View original document

The full text on this page is automatically extracted from the file linked above and may contain errors and inconsistencies.

FRBSF

WEEKLY LETTER

November 17, 1989

Eastward, Ho!
Between 1980 and 1988, California's population
grew by 20 percent, but growth varied widely
within the state. The San Francisco Bay Area
claimed three of the state's slowest growing
counties: Marin, San Francisco, and San Mateo.
None of these counties grew more than 10 percent during this eight-year period. The state's
fastest-growing counties, in contrast, added
population at rates at least double the statewide
average. Three of California's fastest-growing
large counties, EI Dorado, Riverside, and San
Bernardino, lie east of large metropolitan areas.
Thus, inland areas of California seem to be
experiencing the most rapid growth.
The logic behind this growth is compelling, both
for firms and for individual households. Households find housing more affordable, and avoid the
crime and smog of the big cities. Firms pay lower
costs for land and labor, but still have access to
large metropolitan markets. Many who live and
work in these inland areas also avoid the long
commutes that would be required if they worked
in the larger metropolitan areas.
This Letter examines the geographical patterns of
population and economic growth in California. It
focusses on the differences in the cost of locating
in different parts of the state, drawing some implications for future patterns in the state.

The conventional wisdom
Many argue that the high cost of housing is
stifling growth in the San Francisco and Los
Angeles areas. According to this argument, high
housing costs discourage new migrants from
locating in these high-cost areas, motivate current residents to "cash out" and move to areas
where they can get more house for their money,
and force downtown workers who lack substantial down payments to head further away from
the city center to find affordable homes. Thus,

population growth should be slower in regions
with higher home prices, and faster in regions
with lower home prices.
Current relative home prices in different parts of
California provide fuel for this argument. Median
home prices in the Central Valley and RiversideSan Bernardino areas ranged between $100,000
and $125,000 during the spring of 1989. While
these prices are not low compared to prices
nationally, they compare very favorably to the
statewide median of close to $200,000, and to
the $250,OOO-plus price tags common on homes
in nearby coastal areas.

A more complex relationship
Other things equal, it makes sense that households would tend to locate in regions where they
face lower costs. However, other things are not
equal. High-cost regions have high home prices
because home buyers find these regions attractive and expect their economies to continue
doing well. The specific attraction is likely to
differ from one person to another; it could be
a combination of job opportunities, weather,
cultural or sporting opportunities, and scenery.
Because high home prices reflect fundamental

strengths of a region and its economy, determining the extent to which high home prices are
having a negative impact on the region's growth
can be a difficult task. In fact, the statistical
problems involved in correctly estimating the
impact of housing prices on population growth
are formidable. However, analysis of the simple
relationship between the level of house prices
and the rate of population growth in a given area
may provide some indication whether the detrimental effects of high housing prices tend to
outweigh the positive forces that are responsible
for those high prices. If high house prices generally have had a detrimental effect on regional

THE WESTERn ECOnOmy

The Western Economy is a quarterly
Weekly Letter

review of economic conditions in the Twelfth Federal Reserve District. It is published in the
on the third Friday of February, May, August and November.

FRBSF
growth within California, regions with high house
prices should have tended to experience relatively slower population growth.
During the 1950s and 1960s, there was a positive·
and statistically significant relationship between
housing prices and growth. That is, regions with
higher housing prices in the 1950s and 1960s
tended to experience more rapid growth. This
relationship evaporated during the 1970s; housing prices were completely uncorrelated with
population growth. Duringthe 1980s, home
prices were negatively correlated with subsequent growth. That is, California counties that
had higher housing prices in 1980 tended to
experience slower rates of population growth
between 1980 and 1989.
In light of these observations, one should be
careful about claiming that high housing prices
always stifle population growth. Regions that are
healthy economically tend to have high housing
prices, but they also provide economic opportunities that attract additional residents to the
area. The effect of this strength can outweigh the
detrimental effects of high housing costs, as the
experience of the 1950s and 1960s suggests.
Thus, high housing costs in the San Francisco
and Los Angeles areas should be seen as a sign
of fundamental strength, even though they may
lead to some slowing of growth in these areas.

Business growth
The same factors that might attract people to
low-cost areas also might attract firms. In outlying areas, firms can benefit from proximity to the
huge markets the greater San Francisco and Los
Angeles areas represent, while enjoying the
considerably lower costs available outside those
markets. Land costs are lower and land is more
available. Labor costs also are lower. Fewer traffic
snarls allow easier movement of people and
materials to work locations.
Thus, it is not surprising that job growth in the
198Qs has been rapid in the parts of California
with fast-growing populations. During the fouryear period from 1984 to 1988, employment
expanded by 3.4 percent in California, but by
more than six percent in EI Dorado County and
in the Riverside-San Ber[1ardino area.
While lower-cost regions might be expected to
attract business activity in general, the attractions
are likely to be greater for some kinds of firms

than for others. Specifically, the lower-cost areas
of the state are likely to be particularly attractive
to manufacturing and back-office activities that
require large amounts of space and are sensitive
to labor costs. It's not surprising, therefore, that
manufacturing employment in EI Dorado County
and in the Riverside-San Bernardino area grew at
better than a six percent annual rate between
1984 and 1988, even though manufacturing
employment statewide grew at an annual rate
of only one percent.

A look ahead
Because the differences in land and housing
costs remain large between the Los Angeles and
San Francisco areas and the lower-cost regions
adjacent to them, further rapid growth in the
lower-cost parts of the state is likely. While the
Los Angeles and San Francisco areas should .
continue growing, they are likely to grow more
slowly than the lower-cost regions adjacent
to them.
An even more likely prospect is that the regional
specialization of activities within the state will
continue. The Los Angeles and San Francisco
areas will continue to specialize in high-value
activities like finance, law, and research and
development that are not particularly costsensitive and require the infrastructure of these
major metropolitan areas. Activities that are more
cost-sensitive, such as line manufacturing and
back-office business services, in contrast, are
likely to experience their greatest expansion in
lower-cost areas, either within California or
outside its borders.
These two observations suggest that Cal ifornia's
Central Valley economy, in particular, will continue to grow and to diversify away from its
traditional farming-oriented activities, developing
a larger manufacturing and export-service base.
It is worth noting, however, that growth in this
inland area may bring problems as well as possibilities. As economic activity increases and land
use becomes more intense, some of the advantages of the interior locations likely will be
eroded. The kinds of growth control measures
that have become prevalent in the San Francisco
and Los Angeles areas could become more popular in the inland areas, as traffic and smog
problems become more severe.

Carolyn Sherwood-Call
Economist

DISTRICT INDICA TORS
(Seasonally Adjusted)
89Q3

89Q2

89Q1

88Q4

88Q3

88Q2

88Q1

87Q4

AGRICULTURE
U.S. CROP PRICES, 1985=100
DISTRICT CROP PRICES, 1985=100
FARM CASH RECEIPTS, MILLION S
CATTLE ON FEED, 1985=100
CATTLE PRICES, CALIFORNIA, S/CWT.

111.8
114.7
2671.1
92.1
63.0

115.2
120.7
2646.0
90.0
61.8

116.7
121.1
2565.3
93.1
61.7

112.4
112.1
2333.2
96.6
60.1

111.4
111.5
2318.2
95.9
61.4

102.4
92.6
2205.5
96.5
63.4

102.2
97.5
2365.5
94.1
61.6

100.2
104.3
2210.2
94.8
57.8

FORESTRY
LUMBER PRODUCTION, MILLIONS BOARD FEET
NORTHWEST LUMBER INVENTORY, MIL. BOARD FEET
U.S. LUMBER PRICES, 1986=100

1815.7
2543.6
123.9

1652.4
2447.8
119.3

1575.1
2421.3
122.2

1806.2
2568.1
122.5

1547.1
2462.1
121.3

1647.5
2504.1
123.9

1718.1
2522.0
121.7

1661.9
2462.7
121.6

ENERGY
SPOT PRICE OF OIL, S/BARREL
U.S. RIG COUNT
DISTRICT RIG COUNT
FUEL MINING EMPLOYMENT, 1985=100
U.S. SEISMIC CREW COUNT

19.3
900.7
71.1
81.7
131.3

20.5
891.6
69.5
79.7
130.3

18.5
772.8
67.1
77.8
135.4

14.8
800.1
65.8
79.1
151.1

15.2
957.8
93.4
82.7
184.0

17.3
1061.7
96.9
83.4
201.9

16.7
973.8
79.1
81.4
199.1

18.8
1002.2
99.5
82.0
189.8

MINING
MINERAL PRICES, 1986=100
METAL MINING EMPLOYMENT, 1985=100

129.4
179.8

136.9
176.5

150.4
174.1

146.7
166.7

135.2
161.1

136.9
154.3

136.4
146.1

138.5
137.5

CONSTRUCTION
NONRESIDENTIAL AWARDS
RESIDENTIAL PERMITS
WESTERN HOUSING STARTS, THOUSANDS
CONSTRUCTION EMPLOYMENT, THOUSANDS

1637.9
30430
35.1
1004.3

1518.7
30763
37.7
991.1

1438.0
31470
29.6
987.1

1338.0
36229
33.0
966.8

1543.1
32725
36.3
946.2

1262.6
30907
36.8
933.7

1463.8
27923
28.5
920.0

1608.1
28694
27.9
906.8

MANUFACTURING
WAGES, CALIFORNIA, S/HOUR
EMPLOYMENT, THOUSANDS
DURABLES, 1985=100
CONSTRUCTION DURABLES, 1985=100
AEROSPACE, 1985=100
ELECTRONICS, 1985=100
SEMICONDUCTOR ORDERS, MILLIONS S, NOT S.A.

11.2
3159.0
104.3
113.1
119.1
99.6
1173.0

11.1
3156.2
104.2
112.5
118.1
99.4
1300.0

11.0
3157.4
104.3
114.1
116.8
99.9
1300.0

11.0
3136.4
103.5
112.5
115.4
100.4
1066.0

10.9
3103.5
102.7
110.0
114.2
99.1
1222.0

10.8
3101.1
102.5
111.2
113.6
97.8
1269.0

10.8
3089.2
102.3
111.4
113.6
97.0
1126.2

10.9
3056.3
101.5
110.1
112.4
95.2
1056.8

WHLS/RETAIL TRADE EMPLOYMENT, THOUSANDS
RETAIL SALES, PACIFIC DISTRICT, MIL. $

4676.5
23393

4642.6
23053

4629.5
22484

4561.3
22038

4531.2
21007

4485.8
20795

4452.5
20813

4407.5
20133

SERVICES EMPLOYMENT, THOUSANDS
HEALTH CARE, 1985=100
BUSINESS SERVICES, 1985=100
HOTEL, 1985=100
RECREATION, 1985=100

4990.4
118.3
130.2
127.5
110.7

4940.8
117.1
128.4
126.2
111.6

4912.3
116.2
128.6
125.4
110.9

4862.6
115.5
127.1
125.2
108.5

4796.0
114.3
126.3
122.2
104.6

4746.6
113.3
124.7
120.3
105.8

4691.7
112.4
122.2
119.5
106.6

4640.0
111.5
119.5
118.1
108.5

FINANCE, INSUR. AND REAL ESTATE EMPLOYMENT

1236.7

1227.5

1227.0

1220.3

1214.4

1208.9

1205.7

1202.1

GOVERNMENT EMPLOYMENT, THOUSANDS
FEDERAL GOVERNMENT
STATE AND LOCAL

623.8
2707.9

625.8
2664.5

627.8
2644.5

620.1
2622.1

613.9
2599.0

611.9
2576.2

613.2
2552.0

613.9
2537.9

Data are weighted aggregates of availabLe 12th District state data and are expressed as monthLy rates unLess otherwise noted.
District Indicator data are constructed by FRBSF research staff from pubLic and industry sources.

Opinions expressed in this newsletter do not necessarily reflect the views of the management of the Federal Reserve Bank of
San Francisco, or of the Board of Governors of the Federal Reserve System.
Editorial comments may be addressed to the editor (Barbara Bennett) or to the author.... Free copies of Federal Reserve
publications can be obtained from the Public Information Department, Federal Reserve Bank of San Francisco, P.O. Box 7702,
San Francisco 94120. Phone (415) 974-2246.

Ont6 V:l

'OJsPUl?J:I Ul?S

lOLL xog 'O'd

O)SI)UOJ~

JO

UOS

~U08

aAJaSa~ IOJapa~

~uaw~Jodaa l.pJOaSa~

Twelfth District Business Sentiment Index*

PERSCIIAL INCOIIE
ANNUALIZED PERCENT GROWTH RATES

%
89Q2

89Q1

88Q4

88Q3

8IlQ2

ALASKA
ARIZONA
CALIFORNIA
HAWAII
IDAHO
NEVADA
OREGON
UTAH
WASHINGTON

13.9
8.8
12.1
11.0
7.4
13.3
11.1
10.9
9.7

11.0
5.9
2.0
3.7
6.5
6.3
4.1
1.0
12.3

5.8
9.4
12.2
15.8
14.5
16.2
14.0
14.1
11.0

1.9
10.0
12.3
10.8
7.9
15.2
7.6
7.3
6.5

11.2
9.6
9.7
8.5
12.9
13.3
10.9
11.8
8.9

12TH DISTRICT
U.S.

11.5
8.5

3.6
6.4

12.2
11.1

11.0
8.2

9.9
8.3

(1988-89)

GNP

100

INFLATION

80

60
40

20

I5lI Worse

•

* Year-to-date
a

~1o~.r~~q.16t..,,~r"'~~q.,~1o"."'4,'i-)S'~Oo16t.."~~,,,~~q.,
~

~

* The index is constructed from a survey of approximatety
75 business leaders in the 12th Federal Reserve District.

__AGRICULlURAL EJlPLOYIlENT
ANNUALIZED PERCENT GROWTH RATES
89Q3

89Q2

89Q1

88Q4

IINBIPLO\'IlENT RATES
AVERAGE QUARTERLY DATA

88Q3

ALASKA
ARIZONA
CALIFORNIA
HAWAII
IDAHO
NEVADA
OREGON
UTAH
WASHINGTON

5.3
2.0
2.7
3.5
4.6
5.5
2.4
5.4
3.1

7.3
1.3
0.7
2.7
2.4
2.6
1.7
5.3
3.9

2.8
2.0
4.3
3.7
3.3
6.4
6.5
1.3
6.1

3.6
2.8
3.1
2.9
4.7
10.5
8.2
5.2
·6.7

0.3
0.1
3.1
2.9
4.0
7.4
4.7
3.2
2.7

ALASKA
ARIZONA
CALIFORNIA
HAWAII
IDAHO
NEVADA
OREGON
UTAH
WASHINGTON

12TH DISTRICT
U.S.

2.9
2.1

1.5
2.4

4.3
3.3

4.1
3.1

3.0
3.0

12TH DISTRICT
U.S.

* Year-to-date

* Year-to-date

89Q3

89Q2

89Q1

88Q4

88Q3

7.6
5.8
5.0
2.0
5.1
5.3
5.3
4.0
5.8

7.5
5.1
5.5
3.2
5.2
5.2
5.4
4.4
5.7

8.5
5.8
4.8
3.6
5.5
5.5
5.5
4.3
6.0

9.0
6.2
5.0
3.2
5.5
4.3
5.1
4.1
5.7

8.8
6.8
5.3
3.0
5.5
4.9
6.0
5.1
6.3

5.1
5.2

5.4
5.3

5.1
5.2

5.1
5.3

5.6
5.5

Same

rJ Better