View original document

The full text on this page is automatically extracted from the file linked above and may contain errors and inconsistencies.

FRBSF

WEEKLY LETTER

Number 92-28, August 7, 1992

Are Big U.S. Banks Big Enough?
According to some observers, international bank-ing is like sumo wrestling-in one respect, at
least: An institution needs to be big to compete
and, generally, bigger is better. The analogy is
motivated by the prominence of Japanese banks
among the world's largest banks. A decade ago,
the U.s. had the two largest banking organizations in the world (by asset size), and only one
Japanese bank ranked among the top ten. But
today, the list of the ten biggest bankingorganizations includes eight Japanese banks and no
banks.

u.s.

This apparent reversal offortune has been used
to support the argument that U.S. banks are not
big enough to compete internationally. To some
extent the fuel for this argument has diminished
as the fall in the Japanese stock market and problem domestic and foreign loans have dulled the
luster of Japanese banks' performance. Nevertheless, the presence of foreign "mega"-banks
is still seen as a mandate for bigger banks in
the u.s. This Weekly Letter looks at this issue
by considering the evidence on the importance
of bank size to efficiency and international
competition.
Banking structure
The U.S. banking system is less concentrated
than the banking systems of many other countries_ In part this is due to the U.S.'s historical restriction on banks' geographk expansion. Over
the past decade, however, these legal barriers to
bank consolidation have been relaxed. For example, since 1983, the number of states permitting
statewide branching increased from 23 to 38,
wh i1e the number of limited branching states
declined from 19 to 11 and the number of unit
banking states fell from 8 to 1. In addition, all but
three states now have enacted legislation that
permits entry by certain out-of·state banks, with
most states allowing entry from any state. As a
result, since 1980, the number of commercial
banking organizations-that is, holding companies plus independent banks-has fallen from
about 12,700 to 9,700, a 24 percent drop.

Even with these changes, however, the number of
banks in the u.s. remains high relative to other

countries. Currently the U.s. has about forty commercial banking organizations per million people,
while the United Kingdom has around ten per
million, and Japan has a little more than one
per million.
Further consolidation in the u.s. banking system
will occur, since the banking industry is still adjusting to the changes in the regulatory environbanking
ment. But it is not likely that the
system will become as concentrated as the ones
in many other countries, both because of residual
limitations on geographic expansion and because
of the greater emphasis the
places on the anticompetitive effects of bank mergers. Although
in recent years regulators have approved more
bank mergers in light of increased nonbank competition, they will continue to keep antitrust considerations in the forefront.

u.s.

u.s.

Some are concerned that these regulations obstruct the economic forces that would "naturally" give rise to "mega"-banks here in the u.s.
In particular, they argue that restrictions on consolidation, particularly for large banks, sacrifice
efficiency, which is detrimental not only to the
u.s. banks' international competitiveness, but
also to their domestic customers.
Size and efficiency
The empirical research on efficiency in banking
raises doubts about how far the advantages of
size go. Most studies on cost efficiency suggest
that scale economies are exhausted well below
the size of the larger u.s. banks. Moreover, recent studies find that unexploited scale economies account for a relatively small part of the
overall variation in efficiency among banks. This
means that, beyond a point, the efficiency gains
owing to size may be small.

Bank mergers could increase efficiency in other
ways, however. For example, empirical research
finds that the measured degree of efficiency varies greatly among banks. One interpretation of
this finding is that the variation in efficiency is
due to differences in the way banks use inputs;
in other words, some banks simply may be managed better than others. In that case, a successful

FABSF
merger would involve a more efficient firm taking over a less efficient firm.
There are, of course, other reasons for bank mergers. One is portfolio diversification through geographic expansion. The changes in intrastate and
interstate banking laws mentioned above opened
the way for banks to pursue that objective through
mergers. The mergers that are intended to achieve
diversification could be viable, even without a
difference in the economic efficiency of the
banks being combined.
Whatever the motivation, the empirical evidence
on the effects of actual mergers suggests that,
though the resulting firm may be bigger, it is not
necessarily more efficient. For example, while
mergers tend to reduce personnel costs per unit
of output, those savings are often offset by increases in other costs. The evidence shows that
some bank mergers have improved efficiency
while others have decreased it, and on balance
the effects have been more or less neutral.
Even though formal statistical analysis does not
make much of a case for directly linking "mega"bank size and efficiency, the structure of banking
in much of Europe and Japan often is viewed as
evidence that large banks have a competitive
edge stemming from greater efficiency. This view
would be more persuasive if the banking systems
in other countries were clearly the results of
banks taking advantage of economic efficiencies.
However, just as regulatory policy has affected
banking structure in the U.s., regulatory policies
in other countries have influenced their banking
structures. In several major countries, policies
have limited the number of banks, which has
led to relatively concentrated banking structures.
The banking structures observed in these other
countries, then, are not proof that big banks are
generally more efficient in providing financial
services.

Are big banks better international competitors?
A look at which banks are active in international
banki ng suggests that size does matter to some
extent. Around the world, large banks are generally the only ones with any meaningful global
presence. In the U.s., for example, only the largest banks ($20 billion or more in assets) are materially involved in international banking. It is
interesting to note that most studies find that
scale economies for u.s. banks are exhausted

well before that point. This suggests that it is possible that scale economies in international banking continue beyond the point where they are
spent in other aspects of banking.
The advantages of size in international banking,
however, do not necessarily increase indefinitely.
In the U.s., many banks with over $20 billion in
assets are involved to a significant extent in overseas business. Among these large banks, size
does not seem to have much bearing on the degree of globalization. More specifically, among
the large banks, the importance of foreign activities relative to domestic banking is not strongly
related to the size of a bank. Moreover, the ability of some moderately large u.s. banks to have
50 percent or more of their activity related to
international banking suggests that they can
compete effectively. It is also important to note
that a good deal of international banking involves off-balance-sheet items, such as options,
swaps, and forward contracts. In this area, U.S.
banks have been very strong competitors, which
tends to belie the notion that u.s. banks are at a
disadvantage owing to their size relative to larger
foreign banks.
In other countries, the picture on asset size and
globalization is mixed. For japan, size is positively correlated with globalized activities. For
large globally active German banks, there does
not appear to be a connection between size and
globalization. For Canadian and French banks,
the correlation is negative-that is, the larger the
bank, the smaller its proportion of international
activity.

A look at the competition
The "mega"-banks we have been discussing so
far are not purely the creatures of favorable regulatory policy, of course. The growth in assets of
many large foreign banks relative to the large
U.s. banks also reflects domestic economic conditions in those countries. This clearly has been
the case for japan: A rapid economic expansion,
coupled with policies limiting the number of
banks, fostered the growth of the large banks. It
is not clear, however, that gains by a bank in its
domestic market necessarily translate into greater
competitiveness elsewhere in the world.
On this point, the experience of japanese banks
on our West Coast is interesting. In California,
Japanese-owned banks clearly are a presence,

with about 25 percent of banking assets. While
Japanese banks in the state naturally have an advantage in dealing with Japanese firms involved
in international trade, they do not appear to have
an advantage in providing banking services more
generally, nor have the Japanese banks had higher
earnings. During the past ten years, Japanese
banks' periOimance in terms of return on assets
(ROA) has not been better than that of domestically o\vned banks, on average. In fact, over the
past four years, domestically owned banks in
California have had a higher ROA. And, last year,
Japanese-owned banks in the state posted a net
loss, while domestic banks showed positive,
though modest, earnings. It is also interesting to
note that, as a group, other foreign banks operating in the u.s. have underperformed domestic
banks over the past several years. U.S. banks,
then, certainly are not at any disadvantage in
competing with foreign banks in U.s. markets.

Conclusion

Big banks in the u.s. are big enough to compete
effectively with their foreign counterparts. Therefore, the relative size of banks in the
compared to those in other countries should not be a
determining factor in the degree of consolidation
in the u.s. banking industry. Even without that
influence, though, further consolidation in the
u.s. banking system is inevitable. But the result
should be a competitive domestic banking system with numerous banks, including small banks
and several large banks that are active internationally, even if they do not match the ultra-mega
status of some of their foreign competitors.

u.s.

Fred Furlong
Economist,
Assistant Vice President

Opinions expressed in this newsletter do not necessarily reflect the views of the management of the Federal Reserve Bank of
San Francisco, or of the Board of Governors of the Federal Reserve System.
Editorial comments may be addressed to the editor or to the author.... Free copies of Federal Reserve publications can be
obtained from the Public Information Department, Federal Reserve Bank of San Francisco, P.O. Box 7702, San Francisco 94120.
Phone (415) 974-2246, Fax (415) 974-3341.
Printed on recycled paper Q
....
with soybean inks.
\V ~

Onl'6 V)

'OJSpUl!J:l Ul!S

WLL xog ·O·d

O)SI)UOJ::J UOS

JO

~uo8

a"Jasa~ IOJapa::J

~uew~Jodea l.pJOeSe~

Index to Recent Issues of FRBSF Weekly Letter

DATE NUMBER TITLE

AUTHOR

1/31
2/7
2/14
2/21
2/28
3/6
3/13
3/20
3/27
4/3
4/10
4/17
4/24
5/1
5/8
5/15
5/22
5/29
6/5
6/19
7/3
7/17
7/24

Walsh/Newman
Laderman
Schmidt
Dean
Sherwood-Call
Moreno
Motley
Kim
Glick
Cromwell
Hutchison/Judd
Throop
Zimmerman
Neuberger
Trehan
Schmidt/Dean
Cromwell/Schmidt
Sherwood-Call
Walsh
Sherwood-Call
Cromwell
Parry
Trenholme/Neuberger

92-05
92-06
92-07
92-08
92-09
92-10
92-11
92-12
92-13
92-14
92-15
92-16
92-17
92-18
92-19
92-20
92-21
92-22
92·23
92-24
92-25
92-26
92-27

Presidential Popularity, Presidential Policies
Progress in Retail Payments
Services: A Future of Low Productivity Growth?
District Agricultural Outlook
The Product Life Cycle and the Electronic Components Industry
Japan's Recessions
Will the Real "Real GDP" Please Stand Up?
Foreign Direct Investment: Gift Horse or Trojan Horse?
U.s. International Trade and Competitiveness
Utah Bucks the Recession
Monetary Announcements: The Bank of Japan and the Fed
Causes and Effects of Consumer Sentiment
California Banks' Problems Continue
Is a Bad Bank Always B~d?
An Unprecedented Slowdown?
Agricultural Production's Share of the Western Economy
Can Paradise Be Affordable?
.
The Silicon Valley Economy
EMU and the ECB
Perspective on California
Commercial Aerospace: Risks and Prospects
Low Inflation and Central Bank Independence
First Quarter Results: Good News, Bad News

The FRBSF Weekly Letter appears on an abbreviated schedule in June, July, August, and December.