View original document

The full text on this page is automatically extracted from the file linked above and may contain errors and inconsistencies.

September 6,1974

Citing the "meat-ax, undifferenti­
ated" impact of monetary policy
upon interest-sensitive sectors of
the economy, Congressman Henry
Reuss (D., Wise.) recently intro­
duced legislation that would make
the Federal Reserve System respon­
sible for the allocation effects of
policy. While conceding that the
current "intractable inflation" will
require considerable monetary
restraint, the Congressman also
argued that indiscriminate restraint
is "irresponsible." Consequently,
his bill would require the Fed to
allocate member-bank credit so that
less would be available for "non­
priority uses"— gambling casinos,
conglomerate mergers, non-essen­
tial real estate and "inflationinducing" inventory accumulation
— and more would be available for
"priority" loans and investments.
Priority areas could include, among
others, loans to finance capital
investments that increase produc­
tive capacity, control pollution or
conserve energy; loans to finance
low- and middle-income housing
and small businesses; and invest­
ments in the obligations of state and
local governments.
The bill calls for member-bank
credit to be allocated to "priority"
areas through the use of supple­
mental reserve requirements and
credit subsidies against various
bank-asset categories. Under the
legislation, the Federal Reserve
could require each member bank
to hold supplemental reserves
against "non-priority" loans and
investments, in addition to the
usual reserves against deposits, and
1




could allow a bank to credit a per­
centage of "priority" assets against
these supplemental reserves. Since
these reserves (like other reserve
requirements) are a form of tax, and
since the credits are the equivalent
of a tax reduction, their interaction
would alter the relative earnings on
various assets and thus provide
banks with an incentive to finance
priority activities.
Supporters of the Reuss proposal
argue that such a system involves
minimal interference with the
market system and would be rela­
tively easy to administer, and more­
over, that it has been employed
successfully by a number of foreign
central banks. This system could be
seen as a logical extension of the
selective-control devices used in­
creasingly by the Federal Reserve
in recent years— Regulation Q, of
course, as well as reserve require­
ments on a wide range of non­
deposit sources of funds, such as
Eurodollar borrowings by American
banks and the proceeds of commer­
cial paper sold by bank holding
companies.
Flaws in the proposal
Critics of the Reuss proposal con­
cede that, initially, more funds
probably would flow to the "prior­
ity" areas favored by the credits and
fewer funds to the "non-priority"
areas subject to the supplemental
reserves. But this might prove to
be only a short-term phenomenon.
For one thing, the proposal as pres­
ently constituted would apply only
to banks which are members of the
Federal Reserve System. Because
(continued on page 2)

Opinions expressed in this newsletter do not
necessarily reflect the views of the management of the
Federal Reserve Bank of San Francisco, nor of the Board
of Governors of the Federal Reserve System.

the supplementary reserves are a
form of tax, which increases costs,
banks could be tempted to with­
draw from membership to avoid the
"tax." To the extent that such an
attrition of membership occurred,
the effectiveness of supplementary
reserves as an allocating device
would be reduced.
The problem of leakages would be
aggravated by the exclusion of other
institutions which participate ac­
tively in the loanable-funds market
— nonmember banks, savings-andloan associations and insurance
companies, not to mention other
financial institutions and nonfinan­
cial corporations. Moreover, the
imposition of relatively high reserve
requirements on non-productive
loans and investments would offer
no guarantee of a reduction in the
flow of credit to such uses. In all
likelihood, those flows would
simply shift to other sectors of the
credit market, such as the commer­
cial-paper market, as business credit
demands repeatedly have done in
the past in response to only slight
differentials in borrowing costs. And
even if we could be sure that the
proceeds of a priority loan were
actually being used for the intended
purpose, we could not be certain
that that action would not free up
other resources for "non-priority"
uses.
To the extent that earnings (and
payouts) are adversely affected by
supplemental reserve requirements,

depositors and stockholders can
avoid the "tax" by placing their
funds elsewhere, and in an era of
increasing investor sophistication
and rapid technological innovation,
they are likely to do so with increas­
ing ease. (But small savers and
borrowers, who are limited in their
dealings to banks subject to reserve
requirements, would be penalized
by having, in effect, to subsidize
"priority" borrowers.) At the same
time, the credit aspect of the assetreserve proposal would discriminate
in reverse— against those depositors
and stockholders whose institutions
are not subject to any form of re­
serve requirement.
Plugging leakages
Supporters of the credit-allocation
proposal recognize these potential
leakages and note that to some
extent they would be "plugged"
by other proposed legislation, which
would give the Fed power over the
reserve requirements of nonmem­
ber banks. Some proponents,
cognizant of the $300 billion avail­
able in inter-firm trade debt and
internally generated funds, would
attempt to plug these leakages also
by extending credit allocation re­
quirements to the whole gamut of
financial and non-financial institu­
tions. Alternatively, they would
impose mandatory credit-allocation
measures upon the Fed similar to
those exercised over consumer, real
estate and other credit during the
Korean War.
In rebuttal, critics argue that past
efforts to plug leakages have not

2




been too successful— witness the
decade-long attempt (recently
abandoned) to reduce ba!ance-ofpayment deficits through controls
over foreign lending and invest­
ment. Plugging all potential leakages
of credit also would require the
exercise of Federal aegis over state
regulatory agencies.
Moreover, what specific criteria
should determine what sectors
qualify for "priority" treatment?
Consumers and farmers, for ex­
ample, might feel deserving of
treatment at least equal to that
afforded middle-income homebuyers, small businesses, or large
firms financing additions to capac­
ity. Also, we cannot tell what the
relative impact upon employment,
incomes, savings (and prices) would
be of channeling credit to homebuyers as compared with (say) large
industrial firms. Then there is the
question of conflicting objectives
among various "priority" areas.
Housing, for example, may rank
high as a social need, but it does not
rank high in terms of one of the
other criteria adduced in support of
priority treatment— namely, provid­
ing needed additions to the nation's
productive capacity.
Problems of equity
Credit-allocation schemes are de­
signed to rectify problems of in­
equity, which ultimately arise from
unequal market power. But critics
argue that this inequity can be
better rectified through fiscal policy,
whose costs and benefits are visible
and measurable, than through a
3




maze of portfolio regulations loaded
with indirect subsidies and taxes of
uncertain incidence, and riddled
with leakages. This approach not
only would reduce the leakage
problem, but would bring into
sharper focus the need for deter­
mining priorities and making the
necessary trade-offs between pos­
sibly incompatible objectives—
such as equity, economic growth,
price stability and environmental
balance. Also, priorities can change,
so that assigning responsibility for
their determination and implemen­
tation to the Fed means giving the
central bank enormous power to
substitute a wide range of assumed
public preferences for private
decisions.
Finally, critics of asset-reserve pro­
posals question whether foreign
experience effectively validates
their use, as has been claimed. Sev­
eral recent investigations of the
experience of Western European
countries conclude that such con­
trols cannot replace, and may even
undermine, efforts to control the
money supply. Also, despite the use
of such measures, prices have risen
even faster in Europe than in the
U.S. Given this country's relatively
low degree of banking concentra­
tion, the wide availability of its
nonbank lending opportunities, and
the relative openness of its money
and capital markets, it could be
argued that selective credit controls
are even less likely to succeed in
the U.S. than elsewhere.
Verle Johnston

m

o c=3

u o i S u i q s B M • qe jn • uoSaJO • epeASN . oqepi
M EM B|-| .
B jU J O p jE ^
.
E U O Z U y • £ > |S E |V

•^1|E3 '0»Sj3UBSj UBS
2SL ON IlWHSd
aivd

dovisod s n

1IVW SSV13 ISMIJ

BANKING DATA—TWELFTH FEDERAL RESERVE DISTRICT
(Dollar amounts in millions)

Selected Assets and Liabilities
Large Commercial Banks

Amount
Outstanding
8/21/74

Change
from
8/14/74

Change from
year ago
Dollar
Percent

Loans (gross) adjusted and investments*
Loans gross adjusted—
Securities loans
Commercial and industrial
Real estate
Consumer instalment
U.S. Treasury securities
Other Securities
Deposits (less cash items)— total*
Demand deposits adjusted
U.S. Government deposits
Time deposits— total*
Savings
Other time I.P.C.
State and political subdivisions
(Large negotiable CD's)

83,251
65,782
1,177
23,526
19,782
9,441
4,633
12,836
79,631
21,609
536
55,968
17,758
28,840
5,954
15,787

Weekly Averages
of Daily Figures

Week ended
8/21/74

Week ended
8/14/74

Comparable
year-ago period

-

114
413
299

-

31
226
195

11
126
-1 1 5

+

739

+ 1,277

0

+

528

+

-

+
+
+
—

—
—
—

+
+
+
+
+

585
94
19
52
42
3
336
155
146
777
226
429
7
292
18
428

+ 8,280
+ ;?,950
+
36
+ 3,033
+ :>,610
+ 723
—
499
+ 829
+ c>,936
+ 640
+
74
+ 3,846
+
13
+ r ,431
—
236
+ 3,762

11.04
13.75
3.16
14.80
15,20
8.29
9.72
6.90
9.54
3.05
16.02
11.66
0.07
23.20
3.81
31.28

+
+
+
+
+
+
_

+
+
+
+
+
+
+
—

+

Member Bank Reserve Position
Excess Reserves
Borrowings
Net free ( + ) / Net borrowed ( —)
Federal Funds— Seven Large Banks
Interbank Federal funds transactions
Net purchases ( + ) / Net sales ( - )
Transactions: U.S. securities dealers
Net loans ( + ) / Net borrowings ( - )

530

+ 142

in clu d e s items not shown separately.

Information on this and other publications can be obtained by calling or writing the
Administrative Services Department, Federal Reserve Bank of San Francisco, P.O. Box 7702,
San Francisco, California 94120. Phone (415) 397-1137.