View original document

The full text on this page is automatically extracted from the file linked above and may contain errors and inconsistencies.

Changing M oney D em and?
How much money is enough? To
the layman, the answer may be
evident, but to the economist, it's a
very complex subject, especially
since long-run relationships linking
the demand for money to the level
of economic activity and interest
rates appear to have broken down
since mid-1974. Moreover, a wrong
answer could be dangerous, for if
policymakers miscalculate the
amount of money that businesses
or households need to carry out
their transactions, recession or in­
flation could result—depending on
the direction of the error.
Several puzzling pieces of evidence
have surfaced in recent months to
suggest a possible shift in the
nation's demand for money. First,
some econometric models have
been systematically overforecasting
the money demand, generating
predictions which are significantly
greater than the actually realized
magnitudes. Second, velocity (mon­
ey turnover) has risen rapidly dur­
ing the recovery period, suggesting
a decline in the volume of money
needed to support a given level of
transactions. Third, short-term in­
terest rates have generally moved
downward since last fall, quite in­
consistent with the recovery in ec­
onomic activity and the upsurge in
velocity.
These three observations would
suggest that the demand for money
has fallen sharply, making it possi­
ble for people to reduce their cash
balances at each level of income
and yet feel sufficiently liquid to
permit a decline in interest rates. If
1




a decline in money demand has
actually occurred, then the provi­
sion of a slower growth in money
supply is appropriate to finance the
recovery. However, if money
demand has not declined, then a
somewhat more rapid growth in
money supply is needed to finance
the recovery.
Some analysts are not convinced
that the demand for money has
changed. They point to the relative
stability in money demand in the
past in the face of major changes in
financial institutions, economic
conditions, and shocks to the inter­
national economic system. They
suggest that the simultaneous over­
forecasting of money demand in
large models, rise in velocity and
falling interest rates can be
explained by factors other than a
decline in money demand.
Evidence from econometrics

Consider the over-forecasting of
money demand in various econo­
metric models. Whereas the actual
money supply (M-i) totaled about
$295 billion in the fourth quarter of
1975, the typical model would sug­
gest that households and businesses
desired to hold at least 5 percent
more than that, judging from past
relationships of income, interest
rates and money. This gap had
gradually developed from mid-1974
to the end of 1975. The gap does
not appear to have widened in
recent months.
This overforecasting of money de­
mand could come about either be­
cause of a decline in money de(continued on page 2)

Opinions expressed in this newsletter do not
necessarily reflect the views of the management of the
Federal Reserve Bank of San Francisco, nor of the Board
of Governors of the Federal Reserve System.

mand or because of the inappropri­
ateness of the interest rate chosen
to measure the opportunity cost of
holding money. Typically, the
Treasury bill rate is used for this
purpose, since it gives such a good
fit for past periods. However, the
bill rate may not have been the best
measure in the 1974-75 period, be­
cause of the substantial rise in risk
as perceived by households and
businesses appropriate to the re­
cent era of unprecedented inflation
and recession. Risk aversion has
shown up in many ways: a sharp
rise in the savings rate; a rising
preference to hold currency rather
than bank deposits; a conservative
investment demand by corpora­
tions in the face of a strong recov­
ery in corporate sales and profits;
and a decision by banks to widen
the spread between their loan rates
and the cost of their funds.
It could be argued that the defaultfree Treasury bill rate is inappropri­
ate in this setting and it should be re­
placed by a rate which incorporates
risk. It could be measured by the
wide rate spread between lower­
rated and higher-rated corporate
bonds, such as has appeared since
mid 1974. However, there are no
comparable published risk differ­
entials for lower and higher rated
short-term instruments, which are
the standard measures used in
money-demand equations. One
possible alternative would be the
bank prime business-loan rate. This
is not a completely satisfactory al­
ternative, but it does produce bet­
ter forecasts of the demand for
2




money from mid-1974 to end-1975
than the T-bill rate does. If the risk
argument is correct, then the de­
mand for money is just as stable
now as in the past. The incentive to
economize on non-interest earning
cash balances is measured best by
the higher interest rates the private
sector faces, rather than by the
default-free interest rate on short­
term government securities.
Evidence from velocity

The large rise in velocity in the
second half of 1975 tends to corrob­
orate the econometric-forecasting
evidence regarding the reduction
in the demand for money. This rise
in velocity was unusually rapid, ex­
ceeding a 10-percent annual rate—
compared with trend growth of less
than 3 percent. If we are entering a
period of unpredictable move­
ments in money turnover, it means
increasingly unstable relationships
between money and income due
possibly to an increased instability
in the demand for money.
A close look at the data suggests
that velocity has not moved signifi­
cantly away from the levels that
might be expected at this stage of
the business cycle. Recent move­
ments have paralleled the typical
cyclical pattern, with velocity
growth above trend in the upswing
of the cycle and below trend in the
downswing. Velocity fell signifi­
cantly below trend in the three
quarters preceding the cyclical
trough in the second quarter of
1975. The rise in the first three
quarters of recovery has just re­
turned velocity to its trend level.

Moreover, the magnitude of the
recent deviation from trend was
actually less than in certain earlier
periods, such as 1966-67. Indeed, in
that particular period, similar ques­
tions were raised about changes in
the demand for money but later
evidence indicated the absence of a
significant shift.
Evidence from interest rates

The unexpected decline in interest
rates in late 1975 and early 1976, like
the evidence provided by forecast­
ing models and velocity data, tends
to support the argument for a de­
clining demand for money. Typical­
ly, rising rates go along with the
type of recovery in output and
velocity that we have recently expe­
rienced, so that the sudden decline
was quite unexpected.
It should be recalled that the mar­
ket interest rate is made up of two
components, the real rate and an
inflation premium. The real rate is
determined by the real demand for
credit and other “ real” factors. The
inflation premium in short-term
interest rates is determined by re­
cent inflation experience. The dif­
ferential impact of these two ele­
ments goes a long way in explaining
a number of surprising twists in
short-term markets during the last
several years. For example, the
upsurge in rates in the first half of
1974 occurred when real GNP
and real credit demand was
declining.
What explains this and other unu­
sual movements in interest rates? To
a large extent, short-term inflation
3




expectations. Inflation, of course,
has always had a major impact on
short-term interest rates, but in the
past, inflation has usually risen only
during boom periods. But then, in
the past several years, inflation has
moved independently of cyclical
movements in real output. Thus, in
1974, when interest rates rose to
unprecedented levels in the face of
a decline in real GNP, they appar­
ently reflected that period’s un­
precedented high level of short-run
inflation expectations, offsetting
the impact of the concurrent de­
cline in real GNP. By the same
token, the current fall in short-term
interest rates is associated with a
recent slowing in inflation and thus
in short-run inflation expectations.
Taken together, the three develop­
ments cited—overforecasting of the
money demand, rising velocity and
falling interest rates—could suggest
a decline in the nation’s demand
for money. But as indicated, there
may be alternative explanations for
these phenomena. The moneydemand equation yields different
results with the choice of an inter­
est rate that incorporates a high-risk
premium; velocity may not be too
far out of line given the present
stage of the business cycle; and
interest rates may not be too far out
of line given the fall in short-run
inflation expectations. The issue is
uncertain, and the jury of economic
theorists may remain split for years
to come. Unfortunately, policy­
makers have to deal with these
uncertainties while the jury is
still out.
Michael Reran

uo}8umsB/v\ •
• uoSaJO • bpbaon . oqepi
MBMBH • BjUJOJjlBJ • EUOZjjy . E>)SB| v

• J j | 0 '0 3 S J3 U B JJ UBS

ZSZ

O N

llW liH d

aivd

a o v is o d s n
n v w s s v i d is m j

upjn8®8a>^fl

BANKING DATA—TWELFTH FEDERAL RESERVE DISTRICT
(Dollar amounts in millions)
Selected Assets and Liabilities
Large Commercial Banks

Amount
Outstanding
4/14/76

+
+
+
+
+
+
-

Loans (gross, adjusted) and investments*
Loans (gross, adjusted)—total
Security loans
Commercial and industrial
Real estate
Consumer instalment
U.S. Treasury securities
Other securities
Deposits (less cash items)—total*
Demand deposits (adjusted)
U.S. Government deposits
Time deposits—total*
States and political subdivisions
Savings deposits
Other time deposits^
Large negotiable CD's

88,360
65,769
2,193
23,010
19,534
10,688
9,998
12,593
88,394
25,033
430
61,314
6,611
25,612
26,721
11,635

Weekly Averages
of Daily Figures

Week ended
4/14/76

Member Bank Reserve Position
Excess Reserves
Borrowings
Net free(+)/Net borrowed (-)
Federal Funds—Seven Large Banks
Interbank Federal fund transactions
Net purchases (+)/Net sales (-)
Transactions of U.S. security dealers
Net loans (+)/Net borrowings (-)

Change
from
4/07/76
397
403
455
2
38
29
12
18
654
293
42
285
448
87
426
662

Change from
year ago
Dollar
Percent
+
+
+
+
+
+
+
+
-

+
+
+
+
+
+
+
+
-

2,077
120
675
1,193
172
822
2,268
71
3,278
1,172
125
1,936
553
6,104
2,455
4,205

Week ended
4/07/76

2.41
0.18
44.47
4.93
0.87
8.33
29.34
0.56
3.85
4.91
22.52
3.26
7.72
31.29
8.41
26.55

Comparable
year-ago period

42
16
58

61
0
61

+ 1,338

+ 1,139

+ 2,584

+ 1,419

+

+ 1,303

-

779

+

6
1
5

•Includes items not shown separately, individuals, partnerships and corporations.

Editorial comments may be addressed to the editor (William Burke) or to the author. . . .Information
on this and other publications can be obtained by calling or writing the Public Information Section,
Federal Reserve Bank of San Francisco, P.O. Box 7702, San Francisco 94120. Phone (415) 544-2184.