View original document

The full text on this page is automatically extracted from the file linked above and may contain errors and inconsistencies.

Federal Reserve Bank San Francisco | Should the Fed React to the Stock Market? |

FEDERAL RESERVE BANK
OF SAN FRANCISCO
HOME

RESEARCH

BANKING SUPERVISION

EDUCATION

Search SF Fed
COMMUNITY

CASH

OUR DISTRICT

Home > Economic Research > Publications > Economic Letter > Should the Fed React to the Stock Market?

Economic Research

Our Economists | Publications | About Us

FRBSF ECONOMIC LeTTer
2003-34

November 14, 2003

Subscribe

RSS Feed

Share

« More Economic Letters

Should the Fed React to the Stock Market?
Kevin J. Lansing
Asset prices and the economy
Costs of ignoring bubbles
Can bubbles be identified?
Empirical evidence
Conclusion
References
The late 1990s witnessed the emergence of the greatest speculative bubble in financial market history.
Investors bid up stock prices to unprecedented valuation levels as they extrapolated a temporary surge
in corporate earnings growth far into the future. When these optimistic projections failed to materialize,
the bubble burst, setting off a chain of events that eventually dragged the U.S. economy into a
recession during 2001. In the aftermath of these events, a much-debated question is whether U.S.
monetary policy should have reacted more aggressively to the parabolic run-up in stock prices. It has
been argued that a policy of “leaning against the bubble” could have spared the economy from the long
and painful process of unwinding bubble-induced excesses. This Economic Letter examines the issue of
whether central banks should react directly to asset prices. In addition, it presents empirical evidence
which shows that lagged movements in the Standard & Poors (S&P) 500 stock index can help explain
movements in the U.S. federal funds rate since 1987.
Asset prices and the economy
Changes in the prices of assets, such as stocks or houses, can have important consequences for the
economy. During the late 1990s, consumers became wealthier as their stock portfolios appreciated. This
“wealth effect” boosted personal consumption expenditures, which account for about two-thirds of GDP.
Rapidly rising stock prices also helped fuel a boom in business investment by lowering firms’ cost of
capital. Surging tax collections from investors’ capital gains realizations allowed governments at all
levels to increase spending or cut taxes. More recently, rising house prices, together with innovations in
mortgage lending, have allowed consumers to tap the equity in their homes to pay for a variety of goods
and services. Through these channels and others, increases in asset prices may cause demand growth

http://www.frbsf.org/economic-research/publications/economic-letter/2003/november/should-the-fed-react-to-the-stock-market/[2/11/2015 2:40:46 PM]

Federal Reserve Bank San Francisco | Should the Fed React to the Stock Market? |

to outstrip potential increases in supply, thus contributing to inflationary pressure.
Central banks’ goals are to keep inflation low while promoting sustainable real growth. Given that swings
in asset prices can affect both goals, some economists have argued that central banks can improve
macroeconomic performance by responding directly to asset prices. Based on simulations from a small
economic model, Cecchetti, et al. (2000) conclude that performance can be improved if the central bank
raises the short-term nominal interest rate in response to temporary “bubble shocks” that push the
stock price index above the value implied by economic fundamentals. Bernanke and Gertler (2001)
reach a different conclusion; they allow “fundamental shocks” (such as a technological innovation that
raises productivity and profits) to also be a source of movement in stock prices. They assume that the
central bank cannot tell whether an increase in stock prices is driven by a bubble shock or a
fundamental shock. Since both types of shocks ultimately affect real output and inflation, they conclude
that the central bank can do just as well by responding only to those goal variables; they find no
significant additional benefit to responding directly to stock prices.
A limitation of the above models is the assumption that asset price bubbles randomly inflate and burst
regardless of any central bank action. Hence these models cannot address the important questions of
whether a central bank should try to prevent bubbles from forming or whether a central bank should try
to deflate a bubble once it has formed.
Costs of ignoring bubbles
Advocates of preventing stock market bubbles point out that bubbles can distort economic and financial
decisions, creating costly imbalances that can take years to dissipate. During the late 1990s, surging
market values for technology-related companies led many firms to vastly overspend on computers,
networking equipment, and software, at the expense of other items. It is now clear that a portion of that
technology capital was never put into productive service. This wasteful spending was nevertheless
counted in real output statistics, thus contributing to overestimates of the economy’s trend growth rate.
The overhang of the excess capital acquired during the bubble has contributed to low levels of capacity
utilization and a sluggish rebound in business investment relative to the average recovery (see Lansing
2003).
The stock market bubble distorted other areas of the U.S. economy as well. Firms hired large numbers of
permanent employees to satisfy an episode of demand growth that was not sustainable. When the
bubble burst, demand growth slowed and firms had to lay off employees. Now, two years after the
recession’s official end-date in November 2001, labor market weakness persists. The rapid appreciation
of stocks held in employee pension plans led many firms to reduce cash contributions to their plans,
which made reported earnings look better. When stock prices dropped, the value of plan assets shrank,
contributing to an underfunding problem in excess of $200 billion among S&P 500 companies (see Kwan
2003). Foreign investors’ eagerness to participate in the booming U.S. stock market of the late 1990s
drove up the value of the dollar on foreign exchange markets, contributing to a dramatic expansion of
the U.S. current account deficit. The deficit now exceeds 5% of GDP, implying that the U.S. economy
must draw in about $1.5 billion per day from foreign investors to finance domestic spending. Finally, the
collapse in capital gains tax revenues after the bubble burst has forced elected officials to make difficult
and unpopular choices to address the resulting budget shortfalls.
Can bubbles be identified?
Despite the many problems propagated by bubbles, some have argued that central banks should ignore
bubbles. Their argument consists of two parts: (1) central banks cannot reliably determine if a run-up in
stock prices is actually a bubble until after it has burst; (2) an interest rate hike of sufficient magnitude
to prick a suspected bubble would likely send the economy into a recession, thereby sacrificing the
benefits of the boom that might otherwise continue.

http://www.frbsf.org/economic-research/publications/economic-letter/2003/november/should-the-fed-react-to-the-stock-market/[2/11/2015 2:40:46 PM]

Federal Reserve Bank San Francisco | Should the Fed React to the Stock Market? |

To identify a bubble in real time, policymakers would need to judge whether a valuation metric, such as
the price-earnings (P/E) ratio for the aggregate stock market, has crossed into bubble territory. But
rendering such a judgment may be difficult in practice, particularly if the bubble is triggered by investor
overreaction to an actual fundamental improvement in the underlying economy. For example, a pickup
in measured productivity growth during the late 1990s appeared to offer to some fundamental
justification for the rise in the market P/E ratio. Others have countered that the difficulties in identifying
bubbles do not justify ignoring them altogether. Central banks routinely apply judgment to a whole host
of issues affecting monetary policy. One example is the size of the so-called “output gap,” defined as the
difference between actual GDP and potential GDP. The output gap is notoriously difficult to measure in
real time, yet it remains an important input to central bank inflation forecasts.
Regarding the second part of the argument, some worry that a policy designed to prick an emerging
bubble could have unintended negative consequences. Opponents of bubble-popping often cite the
example of the Great Depression, claiming it was exacerbated by the Fed’s overzealous attempts to rein
in speculative stock market excesses. A counterargument is provided by Borio and Lowe (2002), who
perform an exhaustive historical study of financial market bubbles in many countries. According to the
authors, opponents of bubble-popping fail to take sufficient account of the asymmetric nature of the
costs of policy errors when faced with a suspected bubble: “If the economy is indeed robust and the
boom is sustainable, actions by the authorities to restrain the boom are unlikely to derail it altogether.
By contrast, failure to act could have much more damaging consequences, as the imbalances unravel”
(p. 26). They also argue that emerging bubbles can be more readily identified if central banks look
beyond asset prices to include other variables that signal a threat to financial stability. Specifically, they
find that episodes of sustained rapid credit expansion, booming stock or house prices, and high levels of
investment, are almost always followed by periods of stress in the financial system.
Empirical evidence
Clearly, economists have yet to reach a consensus on whether
central banks should react directly to asset prices. But what do
central banks actually do? Interestingly, empirical evidence
suggests that U.S. monetary policy has reacted directly to the
stock market during the term of Federal Reserve Chairman
Alan Greenspan.
Figure 1 plots an estimated Fed policy rule using quarterly data
over the period 1987:Q3 to 2003:Q3. The estimated rule is
constructed along the lines of the well-known “Taylor rule.”
Specifically, the quarterly average federal funds rate is
regressed on a constant term, the inflation rate in the previous
quarter (as measured by the four-quarter percent change in
the GDP price index), and the output gap in the previous
quarter (as measured by the percent deviation of real GDP
from a fitted long-run trend).
Figure 2 adds the annualized percent change in the S&P 500
stock index during the previous quarter to the regression
equation. The use of data from the previous quarter helps
ensure that the direction of causation runs from the stock
market to the funds rate, and not vice versa. Including the
stock market variable significantly improves the empirical fit of
the estimated policy rule. This is most notable toward the end
of the data sample, when the actual federal funds rate dropped
from 6.5% in 2000:Q4 to 1.0% in 2003:Q3. During this time,

http://www.frbsf.org/economic-research/publications/economic-letter/2003/november/should-the-fed-react-to-the-stock-market/[2/11/2015 2:40:46 PM]

Federal Reserve Bank San Francisco | Should the Fed React to the Stock Market? |

the S&P 500 index lost nearly one-third of its value. The above
results reinforce the findings of Rigobon and Sack (2003), who
employ high frequency data on stock market movements and
interest rate changes from 1985 to 2000. They find that a 5%
decrease (increase) in the S&P 500 over the course of a week
raises the probability of a 25-basis-point interest rate cut
(hike) by 64%.
While the data indicate that the Fed reacts directly to the stock market, statistical regressions do not
reveal the motives behind this behavior. One possibility is that forward-looking policymakers view
movements in the stock market as useful predictors of future economic activity. Another possibility is
that policymakers act out of concern for market valuation. In an effort to divine the Fed’s motives,
Hayford and Malliaris (2001) studied Federal Open Market Committee (FOMC) transcripts during
Greenspan’s term. The authors conclude that FOMC members paid significant attention to the valuation
of the stock market and that, on some occasions, concerns about the stock market directly influenced
the conduct of U.S. monetary policy. In one notable instance (February 1994), the transcripts suggest
that FOMC members were worried that raising the funds rate by 50 basis points might trigger a crash in
the stock market, which was thought to be overvalued at the time. In this case, the stock market’s
possible reaction appeared to act as a constraint on policymakers’ desire to tighten policy against the
threat of rising inflation.
Conclusion
Although central banks control only short-term interest rates, their ability to influence longer-term rates
and other asset prices is part of the transmission mechanism of monetary policy. Movements in asset
prices can have important consequences for real output and inflation. Still, economists do not agree on
whether central banks should react directly to asset prices, or, more specifically, whether central banks
should take steps to prevent or deflate asset price bubbles. The arguments against doing so emphasize
issues pertaining to difficulty and risk, but there are strong counterarguments that favor action when
faced with a suspected bubble.
Kevin J. Lansing
Senior Economist
References
[URLs accessed November 2003.]
Bernanke, B., and M. Gertler. 2001. “Should Central Banks Respond to Movements in Asset Prices?”
American Economic Review 91, pp. 253-257.
Borio, C., and P. Lowe. 2002. “Asset Prices, Financial and Monetary Stability: Exploring the Nexus.”
Bank for International Settlements. Working Paper 114. http://www.bis.org/publ/work114.htm

http://www.frbsf.org/economic-research/publications/economic-letter/2003/november/should-the-fed-react-to-the-stock-market/[2/11/2015 2:40:46 PM]

Federal Reserve Bank San Francisco | Should the Fed React to the Stock Market? |

Cecchetti, S., H. Genberg, J. Lipsky, and S. Wadhwani. 2000. “Asset Prices and Central Bank Policy.
Geneva Reports on the World Economy 2.”
London: Centre for Economic Policy Research and ICMB.
http://www.cepr.org/pubs/books/P135.asp
Hayford, M.D., and A.G. Malliaris. 2001. “Is the Federal Reserve Stock Market Bubble-Neutral?” In Asset
Price Bubbles: Implications for Monetary and Regulatory Policies, ed. G.C. Kaufman. Elsevier Science
Ltd., pp. 229-243.
Kwan, S. 2003. “Underfunding of Private Pension Plans.” FRBSF Economic Letter 2003-16 (June 13).
/economic-research/letter/2003/el2003-16.html
Lansing, K.J. 2003. “Growth in the Post-Bubble Economy.” FRBSF Economic Letter 2003-17 (June 24).
/economic-research/letter/2003/el2003-17.html
Rigobon, R., and B. Sack. 2003. “Measuring the Reaction of Monetary Policy to the Stock Market.”
Quarterly Journal of Economics 118, pp. 639-670.
Subscribe

RSS Feed

Share

Opinions expressed in FRBSF Economic Letter
do not necessarily reflect the views of the
management of the Federal Reserve Bank of
San Francisco or of the Board of Governors of
the Federal Reserve System. This publication is
edited by Sam Zuckerman and Anita Todd.
Permission to reprint must be obtained in
writing.

Site Policies

More Economic Letters
Please send editorial comments and requests for reprint permission
to

Research Library
Attn: Research publications, MS 1140
Federal Reserve Bank of San Francisco
P.O. Box 7702
San Francisco, CA 94120

Privacy

Contact Us

Work for Us

Federal Reserve Bank of San Francisco © 2015

http://www.frbsf.org/economic-research/publications/economic-letter/2003/november/should-the-fed-react-to-the-stock-market/[2/11/2015 2:40:46 PM]