View original document

The full text on this page is automatically extracted from the file linked above and may contain errors and inconsistencies.

FRBSF

WEEKLY LETTER

Number 91-39, November 8, 1991

The False Hope of the Narrow Bank
Current proposals to reform the banking system
are intended to limit the cost of the safety net,
while enhancing the stability and competitiveness of U.S. banks. One proposal that has received
a significant following is to limit the safety net to
"narrow" banks. These banks could offer insured
deposits, but would be restricted sharply in their
asset powers. Risky assets wQuld be held by other
banks not enjoying deposit guarantees. The result is supposed to be a banking system that is
both safe and stable.
This Letter highlights some of the flaws in the
concept of deposits backed only by safe assets.
!n particular, I argue that the issuance of deposits
backed by risky assets has important economic
justification. 1\t1aking banks "nariOW" thus risks
handicapping the flow of funds to commerce.
Just as importantly, however, the narrow banking
notion does not solve the problem of banking
system stability.

The narrow bank
Although differing in their details, all the narrow
banking proposals involve partitioning the banking system into "safe" banks for deposits, and
"risky" banks whose liabilities would enjoy no
insurance. The safety of deposits in the narrow
banks would be guaranteed by a system of essentially full deposit coverage. In turn, the integrity
of the insurance fund would be preserved by permitting insured banks only to hold "safe" assets.
Some proponents of narrow banking define
"safe" assets to include only government and
agency securities. Others, such as Bryan (1991)
would extend the range of assets permitted in the
insured "core" banks to others that "have proven
over time to be relatively safe," including home
mortgages and accounts receiving financing.
Implicit in all of the proposals, however, is the
notion that the use of demand debt to finance
risky assets can be restricted without great harm.

Banking and information asymmetry
To see why this reasoning might be flawed, it is
first necessary to characterize the informational
environment in which banks exist, and which

justifies their existence as intermediaries. (It is
easiest to introduce the necessary arguments by
assuming initially that deposit insurance does
not exist.)
Financial intermediaries (including banks) exist
in a world in which the information needed to
assess financial risks is not perfect, or evenly distributed. In particular, the businesses that want to
borrow to finance new projects tend to have better information about the true prospects of the
projects than do the (outside) lenders. Similarly,
bank management has better information about
the quality of its investments than do outside
depositors. Without special contracts, the uninformed parties would be reluctant to provide
credit for fear of being exploited by the better
informed parties. Depositors would not lend
their funds to banks, and banks would not lend
their funds to firms.
Contractual solutions have evolved to address
this dilemma. Bank loan agreements incorporate
features to permit banks to monitor the activities
of the borrower, and to take actions, if necessary,
to protect the bank's interests. Analogously, depositors need to be offered special contractual
protection to be induced to place their funds in
a bank. Depositors are uninformed relative to
bank management, and most also do not have
the resources to be good monitors; in addition,
the bank can be expected to worry less about its
reputation with individual depositors than with
larger investors. Thus, depositors need to be
offered a particularly potent and economical
means of avoiding exploitation by the bank.
Demand debt is just such an instrument. By requiring banks to make good on deposits at fixed
nominal value on demand, and with low transaction costs, holders of demand deposits can easily
withdraw their investment in a poorly managed
bank. In this way, they exert discipline on bank
behavior.

Why combine deposits and risky loans?
Demand debt thus is a concession by bank management to the needs of depositors for control. At

FRBSF
first glance, however, it seems to be a very costly
concession. In the absence of deposit insurance,
demand debt exposes banks to runs, and banks
must invest partlv in liquid assets to meet the uncertain withdra~als of depositors. Since a bank's
greatest returns are from assets that exploit its
monitoring expertise (assets that are, by definition, illiquid), having to accommodate the possibilityof runs thus is costly to the bank.

the most extreme form of the narrow bank, one
that only holds riskless government securities.
Since riskless securities make information asymmetry problems moot, narrow banks could issue
demand equity, instead of demand debt. And
they would tend to do so, since it does not pose
any liquidity burdens, and thus is cheaper than
demand debt to offer. In essence, such narrow
banks would be like today's mutual funds.

But would other forms of liabilities be cheaper?
For example, banks alternatively could raise
funds by issuing equity shares (similar to a
money market mutual fund). These claims do not
impose liquidityrestrictidns on the bank's asset
portfolio. However, the work of Myers and Majluf
(1984) suggests that equity would be even more
costly than debt in a setting of asymmetric informationabout the value of the bank's assets. This
is because uninformed eauitv holders will be re"
luctant to agree to the new i~suance of equity;
since they are uninformed about the quality of
the assets to be acquired, they cannot be certain
that the new equity issuance is in their interest
(rather than being a dilution of their claims). This
can cause new issuance of equity shares to depress share values, making equity shares a costly
way of financing new assets.

A banking system based on demand equity
would be very safe. Since equity holders have
pro rata, rather than fixed, claims on the bank,
they would gain nothing by running. Deposit
insurance would be redundant in such a narrow
bank, except perhaps to protect against fraud.

Issu ing long-term debt is another means of avoiding the liquidity cost of demand debt. But it, too,
imposes additional costs in an environment of
asymmetric information. Specifically, exercising
control via long-term debt involves longer delays
and greater transactions costs for depositors than
would be incurred with demand debt, making it
a less effective means of exerting influence.
Thus, the issuance of demand debt by intermediaries holding risky assets is not serendipitous. It
occurs precisely because bank assets are of uncertain value, and bankers are better informed
than depositors. Therefore, as long as there is a
significant group of informationally handicapped
investors and risky projects to undertake, intermediaries investing in these assets will tend to
issue demand deposits. And the existence of
demand deposits will tend to make the banking
system prone to runs.

Banks as money market mutual funds?
Would a system of "safe" banks with the exclusive authority to issue insured deposits resolve
this dilemma? To seethe effects clearly, imagine

But would "risky" deposit-taking banks cease
to exist? On the contrary: As long as banks with
risky assets must deal with uninformed investors,
they will have to issue demand debt. And, unlike
the "safe;' narrow bank, the risky bank provides
monitoring services that add value to the financial transaction-value that bankers can share
with depositors in order to attract their needed
funds. Thus, as Jacklin (1987) has shown formally,
the marketplace will prefer the demand debt of
risky banks, even if it is uninsured, to equity
claims on "safe" assets, because of the superior,
risk-adjusted returns.

A dilemma
As a consequence, the narrow banks will have
a hard time surviving, despite their "safe" asset
structure, and most deposits will be held in risky
banks. The risk of runs would still exist because
the demand debt of risky banks would still be the
dominant bank liability. Regulators could try, of
course, to "force" the dominance of narrow banks
by forbidding risky banks from issuing demand
deposits. But to do so would exact a clear penalty on the economy, if banks are the intermediary
the market prefers. Thus, narrow banking does
not solve the problem of instability in the banking system except at great expense to the intermediation of credit.
And it is not even clear that the "safety" of the
narrow banking system comes with particularly
lo\,y social costs. tv10st of the securities that make
up the supply of "safe" assets are themselves
backed by public guarantees, either explicitly
in the case of agency issues, such as mortgagebacked securities, or implicitly in the case of

federal and local government debt, which is
guaranteed by virtue of its claims on the future
taxpaying capability of Americans. Thus, to
promote narrow banking based on these "safe"
securities, rather than deposit insurance, to some
degree involves simply substituting one kind of
taxpayer guarantee for another.

Dealing with instability
If narrow banking is not the answer to the problem of bank runs and banking instability, what is?
There are two answers to this question, depending upon whether one believes the public sector
or the private sector is more prone to making
mistakes.
One alternative is to eliminate the safety net altogether, on the grounds that it is unlikely to be
managed well by the public sector. Proponents
of this approach argue that the concomitant
increased discipline that depositors impose on
banks would contain risk-taking. This increased
discipline necessarily would come at the expense
of an increased risk of runs. Proponents of this
view, however, argue that the costs of these runs
are low compared to the costs of a mismanaged
safety net.
The second alternative is simply to manage the
safety net better, by requiring bank capital levels
that are high enough so that the marginal value
of public safety net guarantees is low. This requires raising capital requirements, marking bank
portfolios to market, and immediately reorganizing banks that fail to meet the high capital
requirements. In this way, the incentive to exploit
the safety net is diminished. In a previous Letter,
we discussed the successful application of this

approach by a European banking system that has
broad asset powers (Pozdena 1990).

Conclusion
In any case, narrow banking seems not to be a
solution. The artificial partitioning of bank asset
powers is inconsistent with the underlying economics of the business of banking. Imposing
narrow banking would not eliminate the issuance of risky demand debt and the concomitant
dilemma of bank runs, but would handicap
financial intermediation. This is why, from the
earliest known banks in Italy in 1200 A.D. to the
present, risky banks that issued demand debt
dominated those issuing claims on "safe" stores
of value.

RandallJ.Pozdena
Vice President
References

Bryan, L. 1991. "A Blueprint for Financial Reconstruction:' Harvard Business Review (May-june)
pp.73-86.
Jacklin, c. 1987. "Demand Equity and Deposit Insurance:' Graduate School of Business, Stanford
University. Research Paper No. 1062, (rev. April
1990).
Myers,S., and N. Majluf. 1984. "Corporate Financing
and Investment Decisions When Firms Have Information that Investors Do Not Have:' Journal of
Financial Economics, 13, pp. 187-221.
Pozdena, R. 1990. "Bank Failures, Danish Style." Federal Reserve Bank of San Francisco Weekly Letter
(August 3).

Opinions expressed in this newsletter do not necessarily refled the views of the management of the Federal Reserve Bank of
San Francisco, or of the Board of Governors of the Federal Reserve System.
Editorial comments may be addressed to the editor or to the author.•.. Free copies of Federal Reserve publications can be
obtained from the Public Information Department, Federal Reserve Bank of San Francisco, P.O. Box 7702, San Francisco 94120.
Phone (415) 974·2246, Fax (415) 974-3341.
Printed on recycled paper Q
..:i.
with soybean inks.
~ ~

01': U,6 V::> 'OJsPUP.I:I upS
lOLL x08 ·O·d

O)SI)UOJ~

JO

UOS

~U08

aAJaSa~ IOJapa~

~uew~Jodea 4)JOeSe~
Index to Recent
DATE

NUMBER

4/26
5/3
5/10
5/17
5/24
5/31
6/7
6/14
7/5
7/19
7/26
8/16
8/30
9/6

(91-17)
(91-18)
(91-19)
(91-20)
(91-21 )
(91-22)
(91-23)
91-24
91-25
91-26
91-27
91-28
91-29
91-30

9/13
9/20
9/27
10/4
10/11
10/18
10/25
11/1

91-31
91-32
91-33
91-34
91-35
91-36
91-37
91-38

TITLE

Issues of FRBSF Weekly Letter
AUTHOR

Record Earnings, But...
Zimmerman
The Credit Crunch and The Real Bills Doctrine
Walsh
Levonian/Cheng
Changing the $100,000 Deposit Insurance Limit
Recession and the West
Cromwell
Financial Constraints and Bank Credit
Furlong
judd/Motley
Ending Inflation
Trehan
Using Consumption to Forecast Income
Free Trade with Mexico?
Moreno
Is the Prime Rate Too High?
Furlong
Consumer Confidence and the Outlook for Consumer Spending Throop
Real Estate Loan Problems in the West
Zimmerman
Sherwood-Call
Aerospace Downturn
Public Preferences and Inflation
Walsh
Bank Branching and Portfolio Diversification
Laderman/Schmidt!
Zimmerman
The Gulf War and the U.S. Economy
Throop
The Negative Effects of Lender Liability
Hermalin
M2 and the Business Cycle
Furlong/judd
Glick
International Output Comparisons
Is Banking Really Prone to Panics?
Pozdena
Levonian
Deposit Insurance: Recapitalize or Reform?
Zimmerman
Earnings Plummet at Western Banks
Neuberger
Bank Stock Risk and Return

The FRBSF Weekly Letter appears on an abbreviated schedule in june, july, August, and December.