View original document

The full text on this page is automatically extracted from the file linked above and may contain errors and inconsistencies.

II

JE1
'5"\

\"::=:::2J
(Q..'o,
II

(\J)

1: r'
C'"
-,\;-..:7"""",

b

1J,

1f"r7V

C9.111
D,\&

0
11'"

/f\i 1(\'

I..\»

March 17, 1978

Fully Employed?
Unemployment has declined from 7.6
to 6.1 percent of the civilian labor
force over the past year (FebruaryFebruary). Meanwhile, Congress has
moved closer to passage of the Humphrey-Hawkins bill, which is aimed at
reducing the rate further to 4.0
percent by 1983. Yet the continuing
controversy over that legislation still
leaves unsettled the question of how
close we are to the full-employment
unemployment rate - that is, the lowest jobless rate under the existing institutional structure that will not result in
accelerated inflation. Estimates differ
Widely, but our analysis suggests that
we are fast approaching full employment, or perhaps are already there.
Fl E U R-then and now
Both the Ford and the Carter Councils
of Economic Advisers have calculated
the fUll-employment unemployment
rate (FEUR)at 4.9 percent - a figure
comparable in labor-market tightness
to a 4.0-percent rate in the mid1950's. The present Council, in fact,
uses that 4.9-percent figure to calculate the potential output of the national
economy. But both Councils have
agreed that certain factors in the current market could push the rate to 5.5
percent or even higher. For that matter, some analysts claim that the mid1950's level of the FEURwas actually
closer to 4.6 or 4.8 percent than to 4.0
percent. Thus, depending on our assumption of the correct level of the
mid-1950's, we could argue that inflationary pressures would be generated

by a jobless rate below the range of
5.6 to 6.3 percent.
Until recently, most economists began
their calculations with the assumption
that inflation pressures had not risen in
the mid-1950's until the unemployment rate fell below 4.0 percent. But
Philip Cagan (Contemporary Economic Problems, 1977) now estimates a
non-inflationary rate for that period at
4.6 to 4.8 percent, and Franco Modigliani and Lucas Papademos (New England Economic Review, Marchi April
1976) estimate the initial FEURat 4.8
percent. These authors, using a Phillipscurve approach, argue that inflationary pressures were evident in the mid1950's at rates well above the publicized 4.0-percent figure. By adopting
their estimates for that earlier period,
we begin with a much higher benchmark than most analysts had previousIyassumed.

Why higher now?
But whatever the FEURmay have been
two decades ago, the rate is much
higher today because of a number of
changing demographic and legislative
factors. First is the shift in the composition of the labor force, with the sharp
expansion of those groups (young
workers and women workers) who
exhibit the highest jobless rates. This
shift, according to Cagan, boosted the
FEURby .46 percentage point over the
past two decades. Another .34 percentage point could be added because
of the several extensions of coverage

(continued on page 2)

of unemployment insurance, which
have helped increase the duration of
unemployment and hence the overall
unemployment rate. The largest impact of this type was the extension of
coverage to seasonalworkers in 1975.
An even more important factor, according to our calculations, is the liberalization of unemployment-insurance
benefits, which may have boosted the
FEURby .55 percentage point. Expanded benefits have tended to increase
the number of people who want to
enter or remain in the labor force.
Consequently, for any given level of
aggregate demand, the system
generates a larger labor force and a
higher unemployment rate than·
would otherwise exist. The liberalization of the program can be measured
by the sharp increase over time in the
ratio of jobless benefits - which are
not taxed - to workers' average
spendable earnings.

decades ago. The recent expansion of
manpower programs could lower the
FEURby .30 percentage point, because
of improvements in job training and
job placement. Another .10 percentage point reduction could be due to
response error in the survey, such as
when a person being interviewed mistakenly tells the survey interviewer that
another person in the household
failed to look for work in the survey
period.
Other evidence
Because of all the factors cited here,
the full-employment unemployment
rate today may be in the range of 5.6
to 6.3 percent, instead of the 4.9-5.5
percent range cited by the Council of
Economic Advisers. In any event, the
higher range appears more reasonable than the lower range in any recent
comparison of the "unemployment
gap'"- the difference between the
measured jobless rate and the FEURand the "capacity gap the difference between the measured capacity- .
utilization index and the full-capacity
level of 87.5 percent. With the use of
the higher FEUR,the unemploymentgap and capacity-gap relationships are
brought into line with the
experience of the early-to-mid-1960's .
N

A further increase of .50 percentage
point in the FEURcan be attributed to
legislated increases in the minimum
wage, which tend to increase joblessness among young unskilled workers
because their efforts are not worth
the higher mandated wage. Another
.20 percentage point may be added
by the work-registration requirement
for welfare
- individuals who
might not otherwise be counted as
jobless because they wouldn't be
looking for work.
In contrast, several factors could tend
to lower the full-employment jobless
rate, in relation to the level of two

2

-

Other signs of a tighter labor market
are provided by employment data,
which are much stronger at this stage
of the business expansion than they
were at the comparable stages of the
four preceding cycles. Total employment has expanded at a 3.5-percent
annual rate since the trough of this cycle, compared with a 2.5-percent average gain for the several preceding
cycles. The ratio of employment to

6.3%

Percent

6

5

4

5.6 % .k Shift -labor force composition
Extended unempl. insurance
Liberalized U I benefits
.k'increased minimum wage
k

_

A:-

.:.:.:.:.:.:.:.:.:.:.:

.

3
2
Full-employment

1

. - - -

..

_- - - - - - - - - - - - - - - - _. _- - - - -

adult population has risen by 1.9 percentage points over this expansion,
compared with a gain of 0.8 percentage point for the average of earlier
cyclical expansions. Most importantly,
the rise in employment to a record 58
percent of the adult population suggests a fairly rapid move toward full
employment.
All these signs suggest that the economy is much stronger than commonly
believed. If the economy is fully employed with a jobless rate between
5.6 and 6.3 percent, further stimulus
might only lead to more inflation without solving the real structural problems
of unemployment. Thus, this high level of the FEURgives policymakers
much less room for maneuver than
they might have expected in 1978.
What FlEURfor the future?
Forecasting the full-employment jobless rate is somewhat simplified by the
fact that the future composition of our
working-age population (16 years and
over) is largely known today, barring
any unusual behavior in mortality
and/ or immigration. And our population is aging. Between 1980 and 1985,
the number of youths (1 6-24) will decline in absolute numbers as well as a
of the working-age population. This aging trend will tend to
lower the overall unemployment rate,
since young workers have higherthan-average unemployment rates. But
whether the future FEURwill actually
decline depends also on labor-force
participation rates and other factors.
If participation rates remain constant
between now and 1985, the FEUR
could decline perhaps a full percentage
3

point, according to a recent study prepared for the National Commission on
Manpower Policy. If, on the other
hand, participation rates increase in line
with recent trends, the FEURdecline
could be closer to a half-percentage
point by 1985 ..
But several caveats must be kept in
mind. The female labor-force participation rate has recently risen far above
trend. If this development continues,
the future FEURcould rise above forecast because of the tendency for females to exhibit higher-than-average
unemployment rates. Again, the future FEURcould rise if public assistance,
unemployment compensation and
other transfer payments increase - in
relation to spendable wages - at
more than their past average pace. Unemployment can also be affected in
the other direction. The FEURcould fall
below the projected 1985
if the
government introduces effective manpower programs which cure structural
labor-supply problems and don't simply replace workers already employed.
Given all these changes in the composition of the labor force and in the institutional framework, by the mid-1 980's
the full-employment unemployment
rate could decline perhaps 0.5 to 1.0
percentage points below the present
range of 5.6 to 6.3 percent. However,
successfully-executed manpower pro;,.
grams are essential if we are to
achieve the goal of the HumphreyHawkins bill- 4.0 percent by 1 983without.generating new inflationary
pressures.
Rose McElhattan

!!l?Ml?H

0
0 uo8aJO • l?pl?AaN • oLjl?PI
l?!UJoJ!ll?)
l?uozlJV
e>jsl?IV

C\S)

'J!I1?:J
IOJSpUi! J;! Ui! S
ZSL'ON 11W1Bd
GI\ld
39\11 50d 's'n
11\1W SS\ll:J 15111::1

BANKINGDATA-TWELFTHFEDERAL
RESERVE
DISTRICT
(Dollar amountsin millions)
Selected Assetsand liabilities
LargeCommercial Banks

Amount
Outstanding
3/1178

Loans(gross,adjusted)and investments*
Loans(gross,adjusted)- total
Securityloans
Commercialand industrial
Realestate
Consumerinstalment
U.s. Treasurysecurities
Other securities
Deposits(lesscashitems)- total*
Demand deposits(adjusted)
U.s. Government deposits
Time deposits- total*
Statesand political subdivisions
Savingsdeposits
Other time depositsi
LargenegotiableCD's

105,928
83,896
1,747
25,845
28,289
14,921
7,716
14,316
103,236
28,299
579
72,517
6,520
31,353
32,040
13,924

Weekly Averages
of Daily figures

Week enqed
3/1178

Member Bank ReservePosition
ExcessReserves(+)/Deficiency(-)
Borrowings
Net free(+)/Net borrowed (-)
federal funds-Seven LargeBanks
InterbankFeder.alfund transactions
Net purchases(+)/Net sales(-)
Transactionswith US. security dealers
Net loans (+ )/Net borrowings (-)

Change
from
2122178
+
+

+
+
+
+
+
+
+
+

-

+
+

-

+
+

767
614
25
308
104
47
48
105
1,056
748
5
460
33
99
357
629

Changefrom
year ago
Dollar
Percent
+ 13,162 +
+ 12,790 .+
+ 230 +
+ 2,554 +
+ 6,260
+
+ 2,524
+
1,052
+ 1,424
+
+ 11,159 +
+ 2,278 . +
313
+
+
+ 8,326
+
852
+
+
118
+
+
+ 6,693
+
+ 5,159 +

-

Week ended
2122178

14.19
17.99
15.16
10.97
28.42
20.36
12.00
11.05
12.12
8.75
117.67
12.97
15.03
0.38
26.41
58.86

Comparable
year-agoperiod
9
2
11

279
23
302

211
22
233

+ 1,132

+ 1,535

+

302

285

+

68

+

370

+

*Includesitems not shown separately.tlndividuals, partnershipsand corporations.
Editorial comments may be addressedto the editor (William Burke) or to the author, , , .
Information on this and other publications can be obtained by calling or writing the Public Information
Section,federalReserveBankof SanFrancisco,P,O. Box 7702,Sanfrancisco 94120,Phone(415) 544-2184.