View original document

The full text on this page is automatically extracted from the file linked above and may contain errors and inconsistencies.

D e p a ir a r if iie m

October 10,1975

Beyond Recycling
Nearly two years have elapsed
between the history-making
events of late 1973, when the
Organization of Petroleum Ex­
porting Countries quadrupled the
price of oil and embargoed ship­
ments to the U.S., and the more
prosaic events of September 1975,
when the OPEC nations deliber­
ated for a week before imposing a
relatively modest (for them)
increase in oil prices. In this situa­
tion, it would be useful to examine
how well the consuming nations
have been able to cope with this
difficult problem, and how well
the exporting nations have been
able to cope with circumstances
that normally would undermine
any cartel.
Following the end of the embargo,
developed and underdeveloped
countries alike were left with
enormous belance-of-payments
dislocations induced by the oil
price increase. To forestall com­
petitive unilateral currency depre­
ciations, import restrictions or ex­
cessive domestic restrictive poli­
cies, the major consuming nations
first concentrated on the prob­
lem of financing the huge current
account deficits created by the
sudden OPEC actions. Financing
mitigated—and postponed—the
real transfers of resources stem­
ming from the oil price increase.
Recycling experience
In the aggregate, the importing
countries' current-account deficit
has as its counterpart an equivalent
current-account surplus of the
exporting countries. Because this
1
Digitized for FRA SER


surplus must be invested some­
where, capital flows to oil­
importing countries in the aggre­
gate must necessarily balance their
aggregate current-account deficit.
As a practical matter, the bulk of
OPEC's financial surplus must be
invested in the world's principal
money and capital markets, which
are located in a comparatively few
major oil-importing countries. For
individual countries there are wide
differences between the size of
capital inflows and the size of
current-account deficits.
The Euro-currency markets,
which invested over one-third of
OPEC's $60-billion surplus last year,
performed reasonably well. The
U.S. absorbed almost one-fifth of
the total, and another one-fifth
went into various investments in
the U.K. and other developed
countries. The other one-fourth of
the $60-billion surplus represented
OPEC investments in the obliga­
tions of international institutions
such as the World Bank and the
IMF, loans and grants to developing
countries, and military assistance
to Arab states. Commercial banks
of the principal industrial countries
played a major role in facilitating
the flow of OPEC funds.
Despite this encouraging experi­
ence, there is some doubt that
large-scale recycling through pri­
vate money and capital markets can
continue indefinitely. Some of
the problems include: (1) the risks
resulting from loan exposure in
any one country, especially in view
of the impaired debt-carrying
(continued on page 2)

Opinions expressed in this newsletter do not
necessarily reflect the views of the management of the
Federal Reserve Bank of San Francisco, nor of the Board
of Governors of the Federal Reserve System.

capacity caused by previous loans
still outstanding; (2) the risks result­
ing from large concentrations of
liabilities to a few depositors with
similar response patterns and
motives, and (3) the portfolio
imbalances created by distorted
relationships between maturities
of assets and liabilities, with OPEC
depositors prefering short-term
liquid claims but borrowers requir­
ing longer-term financing.
Because some countries might
have difficulty in obtaining private
financing, it has seemed imperative
to expand various international
financing schemes developed in
the earlier stages of the oil crisis.
For example, the International
Monetary Fund expanded its
special oil facility by SDR 5 billion
(roughly $6 billion) and the Organi­
zation for Economic Cooperation
and Development agreed to es­
tablish (subject to legislative
ratification) a “ solidarity fund” or
“ safety net” in the initial amount
of SDR 20 billion, (about $25
billion).
OPEC surplus
These official arrangements will
help to forestall oil-induced
balance-of-payments crises in the
immediate future. But how
manageable will the deficits of oil­
importing countries be over the
longer term? Prospects of success
would be improved if the oil
exporters' cumulative investible
surplus at the end of the current
decade approximates the Treasury

Digitized for FRA SER


estimate of $195 billion (in 1974
prices) rather than the much higher
figures estimated earlier.
The size of these surpluses de­
pends (on the one hand) on the
amount of OPEC oil revenues,
investment income and other
earnings, and (on the other hand)
on the amount of OPEC goodsand-services imports plus
financial-aid transfers. Oil reve­
nues currently are being depressed
by the world-wide recession and
by consuming countries' conserva­
tion measures, but they should rise
again as economic activity
increases—provided the cartel
price can be maintained. As for
investment income, earnings on
OPEC's already large, and still
growing, accumulation of assets
should increase rapidly. On the
other hand, OPEC imports and
financial grants will retard asset
accumulation. OPEC imports in
particular were surprisingly large
last year—amounting to over onethird of their $60-billion surplus—
because of the initiation of major
development programs and the
outlay of large sums for military
hardware. However, there is
some question how long this rate of
imports can be sustained, because
time is needed to make full use of
such a massive inflow of resources.
Real economic costs
The success experienced thus far
in recycling OPEC oil funds has
drawn attention away from some
basic problems stemming from the
oil price increase. While recycling

has eased the adjustment, it has
forced the consuming nations to
pile debt upon debt, except for
relatively small amounts of grant
aid. Debt repayment at some
point will be due, including not
only the sums borrowed but huge
interest payments as well. These
payments will have to take the
form of real transfers embodying
the heavy costs imposed by the
higher import price of oil—costs
payable in the form of a larger
volume of exports of goods and
services. Unless sufficient aid is
forthcoming from the wealthier
countries, especially the major
oil exporters, repayment could
impose a very severe burden on
the poorest oil importers.
Prices and the cartel
A significant and early decline in
the price of oil would ease the
real transfer problem and help the
oil-importing countries manage
their current-account deficits.
Within the present decade, large
supplies of Alaskan and North Sea
oil should become available, and
new discoveries in Bolivia, China,
Malaysia, Mexico and elsewhere
may provide important additional
supplies. Oil exploration and the
development of other energy
sources should be stimulated by
the high price of oil.
Optimistic observers claim that we
are seeing the emergence of
conditions which typically lead to
the collapse of cartels. Downward
price pressures develop either
from increased supplies—whether

from outside sources or from the
breaking of cartel agreements—or
from a weakening of demand such
as we've experienced this year. In
either case, a cartel must progres­
sively reduce output to maintain
prices. Smaller producers are
tempted to increase output,
taking advantage of the price
umbrella maintained by the domi­
nant producer—which must then
cut back its own production again to
keep prices high. Historically, this
process sooner or later results in
the destruction of the cartel and
a drop in prices. In this view,
because price maintenance by the
cartel usually results in additional
sources of supply, prices may even
fall below the level obtaining
before the cartel was formed.
At times this year, OPEC has had
nearly a third of its capacity shut
down, and price-shaving by some
members of the cartel has been
reported even in the wake of the
recent price boost. Indeed, the
September meeting of OPEC
ministers apparently was as much
concerned with holding the cartel
together as with raising prices in
the face of the current worldwide
glut. Continuation of downward
pressures on cartel prices could
make the recycling problem
somewhat less frightening than it
appeared to be a year or two ago.
But this sanguine conclusion
should receive an early test, as
worldwide oil demand expands
in line with a worldwide business
recovery.
Ernest Olson

□1911128% for FRA SER


uojSinqsBM • qe ifl • uoSa-io • epeA3N • °MePI
M BM BH

•

E |U J O p |B 3

.

B U O Z IJ y

•

*I!|B3 'O D spuejj u b s
Z£L ON llW U H

aivd

aovisod s n
HVW SSV1D lS d lJ

BANKING DATA—TWELFTH FEDERAL RESERVE DISTRICT
(Dollar amounts in millions)
Selected Assets and Liabilities
Large Commercial Banks

Amount
Outstanding
9/24/75

Change
from
9/17/75

Loans (gross, adjusted) and investments*
Loans (gross, adjusted)—total
Security loans
Commercial and industrial
Real estate
Consumer instalment
U.S. Treasury securities
O ther securities
Deposits (less cash items)—total*
Demand deposits (adjusted)
U.S. Governm ent deposits
Time deposits—total*
States and political subdivisions
Savings deposits
O ther time deposits}:
Large negotiable CD's

85,559
64,162
1,016
22,727
19,565
10,039
8,811
12,586
86,077
23,779
315
60,618
5,805
20,776
30,153
16,397

Weekly Averages
of Daily Figures

W eek ended
9/24/75

Member Bank Reserve Position
Excess Reserves
Borrowings
Net free (+) / Net borrowed (-)
Federal Funds—Seven Large Banks
Interbank Federal fund transactions
Net purchases (+) / Net sales (-)
Transactions of U.S. security dealers
Net loans (+) / Net borrowings (-)

-

+
+
+
+

+
-

+
+
+
+
+

393
556
697
33
4
16
151
12
67
466
300
687
15
22
508
667

Change from
year ago
Dollar
Percent
+

+ 1,833
3,015
564
1,426
350
+
314
+ 4,836
+
12
+ 5,460
+ 1,560
587
+ 4,585
196
+ 3,033
+ 1,305
+
839

W eek ended
9/17/75

-

+
+

+
+
+
-

+
-

+
+
+

2.19
4.49
35.70
5.90
1.76
3.23
121.66
0.10
6.77
7.02
65.08
8.18
3.27
17.09
4.52
5.39

Comparable
year-ago period

+

37
19
18

+

981

+

1,678

+

520

+

668

+

964

+

945

-

20
119
99

-

58
204
262

in c lu d e s items not shown separately. ^Individuals, partnerships and corporations.

Information on this and other publications can be obtained by calling or writing the Public
Information Section, Federal Reserve Bank of San Francisco, P.O. Box 7702, San Francisco 94120.

Digitized for f R A SER <
4,5) 397' 1137'


E>|S E|V