View original document

The full text on this page is automatically extracted from the file linked above and may contain errors and inconsistencies.

VOL. 6, NO. 11
OCTOBER 2011­­

EconomicLetter
Insights from the

FEDERAL RESERVE BANK OF DALL AS

Did Speculation Drive Oil Prices?
Market Fundamentals Suggest Otherwise
by Michael D. Plante and Mine K. Yücel

The tripling of oil prices
from early 2007 to
mid-2008 is consistent
with several market
fundamentals,
including increased
demand from emerging
markets, low elasticities
of demand and reduced
OPEC excess capacity.

Oil market speculation became an especially popular topic when the
price of crude tripled over 18 months to a record high $145 per barrel
in July 2008. Of particular interest to many is whether speculators drove
oil prices beyond what fundamentals would have otherwise justified. We
explore this issue over two Economic Letters. In this article, we look at evidence from the physical market for oil and conclude that fundamentals,
and not speculation, were behind the dramatic rise and fall in oil prices. In
our companion Economic Letter, we examine the futures market.

O

il prices began their climb in 2002, reaching a record high in
mid-2008, and then collapsed at the end of ’08 amid the global
recession. As world economic growth picked up, so did oil prices. Overall,
the year-over-year change in oil prices has fairly closely tracked world
gross domestic product (GDP) growth (Chart 1).
Energy consumption increases as GDP rises; but energy consumption
in developing countries increases almost twice as fast as in developed
countries. GDP expansion in emerging economies was particularly strong
between 2005 and 2007, averaging 8 percent per year. Real GDP in China,
for example, grew by an average 12.7 percent annually between 2005 and
2007, while the nation’s oil consumption increased 5.1 percent annually
during the period.
From the beginning of 2007 to mid-2008, weekly prices for West Texas
Intermediate (WTI) crude oil jumped 152 percent, from $57 to $143 per
barrel. It’s possible that growing demand for crude oil might not be the
reason for the rise. However, if the increase was due to other factors, oil
consumption should have begun falling in response to the higher prices.
Instead, there was almost no consumption decline during the period,

implying that oil prices were driven by
growing world income and demand.
Insensitivity to Price Change
Consumers of oil and oil products are
not very sensitive to price changes,

especially in the short run. In economic jargon, the price elasticity of
demand is very low. This is mainly
because oil’s use for transportation
purposes accounts for two-thirds of
consumption, especially in developed

Chart 1

World GDP Mirrors Oil Price Growth
Percent

Percent

6

60
50

5

40

World GDP growth
4

30
20

3

10

Real oil price growth
2

0
–10

1

–20
0

–30

–1
2000

2001

2002

2003

2004

2005

2006

2007

2008

2009

2010

–40
2011

SOURCES: International Monetary Fund; Bureau of Labor Statistics; Wall Street Journal.

Chart 2

Reduced OPEC Excess Capacity Helped Tighten Market
Dollars per barrel

Million barrels per day

160

8

July 2008

7

140
120

6

WTI

100

5

80

4

60

3

40

2

20

OPEC excess capacity

0

1
0

2000

2002

2004

2006

2008

2010

NOTE: Oil prices are monthly averages.
SOURCES: U.S. Energy Information Administration; Wall Street Journal.

EconomicLetter 2

F EDERA L RE SERVE BANK OF DALL AS

countries, where there are no close
substitutes in the short term. When
consumers are insensitive to price
changes, a shock in the oil market,
whether from increased demand or
reduced supply, will heighten price
volatility.
To see whether rising oil prices
from 2007 through mid-2008 are
compatible with the elasticities for oil
estimated in the energy economics
literature, we performed a simple calculation. Taking the developed-world
and emerging market GDP growth
rates from the International Monetary
Fund, and making some assumptions
about income elasticities of demand,
we can calculate the higher oil demand
implied by these growth rates. Then,
by comparing actual growth in consumption and the calculated consumption numbers, we can determine the
oil price elasticities they imply. We
found that these elasticities would
have to range from 0.01 to 0.08 for
prices to surge as they did in 2007 and
2008—well within the estimated elasticity ranges in the energy economics
literature.1
OPEC Market Power Firmed Prices
The oil market is not perfectly
competitive. The Organization of
the Petroleum Exporting Countries
(OPEC), since its formation in 1970,
has been an oligopolistic producer,
trying to boost prices by controlling
members’ output (with more success
at times of higher demand growth).
The remaining non-OPEC producers
form a price-taking, competitive fringe.
OPEC’s market share has dwindled
from 52 percent in the early 1970s to
a still hefty 42 percent today. In the
1990s, as the market grew, so did
both OPEC and non-OPEC production. However, non-OPEC oil output
growth flattened around 2003, while
OPEC output continued expanding
from 37 percent in 2003 to the current
42 percent level. Increased market
power, coupled with rising demand,
was a significant factor keeping oil
prices high.

Low OPEC Excess Capacity
OPEC’s crude oil production
capacity has changed little since the
1970s, rising from 34 million barrels
per day in 1973 to 35.5 million barrels
per day in 2008. However, increased
world consumption greatly diminished
the cartel’s excess capacity. OPEC
has added capacity slowly, using its
restrained output to keep prices high.
It is easier to keep cartel members disciplined and conforming to
production quotas when capacity is
tight. Moreover, shocks in a tight oil
market can increase price volatility
because OPEC lacks the ability to offset these shocks, even if it desires to.
Chart 2 shows the inverse relationship
of oil prices and the cartel’s excess
capacity. In mid-2008, when oil prices
reached record highs, OPEC excess
capacity was down to 1 million barrels
per day.2
Inventories Did Not Increase
A speculator wanting to drive up
the current price of oil would have to
buy in the spot market. Since the price
is determined in a cash marketplace
where transactions are settled with
physical oil changing hands, speculative buyers would have to store their
purchases, and inventories would rise.
Instead, during the oil price run-up in
2007 and 2008, inventories in the U.S.
were being depleted. Chart 3 shows
WTI prices and U.S. oil inventories
and illustrates the workings of an efficient market—as supplies diminish,
prices rise and the market tightens.
Another possibility might be
speculators using floating storage,
keeping oil in tankers at sea and off
the market. Floating storage appears
to increase in 2008, rising from 68.4
million barrels at the end of March to
97 million barrels in May (Chart 4).
However, floating storage declined in
June and continued falling throughout
the summer.
We would have expected to see
floating storage rise significantly during the summer if speculators were
in the market; instead, the opposite

Chart 3

Oil Price Speculation? Inventories Didn’t Rise
Millions of barrels
1,150

Dollars per barrel
160

July 2008
U.S. inventories

140

1,100
120
100

1,050

80

WTI
1,000

60
40

950
20
0

900
2007

2008

2009

2010

2011

NOTE: Oil prices are monthly averages.
SOURCES: U.S. Energy Information Administration; Wall Street Journal.

Chart 4

Floating Storage Suggests Changing Demand
Millions of barrels
190

July 2008

170
150
130
110
90
70
50
30
2005

2006

2007

2008

2009

2010

2011

SOURCE: Bloomberg.

occurred. Floating storage did rise
much later in the year, but that was
concurrent with the global recession.
There is one additional type of
storage—producers maintaining the

F EDERAL RESERVE BANK OF DALL AS

oil as reserves and not producing.
However, if we look at OPEC output,
it clearly rose as oil prices went up,
until July 2008. OPEC increased production by 2.4 million barrels per day

3 EconomicLetter

Notes

Chart 5

1

WTI Prices Resemble Commodities Without Futures
Markets

An elasticity of 0.01 implies that for every 10

percent change in oil prices, consumption falls by
0.1 percent. Estimated short-run price elasticities
for oil range from 0.0 to –0.11. See “A Literature
Review of Demand Studies in World Oil Markets,”

Index, January 2008 = 100

by Frank J. Atkins and S.M. Tayyebi Jazayeri,

180

University of Calgary, Department of Economics

160

Discussion Paper 2004-07, April 2004.

Tallow

140
120

OPEC excess capacity has ranged from a high

WTI

2

Illinois Basin coal

of 9.8 million barrels per day in 1985 to a low of

Cobalt

700,000 barrels per day in 2004.
3

100

See “Did Speculation Drive Oil Prices? Futures

Market Points to Fundamentals,” by Michael D.

80

Plante and Mine K. Yücel, Federal Reserve Bank
of Dallas Economic Letter, vol. 6, no. 10, 2011.

60
40
20
0

2003

2004

2005

2006

2007

2008

2009

2010

2011

SOURCES: U.S. Energy Information Administration; Wall Street Journal; Bloomberg.

from the beginning of 2007 to July
2008. Non-OPEC production remained
relatively constant and did not rise,
though this is largely a function of
non-OPEC producers’ zero excess
capacity rather than an attempt to
restrict output.
Other Commodities Surged
Those believing speculation
pushed up prices point to the coincident increase in the number of
noncommercial traders in the futures
market—for example, speculators—
and the rise in oil prices.3 However,
Chart 5 shows that this may not necessarily be the case. It depicts the prices
of WTI, Illinois Basin coal, tallow and
cobalt. Of these commodities, there
is a futures market only for WTI. Yet,
prices for Illinois Basin coal, tallow
and cobalt increased as fast as oil,
if not faster, in 2008 and fell just as
quickly when the economy crumbled.
Such integrated movement in the prices of these commodities is consistent
with a pure demand story, rather than
a speculation one.

Fundamentals, Not Speculation
Activity in the futures market
increased appreciably in the past
decade, as did the number of noncommercial traders. This rise was coincident with the rise in oil prices, leading
some to hypothesize that speculation—
rather than market fundamentals—
drove the price of oil.
The tripling of oil prices from early 2007 to mid-2008 is consistent with
several market fundamentals, including increased demand from emerging
markets, low elasticities of demand
and reduced OPEC excess capacity.
The behavior of inventories was also
consistent with the reality of a tight
market, not with a story of speculation-driven hoarding, whether we look
at inventories above ground, below
ground or floating at sea. Hence, evidence from the physical market for oil,
similar to that from the futures market,
is consistent with oil-market fundamentals leading to increasing oil prices
before the global recession.
Plante is a research economist and Yücel is a
senior economist and vice president at the Federal
Reserve Bank of Dallas.

EconomicLetter

is published by the
Federal Reserve Bank of Dallas. The views expressed
are those of the authors and should not be attributed
to the Federal Reserve Bank of Dallas or the Federal
Reserve System.
Articles may be reprinted on the condition that
the source is credited and a copy is provided to the
Research Department of the Federal Reserve Bank of
Dallas.
Economic Letter is available free of charge by
writing the Public Affairs Department, Federal Reserve
Bank of Dallas, P.O. Box 655906, Dallas, TX 752655906; by fax at 214-922-5268; or by telephone at
214-922-5254. This publication is available on the
Dallas Fed website, www.dallasfed.org.

FEDERAL RESERVE BANK OF DALLAS
2200 N. PEARL ST.
DALLAS, TX 75201