View original document

The full text on this page is automatically extracted from the file linked above and may contain errors and inconsistencies.

October 19, 1979

The Fed CrossesThe Rubicon
"Using the proverb ... 'The die is cast,' he took the river."-Plutarch
Over the October 6 weekend, the Federal
Reserve announced that it was taking three
steps "that should assure better control over
the expansion of money and bank credit, help
curb speculative excesses in financial,
foreign exchange and commodity markets
and thereby serve to dampen inflationary
pressures." First, the Fed announced a onepercent increase in the discount rate, the rate
at which Reserve banks lend to member
commercial banks. Second, it imposed a
marginal eight-percent reserve requirement
on "managed liabilities" -large time
deposits, Eurodollar borrowings, repurchase
agreements against U.s. Government and
federal-agency securities, and federal-funds
borrowing from nonmember institutions.
Finally, the Fed announced a greater
emphasis, in the day-to-day conduct of
monetary policy, on bank reserves-and less
emphasis on confirming short-term fluctuations in the federal-funds rate, the rate at
which banks borrow reserves from each other
and from other institutions.
The first two measures have received considerable attention in the financial markets
and the press, yet may affect the overall
performance of the economy for only a short
period of time. But the third measure, while
receiving much less attention, may have
fundamentally improved the long-run inflation outlook in the United States. By focusing
its day-to-day operations on bank reserves,
the Federal Reserve may now have found a
way to keep growth in the nation's money
supply under tighter control. Since high
inflation rates cannot persist for long without
rapid money growth, substantial progress
against inflation may be achieved over the
next few years.

Operating procedures
The Federal Reserve can influence the growth
in money in either of two basic ways-with
either a reserves operating target or a funds
rate target. Both methods operate through the

market for bank reserves. Under the Fed's
present regu lations, member banks must hold
reserves against deposits equal to a certain
minimum percentage of those deposits. This
means that deposit growth is ultimately
constrained by the rate at which bank
reserves are expandirig. Thus the banking
system must find additional reserves if more
deposits are to be issued. The Federal
Reserve, of course, has the power to add to or
subtract from reserves through open-market
operations, in which it either buys financial
assets from banks (adds reserves) or sells
financial assetsto banks (withdraws reserves).
Under the reserves operating target, as
apparently adopted on October 6th, the Fed
attempts to hit certain target growth rates for
the quantityof bank reserves. Once this
quantity is expanding at a set rate, the rate at
which banks can issue deposits (the main
element in the money supply) will be largely
determ i ned.
Under the funds rate target, as used prior to
October 6th, the Fed attempted to influence
deposit growth not through the quantity of
bank reserves but indirectly through the cost
of these reserves. Banks can borrow from
other institutions in the federal-funds market.
The Fed can affect the interest rate on these
reserves (the fed-funds-rate) by injecting or
withdrawing
A rise in the funds rate,
for example, increases the cost of reserves,
which in turn leads to increases in other
market rates of interest. With higher yields on
financial assets like Treasury bills, the public
chooses to hold smaller stocks of low-or noninterest-bearing deposits, and money growth
declines.
A great deal of research has been done on
which technique does a better job of controlling money. As a technical matter, the
race seems to be a draw: using either the
funds rate or reserves as the operating target

(except in 1 970 and mid-1973) have not been
sufficiently aggressive to keep money growth
from following the path of income growth
over the business cycle. As a result, monetary
policy has generally added to inflationary
pressures in cyclical expansions and to
unemployment in recessions.

produces equally good results. This conclusion, however, leaves out a crucial factor,
namely, the cautious way in which the
Federal Reserve's monetary policymaking
body -the Federal Open Market Committee
-has tended to adjust its funds-rate targets in
response to deviations of the aggregates from
their official longer-run targets. This cautious
control has several implications. First, with
such an approach, a funds-rate operating
instrument in the past resulted in less control
over the monetary aggregates than was either
desirable or feasible. Second, the cautiouscontrol approach is now likely to carry over
to the new reserves operating target. And
third, cautious control of reserves is likely to
improve control over the aggregates.

Why cautious control?
Why hasn't the Federal Reserve moved the
funds rate more actively? The Fed is faced
with a good deal of uncertainty concerning
the cu rrent cond ition of the economy and the
precise timing and impact of policy actions.
This uncertainty reflects the current state-ofthe-art in the economics profession, and is
not likely to be eliminated in the near future.
Under these circumstances, the rational
policymaker with the best available information shou Id react cautiotJslYln changing
the operating target when money growth
appears to be off target. Since the impact of
potential policy actions is uncertain, the fact
that the economy functioned tolerably well
last month is important evidence in favor of
not substantially changing the operating
target this month. In this way, significant
swings in policy are quite rationally delayed
"until next month".

Cautoous fUlf1ldsrate cOlf1ltrol
In evaluating the experience underthe
previous funds rate target, it is important to
recogn ize that growth of the (M 1) money
supply is influenced primarily by two factors.
First, if the Fed increases the funds rate, for
example, M 1 growth tends to fall as banks
find it more expensive to borrow reservesand
as the public finds non- or low-interestbearing deposits and currency less desirable.
Second, as income rises and falls over the
business cycle or in concert with inflation,
Ml growth will also be pulled up and down
as the public's need for transactions balances
changes.

Several political and bureaucratic constraints
on Fed actions also have contributed to
cautious control of the funds rate. First, policy
is made by a committee (the twelve-member
Federal Open-Market Comm ittee) and the
Committee's inevitable compromises sometimes lead to only modest changes in the
operating targets. Second, the Fed is appropriately sensitive to Congressional and public
opinion about the effectiveness of monetary
policies. For some reason, public and
pol itical attitudes tend to view the risk of
doing something to be greater than the risk of
the status quo. Since greater blame attaches
to mistakes resulting from activist policies,
the Fed is influenced in the direction of
gradual ist pol icies or the status quo. Third,
frequent changes in policy impose high costs
on the private sector by forcing it constantly
to revise its decisions, and so can be
detrimental to aggregate economic perfor-

Presumably, in targeting the aggregates the
Fed wishes to avoid increases in money
growth in recoveries which would "overheat" the economy, and decreases in money
growth in recessions which would exacerbate unemployment. Such undesjred procyclical money-supply movements theoretically
can be avoided by changing the funds rate
fast enough to "fight off" the procycl ical
effects of income growth on money.
But as the chart indicates, the Fed generally
has not done so. The funds rate has moved in
the right direction - increasing in recoveries
to restrain monetary accelerations, and
decreasing in recessions to hold back
monetary decelerations. But these actions
2

Annual
Change (%)

150

100

50

·50

·100

. --_.

_-------_.

__ _ ___-----_.
•....... ..

_-_

..-.-

- - _. - ..__...._._----_.

_-_. _----_

__-.

..

..

_--_.

_--

While the Fed can keep interest rates down in
the short-run, this is not true in the long-run.
Attempts to lower rates in the face of strong
money and credit demands result in fast
money growth and ultimately inflation. And
given the inclusion of an inflation premium in
nominal interest rates, attempts to resist
interest-rate increases in the short run often
cause higher rates in the long run. But now,
by emphasizing reserves, the 'Fed may avoid
some ofthe public pressure to control interest
rates, and thus may promote a more accurate
public perception of its actual ability to
control rates.

mance. Thus, in addition to being concerned
with inflation, unemployment, and the
foreign exchange value of the dollar, the Fed
may qu ite reasonably want to provide a
stable policy framework, and in doing so may
be cautious in changing the funds rate.

hilterest rate variability
All of the above considerations regarding the
Fed's control of the funds rate apply equally
well to any other operating target the Fed
might use, includingbank reserves. Thus the
Fed's recent decision to focus on reserves
rather than the fu nds rate cou Id mean that the
reserves-operati ng targets wi II now be moved
cautiously also.

Improved monetary control?
As we have seen, a cautious funds-rate
strategy can lead to procyclical swings in
money and reserves that are larger than
desirable. A cautiously controlled reservesoperati ng target wi II work in just the opposite
direction - it will tend to resist, rather than
accede to, the forces producing procyclical
swings in money. With the supply of bank
reserves expanding at a relatively stable rate,
the maximum rate at which banks can issue
deposits will be relatively stable also.

Cautious control would of course mean that
short- and long-term fluctuations in banks'
demand forreserves would (in most cases)
not be accommodated. This is likely to cause
the federal funds rate to become much more
variable than it has been in the past. This
possibility has prompted some observers to
argue that such funds-rate variability would
be unacceptable to the Fed -indeed, would
cause the Fed to revert to a funds-rate target,
leading again to interest-rate smoothing.

Cautious control appl ied to a reserves
operating instrument thus is likely to insulate
the growth in money more thoroughly from
cyclical swings in output and prices. The
outcome should be a better record in
moderating economic fluctuations and
particularly in containing the rate of inflation.
Under the old system, inflationary pressures
often led to faster money growth and thus
even more inflation later. Under the new
system, more inflation now is likely to be met
by higher nominal interest rates and
unchanged money growth, which means that
higher rates of inflation cannot be
permanently sustained. For this reason,
the long-run outlook for inflation control
has been improved by the recent Federal
Reserve action.

These fears could be exaggerated. First, under
a reserves target, funds-rate fluctuations
probably will not be transmitted to other
money-market rates (such as the Treasury-bill
or commercial-paper rates) to the same
extent that they were under a funds-rate
target. Formerly, cu rrent changes in the fu nds
rate contained policy information aboutwhat
the Fed would do in the future; thus fundsrate changes were almost immediately
reflected in other money-market rates. Under
a reserves-operating instrument, the essentially random day-to-day and week-to-week
changes in the funds rate will convey less
information about its future levels, and will
have a much smaller impact on other moneymarket rates.
Second, under the funds-rate regime, the Fed
came to be held publicly responsible for
interest rates -and thus came under
considerable pressure to keep rates down.

JohnP.JuddandJohnl. Scadding

3

l.S!:!II.:!
U01 8U!4SEM.4Em • uo8aJO • EpEAaN

!!EMt:?H •

E'!UJOJ!lE':)

E'UOZpV.

CD)
ZS'l 'ON
GIYIlI

: J9¥150«1's'n
1I1VWSSYD

BANKINGDATA-TWELFTHFEDERAL
RESERVE
(Dollar amounts in millions)

SelectedAssetsandliabilities
largeCommercialBanks
Loans(gross,adjusted)"and investments*
Loans(gross,adjusted)- total#
Commercial and industrial
Realestate
Loansto 'individuals
Securitiesloans
U.5. Treasurysecurities*
Other securities*
Demand deposits - total#
Demand deposits- adjusted
Savingsdeposits - total
Time deposits- total#
Individuals, part. & corp.
(LargenegotiableCD's)

WeeklyAverages
of Daily Figures
MemberBankReserve
Position
ExcessReserves(+)/Deficiency (-)
Borrowings
Net free reserves(+ )/Net borrowed(-)

Amount
Outstanding
10/3/79
135,090
111,970
31,821
40,785
22,711
2,273
7,513
15,607
45,966
31,151
30,364
54,494
46,213
20,269
Weekended
0/3/79

Changefrom
yearago@
Dollar
Percent

Change
from
9/26/79

-

-

-

+ 16.68
+ 20.01
+ 15.63

+ 19,309
+ 18,670
+ 4,302
+ 8,344

1,359
1,420
148
166
38
54
130
69
3,181
969
286
249
211
272

-

+
+
+

-

+
+
+

Weekended
9/26/79

NA
NA
1,284
1,923
3,654
628
480
7,476
8,619
1,644

-

+
+
+
-

+
+
+

25.72
NA
NA
14.60
14.05
8.64
2.06
1.56
15.90
22.93
8.83

Comparable
year-agoperiod
57
42
99

-

25
96
71

2
15
17

-

514

- 453

243

-

289

77

+ 555

-

FederalFunds- Sevenlarge Banks
Net interbank transactions
[Purchases(+ )/Sales(-)]
Net, U.5. Securitiesdealer transactions
[Loans(+)/Borrowings (-)]

* Excludestrading account securities.
# Includes items not shown separately.
@ Historicaldataarenot strictlycomparable
dueto changes
in thereportingpanel;however,adjustments

havebeenappliedto 1978datato removeasmuchaspossibletheeffectsof thechanges
in coverage.
In
addition,for someitems,historicaldataarenotavailabledueto definitionalchanges.

0

o4EPI

E'>lsEIV