View original document

The full text on this page is automatically extracted from the file linked above and may contain errors and inconsistencies.

lli\((;;

cc:
(G)

January 9, 1981

GaugingFiscalPolicy: I
The incoming Reagan administration is
committed to cutting tax rates and nondefense expenditures, while increasing
defense expenditures. Lower tax rates would
strengthen incentives for suppliers of labor
and capital, and might therefore eventually
speed economic growth from the supply side.
Combined with lower expenditures, such tax
cuts also could ultimately be consistent with
a budget that does not preempt saving from
private capital formation. But the Federal
budget deficit may initially increase rather
than decrease, because of the lag that cou Id
be expected in bri ngi ng nondefense expenditures under control, at a time when defense
expenditures were being raised and taxes
were being reduced.
Even iftax cuts are successful in stimulating
economic growth from the supply side, fiscal
policy will continue to affect capital markets
and aggregate demand. Given the rather
large and uncertain budgetary changes in
prospect, we shou Id try to gauge the size of
these more trad itional impacts of fiscal pol icy
as the new Administration's program unfolds.
The generally accepted measure in this area
is the surplus or deficit in the highemployment budget -the size of the budget
surplus or deficit when the economy is operating at a "natural" (full employment) rate of
unemployment.
Unfortunately, this indicatoroffiscal policy is
subject to problems of both concept and
measurement. One important conceptual
problem is the question of what should be
included on both the expenditures and
receipts side of the budget. An equally serious
measurement problem relates to the need to
infer the natural rate of unemployment by
means of econometric modeling, since it is
not directly observable. In this article, we
examine the rationale of the highemployment budget and then consider the
differences'created by alternative assumptions about the natural rate of unemploy-

ment. In a second article, we consider certain
factors-additions to both the expenditures
and recei pts sides of the budget -that shou Id
be included in any such analysis.

Budgetrationale
Budget analysts introduced the concept of the
high-employment budget into policy discussions during the early 1960's, for the purpose
of separating the effect of the economy on the
Federal budget from the impact of discretionary fiscal-policy changes. Higher levels of
economic activity boost tax receipts and
reduce some expenditures, such as unemployment compensation; and lower activity
does the opposite. These induced changes in
receipts and expenditures act as automatic
stabilizers by helping to reduce the economy's response to any shift in total spending,
but they do not themselves represent independent sources of stimulus or restraint. By
measuring the budget surplus or deficit at a
constant rate of unemployment, analysts can
remove cyclically-induced changes in
expenditures and receipts from their calculations. The resulting surplus or deficit is a
rough measure of the budget's contractionary
or expansionary influence on the level of total
spending. A budgetary surplus indicates a
"tight" fiscal policy, in the sense that the
budget tends to add less to aggregate spending than it takes away, whereas a deficit
implies an "easy" fiscal policy in a reverse
sense.
Fiscal policy affects output and employment
in the short run-and by a multiple of the
deficit or surplus if monetary pol icy is accommodating by providing sufficient money to
stabilize interest rates. But if the Federal
Reserve instead holds to a fixed moneysupply target, the fiscal stimulus or restraint
has a much smaller impacton total spending,
and therefore on output and employment. In
the case of a deficit, the debt issues required
to finance the deficit bid up interest rates in
capital markets, which in turn discourage

IE1
©.\illl Ik\CGJ
IT
Opinions

eXDressed in this newsietter

do not

necessarily r'efiect the views of the management
of the Federal Reserve Bank of San Francisco,
nor 01 the Board of COV2nl<:}rS

of the Federai

economic activity faiis back to where It was
before. At this point, the increased fiscal
stimulus will be completely offset by the
decline in private investment spending
caused by higher interest rates. Even with
monetary accommodation of the stimulus,
additional money simply raises wages and
prices further, and does not affect output and
employment in the longer run.

private investment spending. On the other
hand, in the case of a budget surplus, the
lower interest rates induced by debt retirement stimulate private investment spending,
which provides some offset to the budget's
restrictive effect on aggregate spending.
However, with a given stock of money, the
investment-spending offset to fiscal stimulus
or restraint is less than complete in the shortrun. The resulting impact on total spending is
accommodated by movements in the
velocity of money ci rcu lation caused by the
changes in interest rates.

Consequently, the level of the highemployment budget measures the degree of
crowding out that can be expected if the
current fiscal policy is permanently maintained. A high-employment deficit registers
the average amount of credit that would be
preempted by the Federal budget. On the
other hand, a high-employment surplus
indicates the amountof private capital formation stimulated in the long run by the extra
credit made available through the retirement
of government debt.

From the point of view of short-run stabilization policy, the importantthing is not whether
the high-employment budget is currently in
surplus or deficit, but rather in what direction
the budget is moving. This is because most of
the effects of the current deficit or surplus on
current output and employment have al ready
been felt. Thus, a surplus in the highemployment budget doesn't mean that fiscal
policy is currently slowing the economy, but
only that it helped slow itdown in the past. In
short, the change in the high-employment
budget measures whether fiscal policy is
currently propelling the economy forward or
restraining it. Movement towards a lower
surplus or larger deficit indicates greater fiscal
stimulus-an easier policy tending to expand
current output and employment-and
the
reverse signifies a tighterfiscal policy tending
to slow economic activity.

Which unemploymentrate?
In theory, the high-employment budget
should be calculated on the basis of the
"natural" rate of unemployment, which is the
unemployment rate towards which the
economy gravitates in the long run. However,
this number is not directly observable, but
instead must be estimated. We know that the
natural rate of unemployment has tended to
rise over time as a consequence of a number
of changing demographic and legislative
factors, but we don't know the exact size of
the rate. The official calculation of the highemployment budget assumes an unemployment rate of 5.1 percent. However, recent
estimates by Phillip Cagan, RobertHall,
Alfred Tella and others suggest that the figure
actually should be in the range of 6.0 to 6.S
percent.

As indicated above, budget deficits can
"crowd out" a certain amount of private
capital formation even in the short run (before
wages and prices fully adjust), provided the
central bank holds to a fixed monetary target.
Over a longer period, an easier fiscal pol icy
(even with monetary accommodation)
doesn't stimulate output and employment at
all, but only creates an equal amount of
crowding out. For example, a shift to an
easier fiscal policy can expand output and
employmentfor a time. Butthe resulting pressure on wages and prices must lead to an
increased demand for a given stock of
money, which raises interest rates until

We can estimate the size of the highemployment budget at a 6.S-percent unemployment rate by linear interpolation from the
historical differences between the highemployment budget and the actual budget.
Raising the assumed natural rate to 6.5
percent substantially increases a deficit or
2

reduces a surplus (see chart). For example, in
1 979 the high-employment budget (nationalincome accounts basis) would have been in
deficit by $29.2 billion, compared to an officially recorded surplus of $6.9 billion. The
deficit has been understated in past years
also. The high-employment budget since
1 973 has generated an average annual deficit
of $33.7 billion, instead of the officially
calculated $7.6 billion average deficit. Since
the level of the high-employment budget
measu res the amou nt of permanent crowd ing
out, the budget as currently calculated
apparently greatly understates the extent of
discouragement of private capital formation.

in 1 974 and then easing in 1975. Both also
show a relatively neutral effect on aggregate
demand during the next two years, but show
tightening again in 1 978 and 1 979, and little
change in 1 980.
While the assumed unemployment rate
makes little difference to measured changes
in the degree of short-run fiscal stimulus or
restraint applied to aggregate spending, it can
have a substantial effect on the calculated
amount of credit permanently preempted by
the Federal budget. Indeed, the highemployment budget -measured at a
6.S-percent unemployment rate-indicated
about $29.5 billion of crowding out in 1 980.
This suggeststhat if the new administration
wishes to spur growth, it should take strong
steps to reduce expendit.ures or increase tax
receipts in order to el iminate th is cu rrent drag
on private capital formation. However, actual
crowding out would be of this magnitude
only if expenditures and receipts were
measured on a realistic conceptual basis.
These conceptual problems are examined in
our next Weekly Letter.

Changes in the high-employment budget, in
the short run, indicate changes in the degree
offiscal stimulus or restraint applied to aggregate demand, and in the longer run, indicate
changes in the amount of crowding out. But
the use of a more realistic unemployment rate
basically makes only a level adjustment, and
makes little difference in year-to-year
changes in the high-employment budget (see
chart). Both of these measures of the highemployment budget indicate fiscal tightening

$ Billions

AdrianW. Throop

HIGH EMPLOYMENT BUDGET

20

LEVELS
J-At 5.1% Unemployment

"..,.;',
'.......

.............

-20
..,.,/.-'

', -----------------

-40
40

------

----

At 6.5% Unemployment

ANNUAL CHANGES
"."'\

20

o
-20

"./

".

\

\ ...At 6.5% Unemployment

--

\

"

.......
,..,....

"\

/

/

;/

3

At 5.1%Unemployment-1'

u013U!ljSl:?M.ljl:?ln • uo3aJO • l:?pl:?i\aN
• oljl:?pl
!!l:?Ml:?H• l:?!UJOj!Il:?) l:?uozpV.
l:?>jSl:?IV

(G)

JJ
BANKINGDATA-TWELfTH FEDERAL
RESERVE
DISTRICT
(Dollaramountsin millions)
Selected
AssetsandLiabilities
largeCOO1mercial
Banks
Loans(gross,
adjusted)
andinvestments*
Loans(gross,
adjusted)- total#
Commercialandindustrial
Realestate
Loansto individuals
Securities
loans
U.s.Treasury
securities*
Othersecurities*
Demanddeposits- total#
Demanddeposits- adjusted
Savings
deposits- total
Timedeposits-total#
Individuals,part.& corp.
(Largenegotiable
CD's)
WeeklyAverages
of Daily Figures
MemberBankReserve
Position
Excess
Reserves
(+ )/Deficiency(-)
Borrowings
Netfreereserves
(+ )/Netborrowed(
-)

Amount
Outstanding

Change
from

12/24/80
146,510
124,223
36,959
49,985
24,144
1,496
6,689
15,598
46,298
32,253
27,619
73,618
63,772
29,451

12/17/80
196
200
90
70
207
173
37
33
109
- 757
807
2,639
2,139
1,390

Changefrom
yearago
Dollar
Percent

-

-

Weekended

Weekended

12/24/80

12/17/80

8,077
8,700
3,365
6,671
297
252
590
33
2
1,610
889
14,630
13,642
7,610

5.8
7.5
10.0
15.4
1.2
20.3
8.1
0.2
0.0
4.8
3.1
24.8
27.2
34.8

Comparable
year-ago
period

n.a.

n.a.

28

130

127

64

n.a.

n.a.

35

* Excludes
tradingaccountsecurities.
# Includesitemsnotshownseparately.
Editorialcommentsmaybe addressed
to the editor(WilliamBurke)or to theauthor.... Freecopiesof this
andotherFederalReserve
publications
canbeobtainedbycallingor writingthePublicInformationSection,
FederalReserve
Bankof SanFrancisco,
P.O.Box7702,SanFrancisco
94120.Phone(415)544-2184.

11
I C@I