View original document

The full text on this page is automatically extracted from the file linked above and may contain errors and inconsistencies.

FRBSF Economic Letter
2023-03 | February 6, 2023

Research from
the Federal Reserve
Bank of San Francisco

Financial Market Conditions during Monetary Tightening
Simon H. Kwan and Louis Liu
The current round of federal funds rate increases is expected to reverse a historically large gap
between the real funds rate and the neutral rate at the beginning of the tightening cycle. Financial
markets have reacted faster and more strongly than in past monetary tightening cycles, in part
because of this large gap and the Federal Reserve’s forward guidance. Historical experiences
suggest financial conditions could tighten even more given the size of the gap.

Financial markets play a central role in how business cycles fluctuate and spread through the U.S. economy.
As monetary policy works through various transmission channels to impact real economic activity, financial
market channels are first and foremost in determining both the speed and the extent of policy transmission
(Bernanke, Gertler, and Gilchrist 1999). Thus, understanding how much financial conditions have tightened
provides important feedback for calibrating monetary policy.
In past monetary tightening episodes, the degree of tightening in overall financial conditions depended on
how much and how long monetary tightening continued, as well as prevailing economic conditions when
tightening began. Specifically, the extent of monetary tightening depends on inflationary pressures and how
strong the economy is when tightening starts. In past cycles, federal funds rate increases ranged from about 1
percentage point (1965–66) to over 10 percentage points (1977–80).
This Economic Letter compares the size and the speed of financial market responses between current and
past cycles of monetary tightening. We focus on analyzing long-term interest rates, stock prices, and credit
spreads because they directly affect the cost of capital and thus real economic activity. Since the current
tightening cycle is likely still ongoing, the financial market response could still change substantially.
Nevertheless, comparing current financial market changes to those during previous tightening cycles sheds
light on the speed of adjustment.

Monetary tightening cycles
Figure 1 shows the 15 postwar monetary tightening cycles. The first 11 cycles are identified following the
methodology in Adrian and Estrella (2008). This assumes that a tightening cycle starts when the federal
funds rate rises by 0.25 percentage point (25 basis points) or more in two consecutive months. A tightening
cycle ends when either (1) the federal funds rate is higher than at any time from 12 months before to 9

FRBSF Economic Letter 2023-03 | February 6, 2023
months after and is at least 0.5
percentage point higher than at the
beginning of this period, or (2) the
federal funds rate is higher than at any
time from 6 months before to 6 months
after and is 1.5 percentage points higher
than the average at these end points.

Figure 1
Effective federal funds rate
Percent
20
18
16
14
12

Since the late 1990s, forward guidance
10
became a prominent monetary policy
8
tool (Bernanke 2020). We therefore
6
identify the tightening cycles based on
4
the Federal Open Market Committee
2
(FOMC) communications, as financial
0
markets are always forward looking. For
1974
1984
1994
2004
2014
1954
1964
example, forward-looking language first
Source: Federal Reserve Board of Governors and authors’ calculations.
Note: Blue shading indicates periods of monetary policy tightening as described in text.
appeared in the post-meeting FOMC
press release in May 1999. Although the Committee decided not to raise rates at that meeting, the postmeeting press release signaled the FOMC’s bias toward the possibility of a firming in the stance of monetary
policy. We therefore assume the 1999-2000 tightening cycle started in May, even though the policy rate did
not increase until June.
For the current tightening cycle, the Committee expected after its January 2022 meeting that “it will soon be
appropriate to raise the target range for the federal funds rate.” In the December 2022 FOMC Summary of
Economic Projections (SEP), the median projection of the federal funds rate for 2023 by FOMC participants
was 5.1%, compared to 4.4% for 2022. In this Letter, we make the straightforward assumption that the
federal funds rate will reach 5.1% about the middle of this year, based on the contour of the federal funds
futures. Hence, the current tightening cycle is assumed to last from January 2022 to May 2023, lifting the
federal funds rate from 0.08% to 5.1%.

The federal funds rate
Each tightening cycle has been unique in terms of the duration and the change in the federal funds rate. Not
all tightening cycles have been followed by recessions. The median increase in the federal funds rate in past
tightening cycles was 2.57 percentage points, and the median pace of tightening was 0.20 percentage point
per month. For the current cycle, based on the SEP projections, the expected tightening is 5.02 percentage
points at an average pace of 0.31 percentage point per month, both of which are well above the median.
To control for monetary conditions at the onset of tightening, we compute the real funds rate gap by
subtracting the inflation rate and the real neutral rate from the nominal federal funds rate. The smaller or
more negative the real funds rate gap is, the more monetary accommodation is in the economy. We use the
past 12-month change in the consumer price index (CPI) to measure the inflation rate. Although current CPI
2

FRBSF Economic Letter 2023-03 | February 6, 2023
inflation is an imperfect proxy for expected inflation, the Survey of Professional Forecasters’ expected oneyear-ahead inflation rate, which did not start until 1980, provides qualitatively similar results for the last six
tightening cycles. We use the real neutral rate estimated by Laubach and Williams (2003). For the current
cycle, we use a real neutral rate of 0.5%,
Figure 2
which is the difference between the
Real funds rate gap: Initial levels and changes over cycle
median long-run funds rate of 2.5% from
Percentage points
the December SEP and the 2% target
10
inflation rate.
Start of cycle
Change over cycle
5

Figure 2 shows the real funds rate gap
(blue bars) at the beginning of each
0
tightening cycle. The real funds rate gap
of –7.9% at the beginning of the current
cycle is the largest among all tightening
-5
cycles, in part due to high inflation.
Figure 2 also shows the difference in the
-10
Dec Dec Apr Feb Mar Apr Feb Jul Mar Feb May May Dec Jan
real funds rate gap between the end and
1965 1968 1971 1972 1974 1977 1981 1983 1988 1994 1999 2004 2016 2022
the beginning of each tightening cycle—
-Nov -Aug -Aug -Sep -Jul -Apr -Jun -Aug -Mar -Apr -Jul -Jul -Feb -May
which reflects how much the gap was
1966 1969 1971 1973 1974 1980 1981 1984 1989 1995 2000 2006 2019 2023
Source:
Laubach and Williams (2003), Bureau of Labor Statistics, Federal Reserve Board
closed (green bars). Assuming the
of Governors and authors’ calculations.
inflation rate at the end of the current
Note: Last cycle includes assumptions based on December 2022 SEP projections.
tightening cycle will be 3.1% based on the
December SEP, the real funds rate gap at the end of the current cycle would be 1.5%. If the Fed successfully
closes the funds rate gap by 9.4% by the end of the current cycle—through both raising the interest rate and
bringing down inflation—it would be the largest gap closure on record.

Long-term rates and stock prices
The current increase in the 10-year Treasury rate is the second largest increase of all tightening cycles,
shown by the blue bars in Figure 3. Moreover, the green bars show that the speed of this increase has been
unprecedented. Research shows that the response of asset prices to anticipated monetary policy changes is
essentially zero, while their response to unanticipated movements is large and highly significant (Kuttner
2000). Thus, before forward guidance, each monetary policy tightening may have contained unanticipated
information that had not been fully incorporated into asset prices; therefore, without advance
communication, financial markets would have reacted to each tightening until the cycle ended.
With forward guidance, market participants can form expectations about tightening cycles, including the
expected duration and amount of tightening. Because the expected tightening is fully incorporated into asset
prices well before the completion of the tightening cycle, this partially explains the speed of the increase in
long-term rates in the current cycle.

3

FRBSF Economic Letter 2023-03 | February 6, 2023
A widely held view by economists is that
long-term interest rates tend to have
relatively bigger effects on real economic
activities than short-term rates. This is in
part due to the large share of long-term
debt contracts with a fixed interest rate
in our financial system, including fixedrate mortgages, term loans, and
corporate bonds, whose rates are often
tied to long-term Treasury rates. Thus,
the rapid increase in long-term rates
would cool the economy relatively faster
than in previous cycles.
The contract interest rate above the
Treasury rate, known as the spread, is
another determinant of financial
conditions. The spread reflects the risk
premium demanded by the lender in
providing debt financing to risky
borrowers. In past tightening cycles,
bond spreads haven’t always tightened,
and the median change in the benchmark
Baa bond spread was close to zero.
Currently, the Baa spread has widened
only about 0.06 percentage point, which
is small relative to the large increase in
the long-term Treasury rate.

Figure 3
Percentage point changes in 10-year Treasury yield
Percentage point
0.8

Percentage points
3.5
Total change (left
scale)
3
Average monthly
change (right scale)
2.5

Median total change =
0.48 percentage point

0.6

2
0.4
1.5
1

0.2

0.5
0

Dec Dec
1965 1968
-Nov -Aug
1966 1969

Apr
1971
-Aug
1971

Feb
1972
-Sep
1973

Mar
1974
-Jul
1974

Apr
1977
-Apr
1980

Feb
1981
-Jun
1981

Jul
1983
-Aug
1984

Mar
1988
-Mar
1989

Feb
1994
-Apr
1995

May
1999
-Jul
2000

May
2004
-Jul
2006

Dec
2016
-Feb
2019

0

Jan
2022
-Dec
2022

Source: Federal Reserve Board of Governors and authors’ calculations.

Figure 4
Percent changes in Standard & Poor’s 500
Percent

Percent
25
20
15

Total change (left scale)
Average monthly change (right scale)
Median % change = 2.53%

4
3

10

2

5

1

0

0

-5

-1

-10

-2

-15

-3

In previous tightening episodes, stock
-20
Sep Aug Dec Dec Apr Feb Mar Apr Feb Jul Mar Feb May May Dec Jan
prices initially fell but sometimes
1955 1958 1965 1968 1971 1972 1974 1977 1981 1983 1988 1994 1999 2004 2016 2022
-Oct -Nov -Nov -Aug -Aug -Sep -Jul -Apr -Jun -Aug -Mar -Apr -Jul -Jul -Feb -Dec
rebounded to end the tightening cycle
1956 1959 1966 1969 1971 1973 1974 1980 1981 1984 1989 1995 2000 2006 2019 2022
with a net gain. Figure 4 shows that stock
Source: Bloomberg, Federal Reserve Board of Governors and authors’ calculations.
prices declined on net in five of the past
15 tightening episodes. The median change in the Standard & Poor’s 500 in previous cycles was +2.53%.
Both the current decline in stock prices and the speed of the decline, as measured by the average monthly
change in stock prices, are large relative to the historical average. Stock valuations, such as the price-toearnings ratio, exhibit similar patterns.
Comparing the current changes in bond rates and stock prices to those in previous completed tightening
cycles that lasted longer reflects the notion that forward guidance has front-loaded the financial market
4

5

-4

FRBSF Economic Letter 2023-03 | February 6, 2023
response in the current cycle. This is consistent with the stance of monetary policy being tighter than what is
implied by the federal funds rate (Choi et al. 2022). Repeating the analysis to control for cycle duration
yields qualitatively similar results.

Insights from the past
What can we learn from history to understand how financial conditions could play out through the end of
this tightening cycle? The historical relation between monetary conditions at the onset of tightening cycles
and tightening in interest rates and stock prices may provide some clues. Regressing the real funds rate gap
on the change in the federal funds rate yields a significantly negative relationship: a more negative real funds
rate gap tends to be followed by a bigger increase in the federal funds rate. Given the large negative real
funds rate gap in the current cycle, history suggests that the total increase in the federal funds rate could be
bigger than expected.
Regressing the real funds rate gap on the change in stock prices yields a significantly positive relationship,
implying that the more negative the real funds rate gap, the larger the decline in stock prices during a
tightening cycle. When we use this historical relationship to evaluate stock prices at the large negative funds
rate gap, stock prices are projected to decline further. The historical relationship between the funds rate gap
and bond spreads also calls for more tightening in the bond market. Taken together, with the historically
large funds rate gap at the onset of the current cycle, past experiences indicate that more tightening of
financial conditions could follow.

Conclusions
Current increases in the federal funds rate are expected to reverse a historically large negative real funds rate
gap at the beginning of the cycle. Successfully closing the real funds rate gap will hinge on substantially
reducing the inflation rate. Relative to history, both the size and the speed of tightening in Treasury bonds
and common stocks have been large in the current cycle, in part because of the large gap and the Federal
Reserve’s forward guidance. While the rapid tightening of financial conditions is expected to slow the
economy relatively quickly, historical experiences raise the possibility of even more tightening in financial
conditions given the large real rate gap that needs to be closed.

Simon H. Kwan
Senior Research Advisor, Economic Research Department, Federal Reserve Bank of San Francisco

Louis Liu
Research Associate, Economic Research Department, Federal Reserve Bank of San Francisco

References
Adrian, Tobias, and Arturo Estrella. 2008. “Monetary Tightening Cycles and the Predictability of Economic Activity.”
Economics Letters 99(2), pp. 260–264.
Bernanke, Ben S. 2020. “The New Tools of Monetary Policy.” American Economic Review 110(4, April), pp. 943–983.

5

FRBSF Economic Letter 2023-03 | February 6, 2023

Bernanke, Ben S., Mark Gertler, and Simon Gilchrist. 1999. “The Financial Accelerator in a Quantitative Business Cycle
Framework.” Chapter 21 in Handbook of Macroeconomics 1, part C, eds. J.B. Taylor and M. Woodford. Amsterdam:
Elsevier, pp. 1,341–1,393.
Choi, Jason, Taeyoung Doh, Andrew Foerster, and Zinnia Martinez. 2022. “Monetary Policy Stance Is Tighter than Federal
Funds Rate.” FRBSF Economic Letter 2022-30 (November 7).
Kuttner, Kenneth N. 2001. “Monetary Policy Surprises and Interest Rates: Evidence from the Fed Funds Futures Market.”
Journal of Monetary Economics 47(3, June), pp. 523–544.
Laubach, Thomas, and John C. Williams. 2003. “Measuring the Natural Rate of Interest.” Review of Economics and Statistics
85(4, November), pp. 1,063–1,070.

Opinions expressed in FRBSF Economic Letter do not necessarily reflect the views of the
management of the Federal Reserve Bank of San Francisco or of the Board of Governors of the
Federal Reserve System. This publication is edited by Anita Todd and Karen Barnes. Permission to
reprint portions of articles or whole articles must be obtained in writing. Please send editorial
comments and requests for reprint permission to research.library@sf.frb.org

Recent issues of FRBSF Economic Letter are available at
https://www.frbsf.org/economic-research/publications/economic-letter/
2023-02 Rodríguez-Clare / Supply Chain Disruptions, Trade Costs, and Labor Markets
Ulate /
https://www.frbsf.org/economic-research/publications/economicVasquez
letter/2023/january/supply-chain-disruptions-trade-costs-and-labor-markets/
2023-01 Beauregard /
Christensen /
Fischer /
Zhu

Are Inflation Expectations Well Anchored in Mexico?
https://www.frbsf.org/economic-research/publications/economic-letter/2023/january/
are-inflation-expectations-well-anchored-in-mexico/

2022-36 Mertens

Recession Prediction on the Clock
https://www.frbsf.org/economic-research/publications/economicletter/2022/december/recession-prediction-on-clock/

2022-35 Paul

When the Fed Raises Rates, Are Banks Less Profitable?
https://www.frbsf.org/economic-research/publications/economicletter/2022/december/when-fed-raises-rates-are-banks-less-profitable/

2022-34 Miyamoto/
Nguyen /
Sergeyev

Oil Shocks when Interest Rates Are at the Zero Lower Bound
https://www.frbsf.org/economic-research/publications/economicletter/2022/november/oil-shocks-when-interest-rates-are-at-zero-lower-bound/

2022-33 Daly

Resolute and Mindful: The Path to Price Stability
https://www.frbsf.org/economic-research/publications/economicletter/2022/november/resolute-and-mindful-path-to-price-stability/