanders (depository institutions, hereafter
referred to as banks) that are important components of the determination of deposit rates. For
example, if depositors at location A found banks at
locations Band C to be equally convenient, then
locations A, Band C would be in the same market
because banks at locations Band C would have to
compete with one another for deposits from location A. In economic terms, banks in locations Band
C would be good substitutes for the depositors in
location A.

Through a survey, we have determined that virtually all multiple-branch banks in the West pay
common rates on deposits at all branches. This
suggests that either there are no local differences
in competition or, even if there were, banks with
large branch networks do not find it worthwhile to
exploit them. One reason why it may not be
worthwhile to pay different rates at different
branches is that a depositor can open an account
at the branch with the highest rate yet use deposit
aDd transaction services at the most convenient
branch. Such uniform pricing by several of the large

An analysis of markets

FRBSF
banks with branches in many areas may make it
unprofitable for other banks to price differently.
However, since branching across state lines is not
currently permitted, markets in different states may
be somewhat insulated from one another.
Within a deposit market, supply and demand
determine the deposit interest rate. Thus, a
difference in the levels of deposit interest rates in
two areas suggests the areas are in separate
markets (because either supply or demand is
different). Likewise, since shifts in either supply or
demand within a market would affect all banks' deposit interest rates similarly, deposit rates within a
market should be more highly correlated with one
another than with rates in other markets. In our
analysis of the geographic scope of deposit
markets, we looked at both sorts of evidence.
Our study is based on an analysis of explicit deposit interest rates on MMDAs and Super NOWs
- two accounts that have been free of interest
ceilings since their inceptions and which now
account for 21 and 2 percent of total domestic deposits, respectively. (A more detailed analysis
appears in this Bank's 1985 Summer Economic
Review.) The data are from a monthly Federal
Reserve survey of 59 commercial banks in the
Twelfth Federal Reserve District.
Charts 1 and 2 summarize how deposit rates at the
state level and at the metropolitan area level
within California behave for the MMDA and Super
NOW accounts, respectively. We used the Rand
McNally definition of metropolitan areas known as
RMAs.
For the MMDA, there are some differences in the
level as well as the time pattern of rates among
western states. Both suggest that MMDA markets
are not larger than states. Hawaii, in particular, with
a low and relatively constant rate, appears to be in
a different market. Statistical analysis of these data
confirms that the differences in the average level of
MMDA rates among the states are statistically significant, even with Hawaii excluded.
However, as Chart 1 Panel B shows, there are virtually no differences in the averag~ level of MMDA
rates among RMAs (an average of rates paid by all
banks with offices in an RMA) in California.
Moreover, MMDA rates among California RMAs

are almost perfectly correlated with one another
and evidence not presented in the charts indicates
that they are much more highly correlated with
one another than with rates in RMAs outside the
state. This is further evidence of statewide but not
local MMDA deposit markets. In sum, for the
MMDA, we find no evidence of local markets but
strong evidence of statewide markets.
For the Super NOW (see Chart 2), differences in
the level of rates among the states is staggering,
averaging a difference of over 200 basis points between the highest and lowest. Moreover, there is a
marked difference in the time pattern of rates
among the states, that is, mean rates in eacQstate
are not highly correlated with mean rates in the
other states. Thus, the evidence suggests that
Super NOW markets also are not larger than states.
However, as Chart 2 Panel B shows, there are
apparent differences in the level of Super NOW
rates among RMAs in California, especially during
the February-September 1983 period. Statistical
analysis confirms these differences are significant.
Thus, these inter-RMA differences in rates suggest
the markets for Super NOWs are local. However,
as Chart 2 shows, the rate differences among
RMAs are small compared to the interstate
differences. Thus, although there may be distinct
local markets for Super NOWs, there is apparently
a much higher degree of competition among them
than among the states.

Service competition
The analysis of markets illustrated by Charts 1 and
2 is based solely on explicit deposit rates.
However, competition in the services offered (nonrate competition) also may be important, especially
for transaction accounts. Since we are unable to
measure service competition, it is possible that
differences in the total return (implicit plus explicit)
to depositors would be either larger or smaller than
the differences in explicit rates shown in the chart.
Moreover, differences in fees or minimum balances
(which we do not observe) also could lead to
either larger or smaller differences in true (net of
fees) deposit rates than in the explicit rates we
observed. However, as long as nonpriced service
levels or fees do not vary rapidly over time relative
to explicit rates, the correlation of rates within relative to among areas would not be affected.

Panel A.

Chart 1
Mean MMDA Rates by State

Panel A.

Percent

Chart 2
Mean Super NOW Rates by State

Perceint

11

9

10

9

8

7L.L................':':':-.................................~.....................
Panel B.

Panel B.

Mean MMDA Rates By California RMA
Percent
(Variation within California)

Mean Super NOW Rate By California RMA
(Variation within California)
Percent

11

9

10

8

9

7

8

6

7L..L..L.L--'--J---'---.L.L--'--l---'---LL..L.L---'-Ll-.L.L--'--l---'---.l-J

1982

1984

1985

Conclusions
Both differences in levels and differences in the
time patterns of MMDA and Super NOW rates
among western (Twelfth Federal Reserve District)
states suggest that the markets for both of these
deposit accounts are no larger than states.
For the Super NOW, there are also small (but
statistically significant) differences in rates among
California RMAs, which suggest Super NOW deposit markets may be local, although these
differences could be due to unmeasured
differences in fees or service competition. This suggests that if differences in explicit rates are due to
the existence of local Super NOW markets, these
local markets are not well insulated from one
another. However, the differences in rates among
RMAs are much smaller than the interstate
differences.
For the MMDA, we find no evidence of local deposit markets - mean rates are virtually the same
in all California RMAs, are almost perfectly corre-

5L..L..L.L---'---.L.L--'--J---'---.L.L---'-L..L..L.L---'---LL--'--l---'---.L.l

1983

1984

1985

lated with one another, and are morl? highly correlated with one another than with rates in other
states. Thus, it appears there is a higher degree of
competition among California RMAs for MMDA
deposits than for Super NOW deposits, perhaps
because the supply of transaction deposits is more
local than savings deposits.
These results may not be surprising given the
unrestricted statewide branch banking in California
and the uniform pricing by multiple branch banks.
In California especially, where the five largest
banks have huge branch networks and are represented in virtually all of the RMAs, it is likely that
competition among RMAs would be intense.
Moreover, if unrestricted branching within a state
does in fact lead to statewide MMDA deposit
markets, then regional or national branching may
lead to regional or nationwide MMDA deposit
markets. Thus, as interstate banking progresses, we
would expect to see MMDA depost markets
expanding geographically.
Michael C. Keeley and Gary C. Zimmerman

Opinions expressed in this newsletter do not necessarily reflect the views of the management of the Federal Reserve Bank of San
Francisco, or of the Board of Governors of the Federal Reserve System.
Editorial comments may be addressed to the editor (Gregory Tong) or to the author .... Free copies of Federal Reserve publications
can be obtained from the Public Information Department, Federal Reserve Bank of San Francisco, P.O. Box 7702, San Francisco
94120. Phone (415) 974-2246.

uo~6u!4S0m

040PI

!!omoH

4o~n

O!UJOJIIO)

U060JO
OUOZ1J~

O)SI)UOJ~

JO

UOS

~U08

aAJaSa~ IOJapa~

~uew~Jodea LpJOeSe~
BANKING DATA-TWELFTH FEDERAL RESERVE DISTRICT
(Dollar amounts in millions)

Selected Assets and Liabilities
Large Commercial Banks
Loans, Leases and Investments l 2
Loans and Leases 1 6
Commercial and Industrial
Real estate
Loans to Individuals
Leases
U.S. Treasury and Agency Securities2
Other Securities 2
Total Deposits
Demand Deposits
Demand Deposits Adjusted 3
Other Transaction Balances 4
Total Non-Transaction Balances 6
Money Market Deposit
Accounts-Total
Time Deposits in Amounts of
$100,000 or more
Other Liabilities for Borrowed MoneyS

Two Week Averages
of Daily Figures

Change
from
8/14/85

Amount
Outstanding
8121/85

192,372
173,870
50,490
64,285
35,368
5,426
11,501
7,001
196,711
45,751
31,095
13,637
137,322
44,880
38,104
22,103
Period ended
8/12/85

-

-

-

-

Change from 8/22/84
Dollar
Percent!

241
307
174
79
74
6
103
38
1,323
1,155
46
351
183

-

151

-

148
232

-

-

11,530
11,916
1,277
3,426
6,074
387
349
36
8,750
2,698
3,226
1,443
4,608
7,181

-

3,074
2,713

Period ended
7/29/85

Reserve Position, All Reporting Banks
Excess Reserves (+ )/Deficiency (-)
Borrowings
Net free reserves (+ )/Net borrowed( -)
1
2

3
4

S
6
7

12
59
46

67
19
47

Includes loss reserves, unearned income, excludes interbank loans
Excludes trading account securities
Excludes
government and depository institution deposits and cash items
ATS, NOW, Super NOW and savings accounts with telephone transfers
Includes borrowing via FRB, TT&L notes, Fed Funds, RPs and other sources
Includes items not shown separately
Annual ized percent change

u.s.

-

6.3
7.3
2.5
5.6
20.7
7.6
2.9
0.5
4.6
6.2
11.5
11.8
3.4
19.0

-

7.4
13.9