View original document

The full text on this page is automatically extracted from the file linked above and may contain errors and inconsistencies.

FRBSF

WEEKLY LETTER

July 6, 1984

Budget Deficits and Foreign Savings
It has recently become popular to point out that
foreigners are financing a significant part of our
federal budget deficit. Many consider this a
fortuitous development that will allow the U.S. to
finance a large increase in domestic investment at
the same time. The only risk they see is that this
foreign saving might disappear as quickly as it
apparently developed, and drive U.S. interest
rates up in the process.
This Weekly Letter explains the foreign savings
inflow as another "economic distortion" associated with large budget deficits. More specifically,
the inflow results from an increase in our current
account deficit brought on by an appreciation of
the dollar. The dollar's increased strength comes
from the higher long-term interest rates, caused by
expectations of large budget deficits, that make
u.s. securities more attractive to foreign as well as
domestic investors. Because the inflow simply
mirrors the deterioration in ou r trade position with
the rest of the world, it involves costs to the
economy. Furthermore, this analysis suggests that
the withdrawal of foreign savings can only
develop slowly and is most likely to be associated
with a fall rather than a rise in U.S. interest rates.

Deficits and long-term rates
Budget deficits affect long-term interest rates
because financial makets are forward-looking.
That is, interest rates are strongly influenced by
expectations of developments in inflation,
business cycle growth and government deficits
over the next five to ten years.
As an example, take the actions of Congress and
the Administration to cut tax rates and increase
defense spending in 1981. By raising expectations
of future deficits, they also raised long-term
interest rates even though the actual deficit in
1981 was substantially less than those in the
period 1982-83. Indeed, the 20th century peak
in long-term Treasury interest rates occurred in
September 1981 (some weeks after the largest tax
cut in history became law) even while the inflation
rate was declining and the economy was in a
recession. In addition, tight monetary policy until
mid-1982 raised short-term interest rates relative

to long-term rates and thus also contributed to
generally higher in,terest rates at that time.
Chart 1 illustrates how the gap between inflation
and long-term nominal interest rates has widened
substantially since early 1981. Surveys offinancial
market participants indicate long-term expectalions of inflation have been in the 6.5 to 7 percent
range for the last two years. This suggests that real
long-term interest rates have been substantially
higher since 1981.

Interest rates and exchange rates
In general, the longer the maturity of the underlying U.s. dollar-denominated asset, the larger the
exchange rate response will be to a rise in interest
rates. This relationship is based on accepted interest rate arbitrage conditions that provide a link
between long- and short-term markets. It is based
on two offsetting factors that affect the foreign
demand for u.s. securities: real interest income
and exchange rate risk from holdi l1 g U.S. assets.
The higher is the real interest income from owning
U.s. relative to foreign assets, the greater will be
the foreign demand for U.S. assets. But, the greater
the risk of exchange rate loss a foreigner may suffer
from holding dollar assets, the less will be the
foreign demand for u.s. assets. A rise in U.S. real
interest rates will quickly increase the foreign
demand for U.S. assets and drive the current
exchange value of the dollar above its future
expected value. At the point when the extra interest earned on U.S. assets just matches the extra
exchange rate loss expected from future dollar
depreciation, there will be no further incentives
for foreigners to increase their demand for u.s.
securities, and the dollar exchange rate will reach
at least temporary balance.
The net of these two factors explains why longterm rates have a bigger impact on the exchange
value of the dollar than short-term rates. If U.S.
3-month interest rates increase by 1 percent, then
the extra interest rates abroad will be one-quarter
of a percent for three months. In this short-term
case, the exchange rate must only rise by onequarter of a percent now and be expected to fall by
the same amount over the next three months for
/

FRBSF
the exchange rate loss to just match the extra
interest income. However,if U.s. lO-year interest
rates rise by 1 percent, they would increase the
extra interestincome by 10 percentage points over
comparable foreign assets. For the exchange rate
loss to match this extra interest income, the
exchange value of the dollar must rise by 10
percentage poi nts now and be expected to decl ine
by one percent per year over the next ten years.
Expectations that budget deficits will rise significantly over the next 10 years tend to raise interest
rates on 1O-year securities. They also drive the
exchange value of the dollar up by approximately
10 times the rise in the interest rate. As can be seen
in Chart 2, the weighted average exchange value
of the dollar started to rise substantially in 1981, at
about the same time that real interest rates started
to rise.
If, as a first approximation, one assumes that the
exchange rate will return to its purchasing power
parity (PPP) value in the long-run, deviations of
exchange rates from PPP could be explained by
real interest rate differentials betweentheU.S. and
abroad. A 2.5 percent increase in U.S. reallO-year
rates over foreign 10-year rates would explain an
exchange rate 25 percent above PPP in mid-1982
and one which stays about 25 percent "overvalued" through early 1984 (see Chart 2).

International trade and foreign savings
When u.s. real interest rates started to rise in
1981, they led to an immediate increase in the
desire of foreigners to purchase U.5. securities
and, via the exchange rate mechanism described
above, to an immed iate appreciation of the dollar.
Only as the dollar appreciation increased our
trade and current account deficit could there
develop an actual inflow of foreign savings.
The U.5. current account is our broadest measure
of trade in goods, services and transfer payments
with the rest of the world. In 1981, the current
account registered a $5 billion surplus. By 1983, it
was $40 billion in deficit, and in the first quarter of
1984, about $78 billion in deficit (atannual rates).
While there will always be large gross flows of
funds into and outofthe U.5., a net foreign savings
inflow can occur only when the U.S. current
account is in deficit. Only in this way can U.S.
residents, on balance, go into debt to foreign residents. Thisdebt is satisfied by selling U.s. assets to
foreigners. Driven by the large federal budget defi-

cit, high real interest rates in the U.S. make it more
attractive for foreigners to purchase u.s. securities, whilethe high exchange value of the dollar
makes the purchase of U.5. goods less attractive.
U.S. interest rates are now most likely lower than
they otherwise would have been had foreign
savings inflows not increased significantly in the
last two years. As a resu It, the crowd ing out caused
by budget deficits has occurred in our net export
position rather than in domestic fixed investment.
This can be seen by comparing two statistics.
Business investment as of the first quarter of 1984
is almost 1 percent above its business cycle peak
in mid-1981:That is an unusually fast recovery in
investment this soon after a recession. On the
other hand, real net exports have declined by 3.5
percent of real GNP from mid-1981 to early 1984,
when in the same stage of previous business
cycles, it has typically increased. The U.s. export
and import-competing sectors are now smaller
than if they were not being "crowded out" by
government deficits.

Future course of foreign savings
How much longer can the U.S. current account
deficit and the foreign accumulation of U.S. assets
continue? And, are still higher interest rates
needed for foreigners to finance the $150-$200
billion cumulative U.s. current account deficits
forecast for the next two years?
One line of reasoning suggests that foreigners may
soon reach a limit on the amount of U.5. assets
they desire to hold even at current high U.S. real
interest rates. To put $150-200 billion oftheir
international portfolio into U.s. assets over the
next two years presumably would require an
increased risk premium. In such a case, only a rise
in U.s. interest rates, and/or a fall in the exchange
value of the dollar (thereby reduci ng the risks of a
further dollar depreciation) could induce foreigners to continue buying U.S. securities at a rate
equal to the size of our current account deficit.
However, at least with respect to the period
1984-85, the economic and political stability of
the United States argues that foreigners would
require relatively small risk premiums to increase
their holdings of U.S. securities. Given the highly
integrated international capital market, foreign
residents are probably as willing to hold an
increased share of U.s. assets as New York
residents are willing to hold of California assets.

Another line of reasoning suggests that a foreign
savings inflow of $150-200 billion over the next
two years, while unprecedented, can be sustained
because it wou Id represent on Iy 6-7 percent of the
net savings of other industrial countries of the
world. If such were the case, the only reason that
foreigners would reduce their demand for U.S.
assets is if there were a fall in U.s. real interest rates
or a rise in the expected rate of U.S. inflation
brought on by a change in U.S. monetary or fiscal
policy. If Congress and the Administration significantly changed fiscal policy by reducing the budget deficit, they would permit a decline in both
real and nominal interest rates. The desire of foreigners to hold u.s. securities would correspondingly decline and result in an immediate fall in the
exchange value of the dollar. Real interest rates
and exchange rates would fall together, reversing
their parallel rise since 1981. This would be a
healthy development because it would help el iminate the dollar's current "over-valuation" without
the need for a significant easing in monetary
policy that may increase fears of future inflation.
The alternative is for financial markets to think that
the expected large future deficits would be
financed by an increase in the money supply and
higherfuture inflation. Such an expectation would
reduce real interest rates by shifting the burden of
financing goverment spending away from industries that are significantly affected by tight credit
markets toward those households whose after-tax
incomes rise by less than the inflation rate.
This decline in real interest rates would probably
not be associated with a decline in nominal
interest rates, which would ultimately have to
increase to reflect the rise in inflation expectations. In this case, foreigners would lose confidence in the real purchasing power of their U.S.
assets, as occurred in 1977-78, and therefore
reduce their demand for such assets. The
exchange value of the dollar would decline
promptly as it did in the earlier period.
Conclusion
This analysis suggests thatthe most likely source of
a change in the foreign desire to hold u.s. assets
would be a change in U.S. monetary orfiscal
policy that significantly alters real interest rates or
inflation expectations. But while policy changes
can quickly affect the desire to hold U.S. assets,
actual foreign savings flows can change only
slowly, through adjustments in the U.S. current
account balance. Thus, exchange rates, but not

U.S. interest rates, could decline quickly in the
face of a decline in foreign preferences for U.S.
assets. Foreign savings flows would be reversed
only slowly as the dollar decline eventually leads
to a u.s. current account surplus. This would most
likely prevent U.S. interest rates from falling as
much as they othE!rwise would. However, the
outflow is not likely to be a strong independent
force in raising interest rates.
Michael Keran

CHART 1
Long-term Interest Rates and Inflation
Percent

16
14
12
10

. ;-~

~~

,
#fl.'
'-;

8 ....:""""'......_ - " ' ,
~~
~..
~
6
~....
.
4
Consumer Inflation·',
2L......L.--I_..L......._

1976

1978

.,.,

....................I1....

1980

1982

,

...

---I

1984

·Consumer inflation is measured by percent change of the Personal
Consumption Expenditure Deflator over one year earlier.

CHART 2
U.S. Dollar Exchange Rate
and Purchasing Power Parity
1975 = 100

125
120
115
110
105
100
95
90

L....&._.l.--L_-'---II--.;.a.._........L_............

1976

1978

1980

1982

1984

(Source: Morgan Guaranty 'World Financial Markets')
• Trade weighted index of foreign wholesale prices relative to U.S.
wholesale prices.

040 PI

!!omoH

O!UJoJUO)

ouozPtJ

0>1soltJ

O)SI)UOJj UOS

JO
.J!ll!:) 'o:>spUl!J::I Ul!S
lSL ·ON IIWH:ld
mVd:l9VISOd ·s·n
llVW SSVl:> ISHI::I
aUHOS:lHd

aAJaSa~

BANKING DATA-TWELFTH FEDERAL RESERVE DISTRICT

Loans, Leases and Investments 1 2
Loans and Leases 1 6
Commercial and Industrial
Real estate
Loans to Individuals
Leases
U.S. Treasury and Agency Securities 2
Other Securities 2
Total Deposits
Demand Deposits
Demand Deposits Adjusted3
Other Transaction Balances 4
Total Non-Transaction Balances 6
Money Market Deposit
Accounts-Total
Time Deposits in Amounts of
$100,000 or more
Other Liabilities for Borrowed MoneyS

Weekly Averages
of Daily Figures
Reserve Position, All Reporting Banks
Excess Reserves ( +)/Deficiency (- )
Borrowings
Net free reserves (+ )/Net borrowed( -)

Amount
Outstanding

Change
from

6/20/84
180,698
161,371
48,875
60,118
28,407
4,988
11,953
7,375
187,138
44,290
28,482
12,039
130,809

6/13/84
625
617
354
57
127
15
14
5
-1,434
- 637
-1,748
- 396
- 400

37,361

-1,702

39,403
23,661

-

change from 12/28/83
Percent
Dollar
Annualized

-

-

-

68
5,888

4,673
6,016
2,912
1,219
1,756
75
554
788
3,859
4,947
2,849
736
1,824
2,236
1,238
654

Period ended

Period ended

6/18/84

6/4/84

45
131
86

32
115
83

-

-

-

5.5
8.0
13.1
4.3
13.7
3.0
9.2
20.0
4.2
20.8
18.9
11.9
2.9
11.7
6.7
5.9

1 Includes loss reserves, unearned income, excludes interbank loans
2

IOJapaj

~uew~Jodea lpJOeSe~

(Dollar amounts in millions)

Selected Assets and Liabilities
Large Commercial Banks

~U08

Excludes trading account securities

3 Excludes U.s. government and depository institution deposits and cash items
4 ATS, NOW, Super NOW and savings accounts with telephone transfers

S Includes borrowing via FRB, TI&L notes, Fed Funds, RPs and other sources
6 Includes items not shown separately

Editorial comments may be addressed to the editor (Gregory Tong) or to the author ••.. Free copies of
Federal Reserve publications can be obtained from the Public Information Section, Federal Reserve
Bank of San Francisco, P.O. Box 7702, San Francisco 94120. Phone (415) 974-2246.