View original document

The full text on this page is automatically extracted from the file linked above and may contain errors and inconsistencies.

FABSF

WEEKLY LETTER

October 5, 1984

Call to ARMs
The Adjustable Rate Mortgage (ARM), once an
oddity in the residential mortgage industry, now
commands a major share of new mortgage originations. In the first quarter of 1984, for example,
ARMs ofvarious types represented over 60 percent
of home mortgages originated by banks, savings
and loan associations and other institutionallenders. Some real estate analysts predict that in a few
years the traditional, fixed-rate mortgage (FRM)
will be the oddity, representing only ten or fifteen
percent of new originations.
This Letter examines the adjustable rate mortgage
trend and evaluates its effect on both the lending
industry and the housing sector in general. We find
that although the ARMis an important addition to
the existing array of mortgage instruments, it is not
likely to be the salvation ofthe lending and housing
industries that it is sometimes professed to be.

The ARM
An adjustable rate mortgage is simply a mortgage
instrument that provides for periodic adjustment
of the contract interest rate. At contractually specified intervals,a new monthly payment is computed
using the remaining principal, the revised contract
rate, and the remaining life of the mortgage. In the
pu rest form of the ARM, the adjustment and recomputation of the payment occu r very frequently and
the adjustments in the contract rate are tied to
movements in a short-term market rate. Such an
instrument has a value in the marketplace dependent only upon the outstanding principal of the
loan and thus can be considered free of interestrate risk to the holder of such debt.
The characteristics of this "pure" ARM contrasts
with an FRM (fixed rate mortgage) which, by virtue
of its fixed contract rate and payment, will have a
value in the secondary market that depends upon
ambient interest rate conditions. It is, of course,
this feature of the FRM that caused so much difficulty for mortgage lenders during the 1970s and
early 1980s when interest rates rose sharply and
unexpectedly and drove down the implicit market
value of the mortgage loan portfol ios of most
lenders.

To "immunize" or not
The rise in mortgage rates drew the lenders' atten-

tion to the ARM because the instrument offered
the prospect of "immunizing" the lender's portfolio from interest rate risk. A portfolio consisting
of adjustable rate mortgage assets and short-term
liabilities would not be subject to fluctuations in
net worth that resu It from fluctuating interest rates.
Although perfect immunization is possible with
ARMs in concept, there are a number of reasons
that interest rate risk considerations alone are unlikely to encourage the mortgage market to make
"pure" ARMs the predominant form of mortgage
instrumentation.
First, with a perfectly immunized portfolio, a lender
is implicitly abandoning one ofthe majorfunctions
of a financial intermediary: interest rate intermediation -the funding of fixed rate loans with shortterm liabilities. Presumably, institutional lenders
have performed this function because they enjoy a
comparative advantage over households in doing
so. They have superior access, for example, to
financial expertise and to mechanisms such as
futures markets to manage their risk-taking. If banks
and savings and loan associations abandon this
function, they may lose the marketto some other
form of institutional lender.
Put differently, because borrowers cannot manage
interest rate risk as cost-effectively as lenders,
lenders are likely to find that pure ARMs are attractive to borrowers only at implicit yields that are
lower (after adjusting for risk) than those enjoyed
on fixed rate instruments. This observation appears
to be borne out by the available data on the characteristics of the ARMs. For example, most of the
ARMs issued are actually hybrids of FRMs and
ARMs, with interest rate and payment "caps" that
impl icitly reintroduce some interest rate risk to the
lender. Apparently, pure ARMs appear to have
been difficult to market.

Default risk tradeoff
The second reason that the market share of ARMs
probably will be limited is the likelihood that
"adverse-selection" processes wi II make the ARM
borrower more likely to defau It than the FRM bor"
rower. This problem arises because ARMs probably
are most attractive to borrowers who believe that
interest rates have peaked and are likely to decline

FRBSF
over the remaining life of the instrument. These
same borrowers are likely to have structured their
other financial affairs in a manner consistent with
this expectation. Thus, if interest rates rise (contrary
to these borrowers' expectations), they may be
pushed into default.
This notion, too, is consistent with the available
data. Present default rates on ARMs are about 40
percent higher than for FRMs of similar value
issued in recent years. In addition, private mortgage insurance corporations charge a higher premium on ARMs than on FRMs and often will not
insure the "pure" ARMs at all.

from keeping pace with demand. In such a market,
financing constraints would reduce housing demand and prices and thereby partially offset the
effect of the financing constraint. Mechanisms,
such as ARMs, that provide rei ief from affordabi Iity
constraints, are self-defeating since the relief they
provide cou Id be capital ized into still higher home
prices. For example, housing economist James
Follain has argued thatthe home price boom of
the 1970s was partly initiated by the relaxation of
the affordability constraint caused by the inclusion
of spousal income in calcu lating the payment/
income ratio.

ARMs and.the housing cycle
ARMs and "affordability"
Risk considerations are not the only determinants
of the ultimate marketability of ARMs. One alleged
advantage of the ARM over the FRM is that it
relaxes the "affordability" constraint facing borrowers, thereby perlTlittinghome purchases when
the characteristics of the household or market
conditions normally would not.
The affordability constraihtappliesto the reiationship between mortgage payments and family income. In recent years, as interest rates and home
prices have risen, the mortgage payment on an
average newly purchased home has risen faster
than income. Since the payment/income ratio is
one of the underwriting criteria that lenders employ
in qualifying borrowers for mortgage loans, it is
argued that an increasing number of families find
themselves unable to qualify for home financing.
The ARM is claimed to provide relief from the
affordability constraint since its initial contract rate
is lower than that of the conventional FRM, making
the initial (or qualifying) payment also lower.
It is not clear that the method of housing finance
has anything but a transient effect on the "affordability" of housing. Housing prices have risen relative to prices of other goods and services in recent
years primarily because of growing demand in an
environment of land use controls and other developmental restrictions that have prevented supply

Although ARMs are thus unlikely to improve long~
term housing affordability, they may provide relief
at peaks of the interest rate cycle, offering the
prospect of a less erratic housing investment cycle.
The relationship between interest rates and housing
starts is complex (see Chart 1). Research conducted
at the San Francisco Reserve Bank suggests that
the level of housing starts is relatively insensitive
to the trend level of interest rates but reacts significaiitlyto interest rate"shocks";ยท(Inparticular,we
find that the steady-state level of housing starts is
approximately 1.6 million units annually but that
each sudden one percentage point rise in long-term
interest rates causes a transient reduction of about
250,000 units on an annual basis.) This phenomenon is consistent with the notion that affordability
is of greater cyclical than secular concern. Thus, if
the availability of ARMs provides affordable financing during interest rate peaks, it is possible that
ARMs smooth out the housing cycle.
Unfortunately, we have had too little experience
with ARMs to determine their effect on the housing
cycle conclusively. The data on the share of ARMs
among home mortgages is consistent with the notion that ARMs can rei ieve cycl ical affordabi Iity
problems for the homebuyer. As Chart 2 ind icates,
the ARM share rises sharply when interest rates
rise above trend and falls sharply thereafter. However, the size of the swings in recent housing start
cycles is not statistically different (after controlling

Chart 1
Housing Starts and Long-Term Interest Rates
1965-1984
Thouund lkllt8

Percent

2500

16

... Housing
Starts

2000

Ratel \
I \
I

~ AAM

6

1970

1975

1980

4
1985

for the effect of interest rate and general economic
conditions) from those of earlier periods when
ARMs were not available. This suggests that during
periods of positive interest rate shocks, borrowers
who would have used FRMs simply use ARMs
instead, gambling on a subsequent decline in rates.
In summary, ARMs appear to be something less
than the panacea for the lending and housing

15

./

13

I

.\ I

30

14

I
I

"...

I

40

1965

I

50
10
8

1000

MaIl<et/
I v

Sha,.

12

1500

Percent

16

70

14

Long-Term~'"

Interest

Percent

Chart 2
ARM Share of Mort~age Market
and Long-Term In erast Rates
1981-1984

I(

12

11

20
1982

1983

1984

industries that they are sometimes thought to be.
However, they do provide a mechanism for tailoring the interest-rate risk characteristics of lender
and household portfolios, and they do provide the
mortgage market with an additional mechanism
for coping with a world of volatile and uncertain
interest rates.
RandallJ.Pozdena

Opinions expressed in this newsletter do not necessarily reflect the views of the management of the Federal Reserve Bank of San
francisco, or of the Board of Governors of the Federal Reserve System.
Editorial comments may be addressed to the editor (Gregory Tong) or to the author .... Free copies of Federal Reserve publications
can be obtained from the Public Information Department, Federal Reserve Bank of San Francisco, P.O. Box 7702, San Francisco

94120. Phone (415) 974-2246.

uo~6U!4S0m

040PI

4o~n

!!omoH O!UJoJ!l0)

U060JO
ouoz!J\:)

OpOA0U
0l1sol\:)

O)SI)UOJ::I UOS

JO ~U08
aAJaSa~ IOJapa::l

'1!1l?:> 'o:>sPUl?J:! Ul?S
ZSL: 'ON l1WH:ld
mVd :I~VlSOd'S'n
llVW SSVl:> ISH I:!
OUHOS:lHd

~uaw~Jodaa LpJOaSa~

BANKING DATA-TWELFTH FEDERAL RESERVE DISTRICT
(Dollar amounts in millions)

Selected AssetS and Liabilities
Large Commercial Banks
Loans, Leases and Investments1 2
Loans and Leases1 6
Commercial and Industrial
Real estate
Loan's to Individuals
Leases
U.S. Treasury and Agency Securities2
Other Securities2
Total Deposits
Demand Deposits
Demand Deposits Adjusted 3
Other Transaction Balances4
Total Non-Transaction Balances6
Money Market Deposit
Accounts-Total
Time Deposits in Amounts of
$100,000 or more
Other Liabilities for Borrowed MoneyS

Weekly Averages
of Daily Figures
Reserve Position, All Reporting Banks
Excess Reserves (+ )/Deficiency (-)
Borrowings
Net free reserves ( + )/Net borrowed( - )

Amount
Outstanding

Chi:mge
from

9/19/84
182,932
163,971
48,939
60,947
29,911
5,050
11,787
7,175
188,986
44,007
29,021
12,170
132,808

9/12/84

Change from 12/28/83
Percent
Dollar
Annualized

442
523
286
39
177
3
89
10
-4,012
-3,165
- 275
- 474
- 374

-

-

-

6,907
8,616
2,976
2,048
3,260
13
720
988
2,011
5,230
2,310
605
3,823

-

-

-

5.3
7.5
8.8
4.7
16.7
0.3
7.8
16.5
1.4
14.5
10.0
6.4
4.0

37,671

-

314

-

1,926

-

6.6

40,888
21,915

-

232
8

-

2,723
1,092

-

09.7
6.4

Period ended

Period ended

9/10/84

8/27/84

23
39
15

60
68
7

1 Includes loss reserves, unearned income, excludes interbank loans
2 Excludes trading account securities
3 Exclucles U.S. government and depository institution deposits and cash items
4 ATS, NOW, Super NOW and savings accounts with telephone transfers

S Includes borrowing via FRB, TI&L notes, Fed Funds, RPs and other sources
6 Includes items not shown separately