View original document

The full text on this page is automatically extracted from the file linked above and may contain errors and inconsistencies.

May 1 6,1 980

Has the FedGiven Up?
The answer is, "Certainly not." Those pundits
who have interpreted the steep decline in
interest rates as a Federal Reserve surrender
to inflation have somehow missed the
message of the Fed's October 6 policy shift.
(They probably haven't paid any attention
either to Milton Friedman's Newsweek
columns over the past decade or so.) The real
story is that the Fed has consistently pursued
the same money-growth objectives since last
fall. But in the process, interest rates have
swung widely in both directions, reflecting
(among other things) the Fed's increased
emphasis on money growth rather than
interest rates in its operating processes.
Without doubt, interest-rate movements have
been unprecedented in recent months.
Treasury-bi II rates, for example, rose from
a 10.2-percent average rate last September
to a 15.5-percent average rate in the month
of March, before dropping to 8.8 percent
in early May. And the prime business loan
rate, after rising to 13 V2percent on the eve
of the Fed's October pol icy action, jumped
to 20 percent this April before declining
to the present level of 16V2percent. But these
massive rate movements, far from indicating
monetary-policy shifts, rather have indicated
wide shifts in loan demand, as well as
slowness by market participants in adjusting
to a new market envi ronment.
By improving its control over bank reserves in
the past half year, the Federal Reserve has
managed to reduce money-supply growth
roughly by half. In the two quarters prior to
the October 6 policy shift, the M-1 B measure
of the money supply increased at about an
11-percent annual rate. (M-l B consists of
currency, plus bank demand deposits, plus
similar check-type deposits at other financial
institutions.) In the following two quarters,
the growth rate dropped to about a 5 %-percent annual rate. Then, in the present quarter
to date, the money supply has actually
declined. The recent data indicate, not

a worrisome easing of policy, but rather
a danger of excessive tightening.
Money growth and inflation
To put this problem in the proper context
we should understand the connection
between money growth and inflation, and the
reasons why the Federal Reserve shifted its
operating techniques last fall to fight inflation
more effectively. Most economists agree that
over the long run, the fundamental
determinant of the rate of inflation is the rate
of growth of the money supply. Monetary
growth greater than that which is required to
meet the needs of trade and finance wi II
ultimately result in higher prices (see chart).
However, it takes approximately two years
for most of the effects of an increase in the
money supply to work their way through the
economy to price increases.

Although the relationship is not perfect, there
is a general correspondence between the
U.S. rate of inflation and U.S. monetary
growth two years earlier. This relationship
can be expected to hold in the long run,
while in the short run, inflation may also
be influenced by non-monetary factors such
as oil-price shocks, crop failures, and
price controls.
Between the first quarter of 1979 and the first
quarter of 1980, the price index (deflator) for
personal consumption expenditures rose
by 10.3 percent. What factors accounted for
such a sharp increase? One important factor
was the oil-price shock of 1979. Due
primari Iy to OPEC oi I-price increases, energy
prices in the U.S. rose by almost 40 percent in
1979. This contributed significantly to the
past year's rise in the overall price level, and
the effects may continue as the energy price
increases work their way through to prices of
related products. Nonetheless, the oil-price
shock has added no more than two percentage points to the inflation rate over the
last year. This still leaves us with a high

ke::;crve

Because of strong public pressures to keep
interest rates as low as is consistent with
short-term economic growth, and because
of the operating procedures which were
in place until last October 6, the Fed
in the past tended to use nev,t!y-created
money to purchase a large portion of the
bonds floated by the Treasury to finance the
deficit. This process-monetizing the
deficit -may be explained by the different
effects of expansionary monetary and fiscal
policy on domestic interest rates.

underlying rate of inflation, which is
explainable in terms of the past history of
monetary growth.
Annual money growth averaged about
3 percent in the early 19f)O's, but averaged
over 8 percent between early 1 977 and late
1979. What has caused this excessive money
growth? And if excessive monetary
expansion is the root cause of inflation,
why doesn't the Federal Reserve System
simply adopt more conservative policies and
aim at a slower growth of money and credit?

If the government sells bonds to pay for an
increase in the Federal deficit (expansionary
fiscal policy), this will increase the supply of
bonds available to the public, and will put
upward pressure on interest rates. On the
other hand, if the Fed increases the supply of
money (expansionary monetary policy) by
buying bonds on the open market, this will
reduce the supply of bonds available to the
public, and will put downward pressure (at
least in the short run) on interest rates.

Excessive growth (I)
After the end of World War II, many
countries, including the United States,
adopted national economic pol icies aimed
vigorously at full employment. This is
understandable in the context of the
economic and human ravages of the Great
Depression and the Great War. Later on, the
full-employment goal was augmented by
programs of social welfare and income
maintenance. These goals were achieved
largely through greatly enlarged government
spending programs.

Higher interest rates impact heavily on
businesses, farmers, homebuilders and
state-and-Iocal government units. To avoid
such problems, the Fed sometimes has had
a tendency to buy all of the additional bonds
sold by the Treasury, leaving no change in the
supply of bonds available to the public, and
no immediate change in interest rates. Thus,
in times of large increases in Federal deficits,
such as in the Vietnam War era, the Fed has
.tended to monetize the deficit and thus
increase the supply of money beyond what
it otherwise would have been.

While the programs themselves were
popular, an increase in taxes to finance these
programs was far less popular, and the result
has been chronic large-scale deficit
financing. When economic resources are
substantially under-utilized, it c.an be
constructive to achieve fiscal and monetary
stimulus through well-designed government
spending programs, financed through budget
deficits and/or an accompariying increased
growth of money and credit. However, the
U.S. has recorded federal budget deficits in
19 of the last 20 years, irrespective of the
stage of the business cycle.

Excessive growth (II)
Secondly, high money growth has occurred
because of uncertainty regarding the effects
of monetary policy. Expanding money
growth increases production in the short run,
but increases the inflation rate in the long run.
Similarly, while a deceleration in money
growth leads to an eventual decline in the
inflation rate, the immediate effects are
negative-an increase in unemployment and
a reduction in real output. While the central
bank has a responsibility to strive for
2

Growth Rates
Change(%)

12

(Year over year)
Personal
.1l',
consumption , . ,
deflator
-lI.....

8

•

4

non-inflationary economic growth, it also has
a responsibility to avoid policies which
produce sub-normal growth and excessive
unused resou rces.

directly related to current monetary policy,
such as increases in private-sector investment
demand and increases in inflation expectations. The Fed consequently would feel
forced to buy additional securities, thus
increasing the supply of money, in order to
keep interest rates at their targeted level.

Because of the uncertainties of economic
forecasting, however, there is almost always
a large "gray area" in the range of
appropriate monetary policy, no matter
how clear the proper pol icy may appear
in retrospect to economic historians. Because
of such uncertainties, and because the shortrun effects of policy are sometimes weighted
more heavily than the long-run effects, there
is often a tendency to err on the side of
monetary ease. The result frequently is
a favorable short-run impact on employment
and output, but a worsening of the inflation
rate in the long run.

The old operating procedures, coupled with
reluctance to change the short-term interest
rate, thus led to a procyclical monetary
policy. In other words, we experienced
an overexpansion of the money supply
during economic booms, and underexpansion of the money supply during
slowdowns. And since most years in the past
two decades have been expansion years, this
situation has led to a net overexpansion of the
money supply.

Excessivegrowth (III)

The new operating procedures should avoid
these problems. As we've seen, the Fed now
allows short-term interest rates to fluctuate
much more than before, and concentrates
instead on controlling directly the amount
of reserves in the banking system. Because
banks hold a fairly stable amount of reserves
relative to total deposits, this new procedure
should improve monetary control and prevent some of the excesses which occurred
in the past. Indeed, these procedures seem
to be working, as was noted at the outset.

The third reason for the high monetary
growth of the last decade has to do with the
operating procedures of the Federal
Reserve-the way in which money was
injected into the economy-prior
to
October 6, 1979. Under that procedure,
the Fed's policy-making committee, the
Federal Open Market Committee (FOMe),
chose an appropriate rate of money growth,
and then chose a short-term interest-rate
target (the Federal funds rate) which
appeared to be consistent with the targeted
rate of money growth. If the Fed funds rate
rose above the chosen rate, the Fed would
purchase securities with newly created
money, putting downward pressure on shortterm interest rates. Similarly, if the Fed funds
rate fell below the chosen rate, the Fed wou Id
sell securities, thus withdrawing money from
the system and pushing rates back up.

Looking ahead, it is apparent that the
problem of inflation will not be solved overnight, because it has built up over a number
of years. The Federal Reserve is determined
to reduce, gradually yet consistently, the rate
of growth of the money supply. Despite the
time required to make this policy completely
effective, it is the necessary solution for bringing down the rate of inflation in this country.

This procedure created problems, however,
because of the F OMes reluctance, in practice, to change its targeted interest rate.
Interest rates can be affected by factors other
than monetary policy, so that a policy which
tries to fight such changes wi II result in
monetary growth different from intended.
During a cyclical expansion, for example,
interest rates tend to rise for reasons not

.

3

StephenZeldes

J.Sl:Il.:I
u018U!4SPM"4Pln • uo8aJO" ppeJ\aN" o4PPI
!!PMPH "P!UJoJ!IP:::>
puoZPV
e>lselV

cTI
CC))

IOlSPU E'J: J UE'S

ZSL' ON ll WHld
GiVd
]9 V l SOd

@}ffi,c TI@<§@@

's'n

11VWSSV1JlSHI:I

B AN KI NG DATA-TWE LF TH FEDERALRESERVE
DISTRICT
(Dollar amounts in millions)

Selected Assetsand liabilities
Large Commercial Banks
Loans (gross, adjusted) and investments*
Loans (gross, adjusted) - total#
Commercial and industrial
Real estate
Loans to individuals
Securities loans
U.s. Treasury securities*
Other securities*
Demand deposits - total#
Demand deposits - adjusted
Savings deposits - total
Time deposits - total#
Individuals, part. & corp.
(Large negotiable CD's)

Weekly Averages
of Daily figures
Member Bank ReservePosition
Excess Reserves (+ )/Deficiency (- )
Borrowings
Net free reserves ( + )/Net borrowed (- )

Amount
Outstanding

Change
from

4/30/80

4/23/80

138,394
116,690
33,749
46,079
24,314
1,123
6,391
15,313
43,921
31,085
25,904
64,517
55,610
23,225

+ 39
+ 127
+ 52
+ 116

Change from
year ago
Dollar
Percent

+
+
+
+
+

12,885
14,037
2,949
9,095
2,616
447
1,346
194
+
+ 1,175
406
+
3,838
+ 14,703
+ 15,128
+ 6,164

105

+ 1n
-

150

+ 62
+ 670
-1,141
318
+ 588
+ 541
+ 441

-

Weekended

Weekended

4/30/80

4/23/80

331
88
243

479
148
331

+
+
+
+
+

10.3
13.7
9.6
24.6
12.1
1 - 28.5
- 17.4
+ 1.3
+ 2.7
+ 1.3
- 12.9
+ 29.5
+ 37.4
+ 36.1

Comparable
year-ago period

10
224
214

* Excludes trading account securities.
# Includes items not shown separately.
Editorial comments may be addressedto the editor (William Burke) or to the author, , .. free copies of this
and other federal Reservepublications can beobtained by calling or writing the Public Information Section,
federal Reserve Bank of San Francisco, P.O. Box 7702, San francisco 94120. Phone (415) 544-2184.