View original document

The full text on this page is automatically extracted from the file linked above and may contain errors and inconsistencies.

FRBSF

WEEKLY LETTER

October 6, 1989

Deficits: Twins or Distant Cousins?
Large, persistent federal-budget and foreign-trade
deficits have been two of the most prominent
features of the
economy in the 1980s. There
has been considerable debate concerning the
relationship between these deficits and their
implications for the "health" of the economy in
the long run and standards of living of future
generations. From this debate two main opposing
views have emerged.

u.s.

One view is that the federal budget deficit
caused the trade deficit to develop, allowing
funds to be borrowed from abroad. This "twin
deficits" school of thought argues that these
foreign funds have supported rapid growth in
current consumption and government spending,
and that standards of living for future generations
in the
will be lower as a result.

u.s.

The alternative view is that the trade deficit has
been the result of improved investment opportunities in the
which have led to increased
foreign investment in this country and/or
decreased
investment abroad. In this view,
then, the trade deficit is evidence of economic
strength. The budget deficit is seen as a statistical
curiosity of little importance, and only a "distant
cousin" of the trade deficit.

U.s.,
u.s.

This Letter presents the arguments that lie behind
these two views. Although no consensus has
developed concerning which of them is more
correct, most economists would agree that the
economy has benefited from the emergence
of the trade deficit in the 1980s.

u.s.

Twins·
According to the "twin-deficits" hypothesis, the
large federal budget deficit is responsible for the
foreign trade deficit both directly and indirectly.
Expansionary fiscal policy embodied in the federal budget deficit has led to faster growth in
GNP and thereby contributed directly to an
increased demand for imports in the

u.s.

Most analysts have focused on the indirect effect
of the federal budget deficit. They argue that the

budget deficit caused the trade deficit to develop
by raising real interest rates and the dollar exchange rate. By raising the federal government's
demands on private credit markets, the budget
deficit caused real, or inflation-adjusted, interest
rates to rise. With higher expected returns available in the
relative to abroad, international
and domestic investors bid more aggressively for
dollar-denominated assets relative to those denominated in other currencies, causing the dollar
to appreciate. Moreover, the expectation that the
government's credit demands would persist
far into the future also may have contributed to
the dollar's rise.

u.s.

u.s.

u.s.

The higher dollar, in turn, made
goods
exported abroad more expensive and foreign
goods imported into this country less expensive.
The resultant rise in imports and fall in exports
led to the
foreign trade deficit.

u.s.

By definition, the excess of our imports over our
exports must be financed by an inflow of foreign
funds. Thus, the development of the trade deficit
was a mirror image of this net inflow. The availability of these funds mitigated, but did not
eliminate, the upward pressure on real (inflationadjusted) interest rates.

u.s.

The drop in the private saving rate in the
during the 1980s exacerbated the need for foreign
funds. Although the causes of the decline in saving are a matter of debate, it seems clear that
lower private saving put additional upward pressure on
real interest rates and thereby
contributed to the high dollar, the capital inflow,
and the trade deficit.

u.s.

No rosy future
According to the twin-deficits view, the overall
pattern of saving and investment in the
in
recent years does not present an optimistic picture of the future. The rise in real interest rates
reduced the rate of capital accumulation, although the inflow of foreign funds has kept
interest rates from rising by as much as they
otherwise would have. As a result, the funds

u.s.

FRBSF
obtained from abroad kept investment from
being choked off; however, these funds also
indirectly supported higher levels of consumption and government spending. Th~ net effect of
higher real interest rates and the inflow of foreign
funds is that investment probably has been
.
reduced to some extent, and certainly has not
been enharfced.
The lower level of capital formation, inturn,
probably has red.uced the long-term growth
prospects of the U.S. economy. Moreover, the
build-up in foreign debt represents a substantial
claim on the incomes of future generations. In
combination, these developments suggest a decline in future standards of living. In effect, the
twin-deficits view suggests that a burden will be
placed on future generations of taxpay~rs, who
will be forced to dip into lower incomes to pay
for the high level of current spending that the
present generation has enjoyed.

Distant cousins
The alternative school of thought se~s the budget
and trade· deficits as two separate issues-or at
most "distant cousins:' rather than twins. Many
economists who make this argument rely on a
concept called Ricardian equivalence. Named
after the great nineteenth century Engl ish
economist, David Ricardo, who first described
the concept, Ricardian equivalence posits that
when the government finances an increase in
expenditurethroughan increase in debt, the
public responds by increasing saving enough to
cover (the discounted present valu~ of) the
implicit future tax liability.
Thisimpliesthat increased saving by the private
sectorin response to a budget d.eficit will prevent
real interest rates from rising; the increased
demand for funds in credit markets will be met
by a higher supply of funds as the public saves
more. Thus the link from the budget to the trade
deficit is broken: since the budget deficit does
not cause real interest rates to rise, it cannot
cause either the dollar to appreciate or the trade
deficit to develop.

Investment boom
If the budget deficit does not explain high real
interest rates and th~ trade deficit, what does?
The distant-cousins vi~w suggests that Reagan
fiscal policy provides an answer, but a very different one from that of the twin-d~ficits view. The

cuts in marginal tax rates, and more generally,
the free-market, anti-regulation attitudes of the
Reagan Administration, it is argued, have reduced tax and regulatory distortions, enabling
the
economy to operate more efficiently
and generate more output and income.

u.s.

The greater productivity of resources, in turn, has
led to increased demand for financial capital and
higher real interest rates in the u.s. These higher
returns have made dollar-denominated assets
more desirable, raising the world-wide demand
for dollars and driving up the dollar exchange
rate. The higher dollar has caused the trade deficit to develop, thereby allowing capital to flow in
from abroad.
Given that foreign capital is viewed as having
flowed into the
to finance investment in
plant and equipment, the increase in foreign
indebtedness is unlikely to be a burden on future
generations. The expansion in our capital stock
associated with the inflow of foreign funds is
adding to the future rate of growth of the
economy, and thus should generate the income
necessary to retire the debt, while still allowing
for higher living standards in the future.

u.s.

Thus, although the Reagan tax cuts probably
contributed to the federal budget deficit, Ricardian equivalence suggests that the budget deficit
has not had an effect on the saving-investment
balance, nor on the long-run prospects for the
U.S. economy.

Evidence
Clearly, both views can explain the simultaneous
rise in the budget and trade deficits, as well as
the high levels of real interest rates and dollar
exchange rates. Moreover, both views can explain the rapid growth in theeconomy over the
past six years. The twin-deficits view relies on
the standard, business-cycle effect of expansionary fiscal policy: increased aggregate demand
associated with expansionary fiscal policy stimulated real GNP growth. The alternative view suggeststhat increased aggregate supply associated
with higher capital formation has provided the
stimulus to spending that has propelled real
GNP.
These two views have different implications for
the long-run growth rate of the economy. Under
the twin-d~ficits view, there is no reason to

assume that long-run growth has been raised by
developments in recent years, since rapid growth
represents only a normal cyclical response to
demand factors. The alternative view suggests
that real GNP permanently may be growing more
rapidly. Unfortunately, it is not possible yet to
determine statistically whether the rate of real
GNP growth has changed permanently.
Another way to determine which view is correct
is to analyze the evidence on whether previous
government deficits have been associated with
high real interest rates, trade deficits, and low
private saving rates in the U.s. and in other countries.Unfortunately, despite muc:h research on
the subject, evidence can be found to accept or
reject the implications of both views, and thus is
currently of little help.
Some economists have attempted to discredit the
twin-deficits view by pointing out that the federal
budget deficit really has not been as large in the
1980s as it appears to have been. Serious measurement errors exist in official budget data. For
example, no distinction is made in the federal
budget between current and capital expenditures, and the officially stated federal receipts do
not include the "inflation tax" that is "raised"
when the government is able to pay back its debt
in dollars with eroded purchasing power. Proponents of the twin-deficits hypothesis couriter that
even after the budget is adjusted to account for
these factors, the (high-employment) federal budget moved sharply from surplus to deficit in the
early 1980s.
Economists also have examined the data on
saving and investment in the 1980s for clues as to
which view of the budget and trade deficits is
correct. Investment in plant and equipment does
show rapid growth, as would be predicted by the
view that enhanced investment opportunities
explain the trade deficit. However, investment
normally rises rapidly in economic expansions,
and has risen by no more than the average
amount registered in post World War II expansions in the
Although this observation would
seem to contradict the distant-cousins view,
some economists have argued that investment
has been quite rapid, given the high real-interestrate environment. The contrary position is that
such an argument depends on the particular in-

u.s.

vestment equation one chooses, and is subject to
considerable controversy.
A similar debate exists with respect to the private
saving rate. Contrary to the prediction of Ricardian equivalence, the officially measured saving
rate actually has declined as the budget deficit
has risen. This evidence suggests that the linkage
between the budget and trade deficits has not
been broken by increased private saving, so the
budget deficit may well have been a driving
force in the
economy in the 1980s. However,
some economists argue that without the budget
deficit, the private saving rate would have fallen
even more than it did, and that the Ricardian
effect was important. Again, however, these
assertions are based upon controversial econometric models of saving.

u.s.

Benefits of the trade deficit
Although the debate among economists about
what caused the trade deficit is not resolved,
both schools of thought can agree that the emergence of the trade deficit has been beneficial
for the U.S. economy in the 1980s. Under the
distant-cousins hypothesis, the emergence of
the foreign trade deficit permitted an inflow of
foreign funds that were used for increased investIn this sense, the trade deficit
ment in the
has been highly beneficial to the U.S. economy.

u.s.

Under the "twins" hypothesis, the trade deficit
also had beneficial effects. In the face of large
budget deficits and low personal saving rates, the
inflow of foreign capital associated with the rise
in the trade deficit kept real interest rates from
rising even more than they did. Without this foreign capital, even more business spending on
plant and equipment would have been choked
off, further dimming the longer-run prospects for
growth of the U.S. economy.
These considerations argue forcefully against
protectionist trade legislation. Such legislation
could seriously restrict the flow of goods and
capital internationally, significantly raise interest
rates, and reduce prospects for economic growth
in the U.S. and around the world.

John P. Judd
Vice President and
Associate Director of Research

Opinions expressed in this newsletter do not necessarily reflect the views of the management of the Federal Reserve Bank of
San Francisco, or of the Board of Governors of the Federal Reserve System.
Editorial comments may be addressed to the editor (Barbara Bennett) or to the author.... Free copies of Federal Reserve
publications can be obtained from the Public Information Department, Federal Reserve Bank of San Francisco, P.O. Box 7702,
San Francisco 94120. Phone (415) 974-2246.

r

Research Department

Federal Reserve
Bank of
San Francisco
P.O. Box 7702
San Francisco, CA 94120