View original document

The full text on this page is automatically extracted from the file linked above and may contain errors and inconsistencies.

VOL. 12, NO. 1 • JANUARY 2017

DALLASFED

Economic
Letter
Is the Next Recession Around
the Corner? Probably Not
by Anton Cheremukhin

}

ABSTRACT: A “profits
recession” often predicts
a real recession. A view
of recessions as gluts of
competition explains why this
time a real recession is not
imminent.

G

ross domestic product (GDP)
growth slowed considerably
during the first half of 2016.
Wages have increased faster
than inflation since 2014, cutting into
firms’ profit margins. Following dismal
earnings through mid-2016, some market participants spoke about a “profits
recession.”
These developments prompt a
natural question: When is the next real
recession coming? Economists remain
far from a consensus on what causes
recessions, but there is general belief in
a model in which recessions are caused
by large exogenous shocks that by their
nature are unpredictable.
There is, however, an alternative
paradigm that views recessions as coordination failures among firms trying to
time their contraction or exit from the
market. This interpretation of recessions
as gluts of competition allows analysis of
the economy’s current state and evaluation of how fragile the economy is.
The recent path of economic variables viewed through this depiction
of business cycles sheds new light on
the factors that may have been at play
recently and how they will shape the
next downturn. An interpretation of the
data implies that a recession is likely
within the next two to three years; a
downturn, however, is not imminent.

Business Activity Cyclicality
To understand when the next recession might be coming, it’s helpful to
understand why recessions occur and
determine their distinguishing features.
A recession is a phase of the business cycle characterized by a sharp
slowdown in the pace of expansion.1
The business cycle generally is not just
a sequence of downturns in economic
output, but also features strong co-movement among many economic variables.
Understanding this co-movement helps
understand their source.
Another perspective suggests that
asymmetries in cyclical fluctuations
are driven by inattention of firms to the
state of the economy, to the amount of
competition and to when the time is
right to shrink operations or leave the
market.2 Because of inattention, firms
overestimate their prospects and tend
to overexpand and overstay, heating up
competition among companies, driving
down markups and profits.
Overheating continues until either
competitive pressure increases to the
point where it becomes unbearable and
firms panic, or the “fragile” economy
is hit by an adverse shock. A recession
happens when this glut of competition
unravels, one way or another, and a large
number of firms decide simultaneously
to close or shrink their operations.

Economic Letter
In the aftermath of a recession, the
playing field is much less congested.
Surviving firms take advantage of
increased market power, which quickly
translates into higher markups. Later in the
expansion, as firms increase their capacity
and new firms with superior technologies
enter the market, markups start a gradual
slide toward the next recession. The switch
from the “recovery” stage of the business
cycle to the stage of “fragility” occurs in
the middle of an expansion when output
growth slows and markups start falling.
Looking at the U.S. history of co-movements between output and markups, one
can identify the transitions from recovery
to fragility (Chart 1).3 After each recession
(pink), there is a visually distinguishable
recovery period (green) characterized by
fast growth and elevated markups. Each
recovery period is followed by a fragility
period (white) where growth slows and
markups decline.4

Chart

1

The same statistical procedure that
identifies the switches historically suggests that the U.S. economy entered the
state of fragility recently—in third quarter 2014. Growth significantly slowed
that fall, and markups declined about 4
percent.

Business-Cycle Co-movement
The behavior of major economic
variables over the course of the business cycle provides insight into how the
process proceeds. Specifically, recession
dates as well as the dates when switches
to fragility occurred in the past can be
used to evaluate the average performance of output, the unemployment
rate, markups, profits, price inflation and
wage growth.
First, note the average responses of
these economic indicators to a recession
(Chart 2). In an average postwar recession, output declined sharply by about 3

Output Gap, Markups Tend to Narrow When Recovery Ends
Output gap

Percent
5
4
3
2
1
0
–1
2016:Q2
–2
–0.74
–3
–4
–5
–6
–7
1955 1960 1965 1970 1975 1980 1985 1990 1995 2000 2005 2010 2015
Detrended markup
Percent
5
4
3
2
1
0
–1
–2
2016:Q2
–3
–2.1
–4
–5
–6
–7
1955 1960 1965 1970 1975 1980 1985 1990 1995 2000 2005 2010 2015
NOTES: Pink-shaded areas indicate recession. Green-shaded areas indicate recovery. White areas indicate fragility.
Detrended markup indicates movement absent long-term trends.
SOURCES: Federal Reserve Board; National Bureau of Economic Research; author’s calculations.

2

percent below potential; unemployment
increased sharply from the average of 5.5
percent prior to the recession to around 8
percent; markups stayed 3 percent below
trend throughout the recession and then
quickly increased back to trend almost
two years following the beginning of a
recession.
Profits declined from 10 percent of
GDP in anticipation of a recession to 8
percent at its deepest point and then
increased back toward 10 percent of GDP
in the aftermath of a recession. Core
inflation and wage growth, which gradually rose prior to the recession, reversed
course and returned to normal during the
recession and recovery.
The average responses of the same
economic quantities to a switch from
recovery to fragility are similarly tracked
(Chart 3 on back page). In an average
postwar switch to fragility, output growth
slowed considerably, leading to a gradual
decline in the output gap toward potential; the unemployment rate flattened out
between 5 and 6 percent, while markups
started a gradual decline after remaining
elevated over the course of the recovery.
Profits, which remained a relatively
constant fraction of GDP over the course
of the recovery, declined 2 percentage
points as a share of GDP during the first
two years of fragility. Core inflation did
not appear to respond much to postwar
switches, and wage growth accelerated a
little bit following a typical switch.
The path of the U.S. economy around
the time of the most recent switch mimics closely the typical behavior from past
switches. Growth has slowed since 2014,
markups and profits have been declining,
the unemployment rate has slid to a very
low level by historical standards, inflation
has remained steady and wage growth has
accelerated a bit.

Predicting Recessions
When the economy is already fragile,
what are the telltale signs of a coming
recession?
Research suggests that the likelihood
of a recession remains largely unchanged
over the entire period of fragility, remaining at a higher level when compared with
the recovery period. Specifically, a recession results from one of two forces: 1) the
failure of ineffective businesses to coordi-

Economic Letter • Federal Reserve Bank of Dallas • January 2017

Economic Letter
Chart

2

Economic Variables During Recession Versus Recent Path
Output gap

Percent
3
2
1
0
–1
–2
–3
–4
–5
–10 –8 –6 –4 –2 0

Percent
9

Dodging the Bullet

Unemployment rate

8
7
6
5
2

Detrended markup
Percent
4
3
2
1
0
–1
–2
–3
–4
–10 –8 –6 –4 –2 0 2

4

6

4

–10 –8 –6 –4 –2 0

2

4

6

Profits share of gross domestic product
Percent yearly
14
13
12
11
10
9
8
7
4

6

–10 –8 –6 –4 –2 0

Core consumer price index inflation
Percent yearly
6

Percent yearly
7

5

6

2

4

6

2

4

6

Wage inflation

5

4

4

3

3

2
1

a potential recent shock would be large
enough to create a major imbalance.

2
–10 –8

–6

–4

–2

0

2

4

6

1
–10 –8 –6 –4 –2 0

NOTES Blue line shows paths during switches from fragility to recession with 95 percent confidence intervals. Red line
shows recent path. Vertical line indicates years before/after the switch.
SOURCES: Bureau of Economic Analysis; Bureau of Labor Statistics; National Bureau of Economic Research; author’s
calculations.

nate their timely exit, which is inherently
unpredictable; or 2) an external shock
that knocks the economy out of balance.
Policy action or favorable circumstances
could help the least-productive firms
stop their expansion and coordinate their
timely exit.
Availability of information about firms’
future prospects could be one such policy
device. However, the longer the economy
remains in a fragile state, the smaller the
size of the shock needed to create imbalances, so the likelihood of recession
increases, albeit very gradually, over time.
When the economy is already fragile,
the best indicator of how far away it is
from slipping into recession is the level of
markups and profits. The lower they are
and the longer they stay low, the more
likely a recession will occur. If the majority

of businesses are not paying attention to
these indicators, the firms will continue
expanding, further heating up competition. When the downturn hits, it will be as
unexpected as always.
In such circumstances, a relatively
large disturbance can lead to a wave of
exits and contractions by firms which,
through wide information transmission, spirals the economy into recession.
However, a relatively small shock can
lead to only a small number of the leastproductive firms exiting, allowing recessionary pressures to abate while lessening
competitive pressure. In this case, markups increase slightly, but the length of the
expansion is extended.
The key question about current experience is whether the circumstances are
right for a major contraction and whether

The recent path of profits and markups
suggests that a recession may be indeed
right around the corner, as some market
participants suggest. On the other hand,
would an examination of GDP, profits and
markups have predicted all previous recessions? Yes, these seem to be necessary
signs as reduction in markups and slow
growth did precede previous recessions.
On the other hand, they do not seem
to be a sufficient indicator. There were
two episodes—in 1986 and 1998—when
the same criterion indicated an imminent
recession. But a recession did not materialize, despite the stock market crash of
1987 and a pair of international shocks in
1998.5
The distinguishing feature of both
these episodes relative to prerecession periods was a low level of inflation.
Coincidentally, the current levels of price
inflation and wage growth are low by the
standards of a typical prerecession period.
Core personal consumption expenditures
inflation has barely exceeded 2 percent,
while usually it exceeds 4 percent when a
recession is imminent. Wage growth has
been in the 2–3 percent range, while it
usually also far exceeds 4 percent when a
recession is around the corner. Therefore,
it does not seem like all preconditions for
a recession have been met.
Moreover, drawing on the two aforementioned episodes, preemptive tightening in the 1980s and 1990s could be the
kind of small shock that enabled a longer
expansion by signaling to the least competitive firms that it is time to leave and let
other, more productive, firms grow.
The most recent energy plunge, coupled with the strengthening of the dollar,
could be the small shock that temporarily defuses the competitive pressure and
prolongs the current expansion. The most
recent earnings data seem to point in that
direction. Nevertheless, the U.S. economy
is in a fragile state and a large enough
shock could throw the economy into a
downturn
Cheremukhin is a senior research economist in the Research Department of the
Federal Reserve Bank of Dallas.

Economic Letter • Federal Reserve Bank of Dallas • January 2017

3

Economic Letter

Chart

3

Output gap
Percent
5
4
3
2
1
0
–1
–2
–3
–8 –6 –4 –2 0
2

Percent
9

Unemployment rate

7
6
5
4

6

8

4

–8 –6 –4 –2 0

2

4

6

8

Profits share of gross domestic product
Percent yearly
14
13
11
10
9
8

Core consumer price index inflation
Percent yearly
6

8

–8 –6 –4 –2

Percent yearly
7

0

2

4

6

8

4

6

8

Wage inflation

6

5

5

4

4

3

3

2

To identify a switch from recovery to fragility, abrupt
changes in the growth rate of the output gap and markup
series were identified. After some experimentation,
a simple ad hoc rule was employed. It computes the
difference in the change over the preceding five-quarter
period versus the following five-quarter period. The most
likely switches were identified by taking the biggest break
in the growth rate in output gap and markups over each
expansion. When the two dates did not coincide, the later
date was chosen.
5
The Asian financial crisis was followed by the Russian
financial crisis and led to the collapse and bailout of the
Long-Term Capital Management hedge fund.
4

12

6

For the U.S., a slowdown in the pace of expansion
implies a contraction, but for countries with higher average
growth rates, this is not necessarily the case.
2
“Information Rigidities and Asymmetric Business
Cycles,” by Anton Cheremukhin and Antonella Tutino,
Journal of Economic Dynamics and Control, vol. 73,
December 2016, pp. 142–58.
3
The output gap is the difference between the actual level
of GDP and the potential level, which measures how much
the economy can produce when operating at full capacity.
The measure of potential output used here is described in
“Estimating the Output Gap in Real Time,” by Anton Cheremukhin, Federal Reserve Bank of Dallas, Staff Paper, no.
22, December 2013. The markup series is detrended by
subtracting an extremely smooth long-term trend obtained
by using a Hodrick-Prescott filter.
1

8

Detrended markup
Percent
4
3
2
1
0
–1
–2
–3
–4
–5
–8 –6 –4 –2 0 2 4

1

Notes

Economic Variables During a Switch
to Fragility Versus Recent Path

2
–8 –6 –4 –2

0

2

4

6

8

1
–8 –6 –4 –2

0

2

NOTES Blue line shows paths during switches from recovery to fragility with 95 percent confidence intervals. Red line
shows recent path. Vertical line indicates years before/after the switch.
SOURCES: Bureau of Economic Analysis; Bureau of Labor Statistics; National Bureau of Economic Research; author’s
calculations.

DALLASFED

Economic Letter

is published by the Federal Reserve Bank of Dallas.
The views expressed are those of the authors and
should not be attributed to the Federal Reserve Bank
of Dallas or the Federal Reserve System.
Articles may be reprinted on the condition that
the source is credited and a copy is provided to the
Research Department of the Federal Reserve Bank
of Dallas.
Economic Letter is available on the Dallas Fed
website, www.dallasfed.org.

Mine Yücel, Senior Vice President and Director of Research
Jim Dolmas, Executive Editor
Michael Weiss, Editor
Dianne Tunnell, Associate Editor
Ellah Piña, Graphic Designer

Federal Reserve Bank of Dallas
2200 N. Pearl St., Dallas, TX 75201