View original document

The full text on this page is automatically extracted from the file linked above and may contain errors and inconsistencies.

FRBSF

WEEKLY LETTER

Number 93-21, May 28, 1993

Federal Reserve Independence
and the Accord of 1951
Since the establishment of the Federal Reserve
System in 1913, the Fed's relationship with both
Congress and the President has gone through
many phases, and proposals to change this relationship, or the way the Fed conducts monetary
policy, have appeared frequently in Congress. For
example, Congress amended the Federal Reserve
Act in 1977 to require the Fed to establish money
supply targets and to report those targets to Congress every six months. In the early 1980s, legislation was introduced, but not passed, that
would have requrred the Fed to establish targets
for real interest rates. Other proposals have focused less on the actual implementations and
more on the ultimate objectives of monetary policy. For instance, four years ago, Representative
Neal (D) held hearings on a bill that would have
established zero inflation as the official, and sole,
pol icy objective for the conduct of monetary
policy.
In contrast to these earlier legislative attempts to
affect either the Fed's objectives or its implementation of policy, Senator Sarbanes (D) of Maryland
and Representative Gonzalez (D) of Texas have
proposed changing the structure of monetary
policy decisionmaking. The intent of their proposals is to provide greater political control over
the conduct of monetary policy by increasing the
role of the President in determining who makes
the decisions about monetary policy.
During other episodes in the Federal Reserve's
history, Congress has supported moves designed
to increase the Fed's independence from Executive Branch influence. One of the most important
of these moves occurred in 1951. In March of that
year, the Federal Reserve System and the
Treasury reached an agreement, known as the
Accord, that recognized the independence of the
Federal Reserve to conduct monetary policy. In
the Fed's negotiations with the Treasury, the Fed
was bolstered by Congressional support for an
independent monetary policy. The modern conduct of discretionary monetary policy in the
United States can be dated from the Accord.

u.s.

The pre-Accord period
During the decade before the 1951 Accord, Federal Reserve actions were dominated by considerations arising from the government's World War
II financing needs. The Treasury, faced with the
need to raise funds far in excess of tax receipts in
order to finance the war effort, wanted to keep
interest rates on government securities at low
levels. The Treasury view was supported by the
Federal Reserve, and the Fed adopted an explicit
policy of supporting the government bond market. Particularly during 1942 to 1945 when the
government was engaging in massive borrowing,
this was clearly an important consideration. As
expressed by G.L. Bach, "In this period, Federal
Reserve and Treasury officials agreed, with perhaps more patriotic fervor than foresight, that
there must be no shortage of money to buy the
weapons of war .. ." (Bach 1971, p. 78). In April
1942, the Fed announced that it would maintain
the rate on 90 day government bills at % percent. It did so for the next 5 years.
Whenever a central bank adopts a policy of pegging market interest rates, it gives up control over
the supply of money. If the pegged rates are set
too low, private sector demand for new government debt issues will be too small to take up the
entire issue. To prevent bond prices from falling
(and yields rising), the Fed must serve as the
residual purchaser. In so doing, the Fed automatically increases the reserves of the banking system, allowing an expansion of the money supply.
If the pegged rates are set too high, there will be
an excess private sector demand for government
securities, and the Fed must sell from its own
portfolio of government security holdings in order to prevent interest rates from falling. In the
process, banking sector reserves are reduced,
leading to a fall in the supply of money.
The Fed continued to support bond prices after
the war for several reasons. First, the policy facilitated government borrowing. The low interest
rates reduced the cost of government borrowing,
the Fed commitment ensured that the Treasury

FABSF
could always sell its new bond issues since the
Fed served as the residual purchaser, and, by
insuring the market against capital losses that
would occur if interest rates rose, the bond support program increased the overall demand for
government debt. Second, any increase in interest rates on government debt would also raise
interest rates faced by private borrowers, thereby
resulting in reduced private sector investment
and increased unemployment. This concern
reflected the fears of a postwar recession. Third,
it was argued that a rise in interest rates was an
ineffectual means of combating inflation.
Inthe immediate postwar period, the Federal
Reserve was increasingly concerned about its
inability to preventinflation as long as it was required to support the price of government debt.
With the Consumer Price Index rising more than
14 percent during 1947 and nearly 8 percent during 1948, the Fed believed it needed to control
money and credit growth. The Treasury continued to argue that low interest rates were necessary to maintain confidence in government credit
and to hold down the cost of government debt,
and that controlling the money supply was not
necessarily an effective means of reducing inflation. Tensions rose between the Federal Reserve
and the Treasury over the Fed's desire to establish monetary control. Marriner Eccles, who had
been appointed Chairman of the Board of Governors in 1934 and who openly argued against the
bond support policy, was not reappointed by
President Truman in 1948.
As long as the Fed supported the prices of longterm government debt, holders of the debt could
view these assets as very liquid. With the bill rate
held to 3Ja percent since 1942 while the ceiling
on long-term government securities was a much
higher 2Yz percent,there was little demand for
Treasury bills, Ofthe $16 billion in bills outstanding in 1947, the Fed held $15.5 billion. In the
middle of 1947, the Fed allowed the bill rate to
rise. One consequence of the rate increase was a
rise in the Fed's interest income on the Treasury
bills itheld. To ensure Treasury support for the
rate increase, the Fed agreed to turn over 90 percent of its revenue to the Treasury.
In June, 1948, the Federal Open Market Committee, the Fed's policymaking committee, and the
Treasury announced that the FOMC would direct
open market operations " ... with primary regard to the general business and credit situation"

(Federal Reserve Bulletin, 35, July 1949, p. 776).
Fed Chairman Thomas McCabe considered this
announcementto constitute " ... the removal of
the strait jacket in which monetary policy has
been operating for nearly a decade ... :' At the
time, however, the concern was with the economic recession that developed in late 1948.
Unemployment rose from 3.8 percent in 1948 to
5.9 percent in 1949, and prices actually declined
by 1 percent in 1949. Consequently, the FOMCTreasury agreement was an agreement to lower
interest rates in an attempt to stimulate the economy. It was unclear whether the Fed would have
the flexibility to raise interest rates if the problem
became one of inflation. In Congressional testimony in 1949, the Treasury Secretary made clear
that his interpretation was that the 2Y2 percent
rate on new long-term government securities
would not rise.
The confl ict between the Treasury and the Fed
over interest rate policy led, in 1949, to Congressional hearings on the subject headed by
Senator Paul Douglas of Illinois. At this time,
Congress was generally viewed as supporting the
Fed in its conflicts with the Treasury. According
to Stein (1969, p. 258), the hearings " ... made
it clear that any attempt to bring the Federal
Reserve forcibly to heel would encounter considerable resistance in the Congress, and that the
resistance would have leadership and principles
to which there would be a popular response:'
The Douglas reportconcluded that the benefits
of avoiding inflation were great enough to justify
giving the Federal Reserve the freedom to raise
interest rates, even at the cost of a rise in the cost
of federal debt.

The Accord
In 1950, with the recession over, inflation and the
need for monetary restraint onCe more became
a policy concern. During January and February
1951, the Treasury attempted to bind the Fed to
the maintenance of low interest rates through
public announcements. The Secretary of the
Treasury, John Snyder, announced that consultations with President Truman and the Chairman of
the Federal Reserve Board had led to a decision
that new long-term debt issues would continue to
be offered at a 2Yz percent interest rate, a view
apparently not shared by the Fed. When Fed disagreement became known, President Truman
called the entire FOMC to a White House meeting to discuss policy. The White House and the
Treasury then announced that the Fed would

continue to support government bond prices.
Eccles, who was still a member of the Board of
Governors, then released the Fed's confidential
minutes of the White House meeting, minutes
that contradicted the White House and Treasury
claims of a Fed commitment to keep rates fixed.
As a result of these public disputes, the Fed
asked the President to initiate negotiations between the Treasury and the Federal Reserve.
While the President established a formal committee to resolve the issues of conflict, the actual
"accord" between the two institutions was
worked out directly between Federal Reserve and
Treasury officials. On March 4, 1951, the Accord
was announced to the public: "The Treasury and
the Federal Reserve System have reached full
accord with respect to debt-management and
monetary policies to be pursued in furthering
their common purpose to assure the successful
financing of the Government's requirements and,
at the same time, to minimize monetization of
the public debt" (Federal Reserve Bulletin,
March 1951, p. 267).
Despite the current view that the Accord enhanced the Fed's ability to conduct an independent monetary policy, the language of the Accord
did not specifically address the issue of conflict~would the Fed be expected to continue to
support bond prices? In fact, at the time many
commentators felt the Accord was not the final
resolution of the Treasury-Fed disagreements.
However, it soon became clear that the Fed had
in fact been freed from its obligation to support
the price of government bonds.

necessary separation for controlling the money
supply and for providing the Fed the means for
controlling inflation.
Did the Accord actually give the Fed independence from the Executive Branch to conduct monetary policy? At the end of March 1951, just three
weeks after the Accord was announced, President
Truman appointed William McChesney Martin,·
the Treasury official who had negotiated the
Accord for the Treasury" as Chairman of the Federal Reserve Board, a position he held until 1970.
Martin made clear, however, his view that the
Federal Reserve was an independent agency of
government, responsible to the Congress.
It is important that monetary policy be unconstrained by debt management considerations.
Requiring the Fed to maintain interest rates at
levels that are too low runs the risk of increased
inflation. The conflict between the Fed and the
Treasury that led to the 1951 Accord did, according to Stein, serve a useful purpose: "If monetary
policy had floated free of the [interest rate] pegs
without a direct confrontation, the importance
of flexible monetary policy might never have
become so clear as it did to large numbers of
people, and the Federal Reserve wou Id not have
been left with so vivid a reminder of the dangers
of compromising its independence" (Stein 1969,
p.278).

Carl E. Walsh
Professor of Economics
University of Calif., Santa Cruz
and
Visiting Scholar
Federal Reserve Bank of
San Francisco

After the Accord
Interest rates gradually rose during the two years
following the Accord, and market interest rates
became much more volatile as the Fed was now
able to pursue more activist policies. However,
Shiller (1980) shows that once short-term interest
rates on commercial paper were corrected for
inflation, real interest rates actually became
much less volatile over the 20 years following the
Accord. More importantly for the longer-term
conduct of
monetary policy, the Accord separated the determination of debt-management
policy from that of monetary policy. This was a

u.s.

References
Bach, GL1971Making Monetary and Fiscal Policy.
Washington, D.C.: The Brookings Institution.
Shiller, Robert J. 1980. "Can the Fed Control Real Interest Rates?"ln Rational Expectations and Economic
Policy, ed. S. Fischer. Chicago: The University of
Chicago Press.
Stein, Herbert. 1969. The Fiscal Revolution in America. Chicago: The University of Chicago Press.

Opinions expressed in this newsletter do not necessarily reflect the views of the management of the Federal Reserve Bank of
San Francisco, or of the Board of Governors of the Federal Reserve System.
Editorial comments may be addressed to the editor or to the author.... Free copies of Federal Reserve publications can be
obtained from the Public Information Department, Federal Reserve Bank of San Francisco, P.O. Box 7702, San Francisco 94120.
Phone (415) 974-2246, Fax (415) 974-3341.

~

t.r\
·S~UI uEaqAos ~IIM
'" I(!)' JadEd papAOaJ uO palulJd

OUv6 V::> 'O:>SPUl!J:I Ul!S
lOLL xog 'O'd

O)SI)UOJ~

UOS

JO ~U08
f)AJaSatj IOJapa:l
~uaw~Jodaa

4)JOasati

Index to Recent Issues of fRBSf Weekly Letter

DATE NUMBER TITLE
12/4
12111
12/25
111
1/8
1/22
1/29
2/5
2112
2119
2/26
3/5
3112
3119
3/26
4/2
4/9
4116
4/23
4130
5/7
5114
5/21

92-43
92-44
92-45
93-01
93-02
93-03
93-04
93-05
93-06
93-07
93-08
93-09
93-10
93-11
93-12
93-13
93-14
93-15
93-16
93-17
93-18
93-19
93-20

Diamonds and Water: A Paradox Revisited
Sluggish Money Growth: Japan's Recent Experience
Labor Market Structure and Monetary Policy
An Alternative Strategy for Monetary Policy
The Recession, the Recovery, and the Productivity Slowdown
Banking Turnaround
Competitive Forces and Profit Persistence in Banking
The Sources of the Growth Slowdown
GDP Fluctuations: Permanent or Temporary?
The Twelfth District Agricultural Outlook
Saving-Investment Linkages in the Pacific Basin
A Single Market for Europe?
Risks in the Swaps Market
On the Changing Composition of Bank Portfolios
Interest Rate Spreads as Indicators for Monetary Policy
The Lonesome Twi n
Why Has Employment Grown So Slowly?
Interpreting the Term Structure of Interest Rates
California Banking Problems
Is Banking on the Brink? Another Look
European Exchange Rate Credibility before the Fall
Computers and Productivity
Western Metal Mining

u.s.

AUTHOR
Schmidt
Moreno/Kim
Huh
Motley/judd
Cogley
Zimmerman
Levonian
Motley
Moreno
Dean·
Kim
Glick/Hutchison
Laderman
Neuberger
Huh
Throop
Trehan
Cogley
Zimmerman
Levonian
Rose
Schmidt
Schmidt

The FRBSF Weekly Letter appears on an abbreviated schedule in June, July, August, and December.