View original document

The full text on this page is automatically extracted from the file linked above and may contain errors and inconsistencies.

VOL. 11, NO. 12 • OCTOBER 2016

DALLASFED

Economic
Letter
U.S. Productivity Growth
Flowing Downstream
by Michael Sposi and Kelvinder Virdi

}

ABSTRACT: Measurements
of U.S. productivity growth
have declined, particularly
in the high-tech sector. This
may reflect increased U.S.
specialization in upstream
activities in the global supply
chain. Those activities tend to
experience slower productivity
growth.

P

roductivity is the most important component of sustained,
long-run economic growth.
Sluggish productivity growth
has been a primary reason for the
weak U.S. recovery following the Great
Recession.
U.S. real (inflation-adjusted) gross
domestic product (GDP) growth had
averaged 4.2 percent per year in the four
years following recessions during the
postwar era. However, since the trough
of the 2007–09 Great Recession, output
has grown at less than half that rate.
GDP per worker has increased an
average of 0.4 percent per year since
2010, compared with 1.8 percent from
1947 to 2009.
Researchers and policymakers have
proposed two explanations for declining
productivity growth, particularly in hightech sectors.
The first is “secular stagnation,” in
which there is excess saving and insufficient demand for investment along
with fewer innovations that improve
productivity.
The second is the “mismeasurement
hypothesis,” which holds that the decline
in productivity growth is not as severe
as it seems because of a failure to accurately measure output.
But a third hypothesis may better
explain what has occurred: Production

in the U.S. has become increasingly
concentrated upstream in global supply chains, particularly in the high-tech
sector.
Upstream activities occur early in the
production process and include such
high-value, service-oriented activities
as research and development.1 Because
productivity growth is naturally slower
in upstream than downstream activities,
greater upstream activity contributes
to lower overall measured productivity
growth.

Measuring Productivity
Productivity is the rate at which
production inputs convert to outputs.
Production requires labor, physical capital (machines and buildings) and intermediate inputs (materials and business
services).
Labor and capital add value in the
process of converting intermediate
inputs into output. As such, value added
is defined as the compensation for
labor and capital. Intermediate inputs
are treated as non-value-added factors
of production in order to avoid double
counting of value added.2
To measure productivity, the values
of the inputs and outputs are each deflated by their corresponding price indexes
to isolate changes in quantities of inputs
and outputs. The focus is on total factor

Economic Letter
productivity (TFP) growth, defined as the
growth in the value added that is unaccounted for by expansion of effective
hours worked and the stock of capital.

Examining High Technology
TFP growth has declined in almost
all manufacturing industries in the U.S.
(Chart 1). Computer and electronic
products is one standout industry. The
industry’s TFP growth averaged an annu-

Chart

1

alized 2.14 percent in 2010–13, compared
with 16.51 percent during 1999–2009.3
For other manufacturing industries, TFP
growth slipped an average of 0.57 percentage points to 0.01 percent.
U.S. firms’ movements along supply
chains may partly explain discrepancies in changes in productivity growth
across industries. “Supply chain” refers
to the sequence of production, beginning
with design (upstream) and ending with

Total Factor Productivity Growth Mostly Declines in 2010–13

Plastics and rubber products
Chemical products
Petroleum and coal products
Paper and printing
Textiles and apparel
Food, beverage, and tobacco
Miscellaneous manufacturing
Furniture
Transportation equipment and parts
Elec. equip., app. and components
Computer and electronic products
Machinery
Metals
Nonmetallic mineral products
Wood
Nonmanufacturing

1999–2009 (avg.)
2010–13 (avg.)

-10

-5

0

5
Percent

10

15

20

SOURCES: Bureau of Economic Analysis; authors’ calculations.

Chart

2

Computer and Electronic Products Leads in Value Added

Plastics and rubber products
Chemical products
Petroleum and coal products
Paper and printing
Textiles and apparel
Food, beverage and tobacco
Miscellaneous manufacturing
Furniture
Transportation equipment and parts
Elec. equip., app. and components
Computer and electronic products
Machinery
Metals
Nonmetallic mineral products
Wood
Nonmanufacturing

1999–2009 (avg.)
2010–13 (avg.)

0

10

SOURCES: Bureau of Economic Analysis; authors’ calculations

2

20

30

40
50
Percent

60

70

80

assembly and sale (downstream). There
are many stages in between, and each
stage can be fragmented in various geographic locations.4
New technologies tend to be developed and produced upstream—innovations such as software, machines to
automate assembly, precision equipment
for manufacturing specialized devices,
and faster computers for communications networks. These technologies are
often applied to later stages of production, resulting in increased productivity
growth in downstream activities.
While upstream activities can realize higher productivity from new technologies, the rate that productivity
grows upstream is often slower because
upstream tasks are also burdened with
the responsibility of discovering and producing those new technologies.
Direct measurements of productivity
through supply-chain stages do not exist.
However, a common feature of advanced
economies is that productivity growth is
slower in services than in manufacturing.
During the postwar era in the U.S., the
difference averaged 1 percent per year.
Five economists, led by Marcel Timmer
of the University of Groningen, show
that advanced countries have become
increasingly specialized in tasks carried
out by highly skilled workers.5
Tasks and industries that use highly
skilled workers the most intensively are
service oriented—for example, scientific,
technical, computer systems and data
processing. These are also tasks commonly employed in upstream activities
within manufacturing, such as computers and electronics. Thus, it is natural
that measured productivity growth
declines as production becomes more
concentrated upstream.
Three key pieces of data indicate that
the U.S. computer and electronic products industry has become more concentrated upstream.
First, the share of value added in the
total output of computers and electronics increased from 50 percent before
2009 to 67 percent in 2010–13 (Chart 2).
This contrasts with a decreasing share
in every other manufacturing industry
except chemicals, which increased by a
small margin. When production moves
upstream, it becomes more value-

Economic Letter • Federal Reserve Bank of Dallas • October 2016

Economic Letter
added intensive. Downstream activities
tend to use intermediate inputs more
intensively.
Second, the share of computer and
electronic product sales destined for
intermediate use, as opposed to final use,
increased from 59 percent before 2009
to 72 percent in 2010–13 (Chart 3). This
increase is the largest among the manufacturing industries and is indicative of a
higher concentration of upstream activity
as firms become increasingly removed
from the final consumer.
Third, the share of imports in total
expenditures on computers and electronics increased from 44 percent before
2009 to 53 percent in 2010–13 (Table 1).
There are two possible reasons for
this increase. One is that the U.S. is
becoming less internationally competitive in the computer and electronic products industry. If that were true, we would
see a declining share of industry output
going to exports, but Table 1 shows the
opposite is true. The other possible reason is that the U.S. is importing more
downstream goods. Because the value of
downstream imports includes the value
of output from upstream activities, value
added is double counted. As a result, the
value of the imports is larger.

Chart

3

Share of Intermediate Sales Grows
for Computer and Electronic Products

Plastics and rubber products
Chemical products
Petroleum and coal products
Paper and printing
Textiles and apparel
Food, beverage and tobacco
Miscellaneous manufacturing
Furniture
Transportation equipment and parts
Elec. equip., app. and components
Computer and electronic products
Machinery
Metals
Nonmetallic mineral products
Wood
Nonmanufacturing

1999–2009 (avg.)
2010–13 (avg.)

0

20

40

60
Percent

80

100

120

SOURCES: Bureau of Economic Analysis; authors’ calculations.

Table

1

Average Relative Shares of Imports, Exports
Import share of expenditures*

Export share in output*

Sectors
1999–2009

2010–13

1999–2009

2010–13

Alternative Explanations

Plastics and rubber products

13.9

19.4

9.5

12.1

Of the two leading explanations for
declining U.S. measured productivity growth, the first is secular stagnation, coined in 1938 and repopularized
by Lawrence H. Summers of Harvard
University in the context of the sluggish
recovery following the Great Recession.6
According to this hypothesis, the
imbalance between the supply of savings
and demand for investment is growing. The increased supply of saving is
thought to be driven by, among other
things, aging populations in advanced
economies, while the decline in demand
for investment is thought to be driven by
insufficient investment opportunities. An
outcome of the imbalance is a declining
real rate of return on investment.
Proponents of the hypothesis point
to declines in real returns on government debt at various maturities.7 One
study argues that returns on government
(unproductive) capital are not natural
in this context and that one should look

Chemical products

23.0

25.4

17.9

20.6

Petroleum and coal products

15.7

13.9

7.4

14.0

Paper and printing

8.7

9.3

6.9

9.5

Textiles and apparel

57.9

69.9

12.9

16.6

Food, beverage and tobacco

7.4

8.9

5.6

7.3

Miscellaneous manufacturing

38.7

39.4

16.8

20.5

Furniture

24.9

32.9

3.6

5.7

Transportation equipment and parts

30.1

33.7

20.4

25.6

Elec. equip., app. and components

37.0

46.4

19.5

24.4

Computer and electronic products

43.6

53.0

27.8

29.4

Machinery

30.8

34.3

27.6

31.6

Metals

17.9

20.2

8.4

11.0

Nonmetallic mineral products

16.3

18.8

6.3

8.9

Wood

16.9

15.8

4.5

6.6

Nonmanufacturing

1.8

2.5

2.6

3.5

*Includes intermediate and final expenditures/output.
SOURCES: Bureau of Economic Analysis; authors’ calculations.

Economic Letter • Federal Reserve Bank of Dallas • October 2016

3

Economic Letter

instead at returns on private (productive)
capital. The study shows that returns on
productive capital have not declined and,
in fact, are comparatively high relative to
the past 30 years.8 Thus, it appears that a
main premise of the secular-stagnation
hypothesis isn’t supported by the data.
The second alternative explanation,
the mismeasurement hypothesis, is that
we simply are not fully measuring all of
the output produced. The idea is that
many new high-tech products are generating a “consumer surplus” that is not
showing up in GDP.9 Examples include
“free” search engines and smartphone
apps. The extent to which this consumer
surplus is not measured in output is
referred to as “missing GDP.”
Nonetheless, there is no reason, a priori, to assume that the values of the new
products are not showing up elsewhere
in GDP. That is, consumers are paying
for smartphones, computers and internet service, while the search engine and
application developers earn revenues
through various selling activities, including advertising space, which is used to
sell goods to consumers. All of this shows
up in aggregate GDP even if the consumer does not directly pay for each use of
the search engine or smartphone app.
While there is undoubtedly some
mismeasurement of output, the hypothesis needs to show the size of the mismeasurement and its downward bias to be
valid. More importantly, the hypothesis
must show that the mismeasurement
gets larger over time. A recent paper
shows that mismeasurement is unlikely
to account for the majority of the decline
in measured productivity growth.10

DALLASFED

Shifting Production Implications
The decline in measured productivity growth in high-tech industries may
reflect a shift toward upstream, serviceoriented activities that are subject to
slower productivity growth. High-tech
industries are unique in that their output
is often used to enhance productivity in
all sectors of the economy. A change in
productivity in the computer and electronic products industry can affect productivity in other industries as well as the
aggregate economy.
The fact that measured productivity
growth in the high-tech sector is decreasing does not suggest that the changes in
specialization along the global supply
chain are restricting growth. In fact, supply chains allow for greater specialization
at different stages of production and this
typically improves overall productivity.
The ever-changing nature of production will require the discovery of
technologies that improve efficiencies
in upstream activities. Investment will
have to emphasize human capital accumulation—knowledge, discovery and
innovation. This is a time-consuming
and uncertain process, but no machine
can replace the labor needed to produce
these efficiencies.

Double counting of value added occurs because
intermediate goods themselves are produced using labor,
capital and other intermediates.
3
TFP can also be viewed as the rate at which capital and
labor (value-added factors) are converted into output.
4
If the component is outsourced to an overseas firm, it
can also be called offshoring.
5
See “Slicing Up Global Value Chains,” by Marcel P.
Timmer, Abdul Azeez Erumban, Bart Los, Robert Stehrer
and Gaaitzen J. de Vries, Journal of Economic Perspectives, vol. 28, no. 2, 2014, pp. 99–118.
6
See “U.S. Economic Prospects: Secular Stagnation,
Hysteresis, and the Zero Lower Bound,” by Lawrence H.
Summers, Business Economics, vol. 49, no. 2, 2014,
pp. 65–73, and “Demand Side Secular Stagnation,” by
Summers, American Economic Review, vol. 105, no. 5,
2015, pp. 60–65.
7
Summers looks at five-year, five-year-forward rates for
Treasury inflation-protected securities.
8
See “The Return to Capital and the Business Cycle,” by
Paul Gomme, B. Ravikumar and Peter Rupert, Review of
Economic Dynamics, vol. 14, no. 2, 2011, pp. 262–78,
and “Secular Stagnation and the Returns on Capital,” by
Gomme, Ravikumar and Rupert, Federal Reserve Bank of
St. Louis Economic Synopses, no. 19, 2015.
9
“Consumer surplus” is the difference in value between
what a consumer pays for a good and the value the
consumer derives, or is willing to pay, for the good.
10
“Challenges to Mismeasurement Explanations for
the U.S. Productivity Slowdown,” by Chad Syverson,
National Bureau of Economic Research, NBER Working
Paper no. 21974, February 2016.
2

Sposi is a research economist and Virdi
is a research analyst in the Research
Department at the Federal Reserve Bank
of Dallas.

Notes
Upstream activities include such early-stage activities
as software development, while downstream activities are
those that are closer to the final end use of the product.
1

Economic Letter

is published by the Federal Reserve Bank of Dallas.
The views expressed are those of the authors and
should not be attributed to the Federal Reserve Bank
of Dallas or the Federal Reserve System.
Articles may be reprinted on the condition that
the source is credited and a copy is provided to the
Research Department of the Federal Reserve Bank
of Dallas.
Economic Letter is available on the Dallas Fed
website, www.dallasfed.org.

Mine Yücel, Senior Vice President and Director of Research
Jim Dolmas, Executive Editor
Michael Weiss, Editor
Kathy Thacker, Associate Editor
Dianne Tunnell, Associate Editor
Ellah Piña, Graphic Designer

Federal Reserve Bank of Dallas
2200 N. Pearl St., Dallas, TX 75201