View original document

The full text on this page is automatically extracted from the file linked above and may contain errors and inconsistencies.

Vol. 3, No. 1
JANUARY 2008­­

EconomicLetter
Insights from the

Federal Reserve Bank of Dall as

Inequality and Growth:
Challenges to the Old Orthodoxy
by Erwan Quintin and Jason L. Saving

Inequality can have

Discussions of how best to alleviate poverty often center on the relative merits

disruptive effects on

of policies that boost growth and those that promote redistribution. If greater inequal-

resource allocation in

ity allows economies to expand faster, or if it’s an inevitable consequence of progrowth

economies where

measures, the two principles seem incompatible. Under such a scenario, societies seeking

markets function

rapid growth rates have to forgo redistribution from rich to poor. Conversely, choosing a

poorly. Inequality,

high degree of redistribution implies the decision to accept lower growth rates.

therefore, is more likely

If, on the other hand, inequality impedes growth, these principles aren’t only

to be harmful in

compatible but may, in fact, reinforce one another. François Bourguignon, the former

countries with

World Bank chief economist, wrote: “If one interprets literally the potentially negative

weak institutions.

relationship between inequality and growth, then redistribution [from rich to poor]
would enhance growth. It would then be sufficient to have at one’s disposal policy instru-

ments to guarantee that growth is
pro-poor—i.e. that it reduces inequality—for a virtuous circle to start and
lead progressively to faster growth,
declining inequality, and accelerated
poverty reduction.”1
The question of whether inequality impedes or fosters economic
growth once seemed largely settled,
with traditional economic theory
focusing on inequality’s beneficial
effects on saving, investment and
incentives. In the past two decades,
however, research has identified new
channels between inequality and
growth, suggesting a more subtle relationship than the one advanced by
earlier theorists.
The new work doesn’t refute
many of the important insights of classical economics, but it points out that
inequality can have disruptive effects
on resource allocation in economies
where markets function poorly. Inequality, therefore, is more likely to
be harmful in countries with weak
institutions for the exchange of goods,
services and money. This confirms
the idea that improved market institutions are a key condition for economic
success.
Trade-offs between inequality and
growth aren’t merely theoretical matters. They’re crucially important not
only for policymakers who shape their
countries’ safety nets but also for monetary authorities seeking to understand
potential growth rates and make more
informed policy decisions.

with wealth. If the rich save at a high
rate, a view closely associated with
prominent economist Nicholas Kaldor,
unequal societies can actually build up
their productive infrastructure faster
than equal ones, achieving higher
growth rates.
Inequality could also foster
growth because new industries typically require large initial investments.
If credit markets function poorly, a
society’s savings may not be efficiently
transferred to investments. In this
environment, a high concentration
of wealth may allow some investors
to overcome these impediments and
stimulate growth by bringing capitalintensive industries into being.
In the early work, income or
wealth redistribution policies are
overwhelmingly viewed as detrimental to growth based on at least
two arguments. First, redistribution
via such instruments as progressive
taxation distorts incentives to save,
which reduces resource accumulation.
Second, some variation in economic
rewards helps provide incentives to
invest and work.

Classical Views
Until recently, a broad set of ideas
led much of the economic profession
to opine that inequality was, if anything, favorable to—or at least a necessary by-product of—economic growth.2
In classical models, economic
growth depends chiefly on the rate at
which nations accumulate productive
resources, a factor that traces to aggregate savings rates. In this context,
distributional considerations matter
for growth only if households’ propensity to save varies systematically

EconomicLetter 

The classical view long dominated economic thought and emphasized that policies designed to reduce
inequality would entail adverse consequences for economic growth.
Recent Challenges
Over the past two decades, these
conventional notions have been challenged both on empirical and theoretical grounds. In cross-country comparisons, for example, researchers have
generally found a negative relationship between income inequality and
subsequent economic growth. These
empirical findings, taken at face value,
suggest that more equality could, in
fact, foster growth.3
We illustrate the empirical argument by plotting income inequality in
1960 against average growth rates over
the next four decades for all countries
with available data. The results suggest, albeit weakly, that nations with
more initial income inequality have
tended to fare worse in the long run
than countries with greater equality
(Chart 1). In this example, inequality
alone accounts for a fairly small frac-

Chart 1

Income Inequality and Economic Growth by Nation
Average real GDP per capita growth, 1960–2000 (percent)
7

Taiwan

6

China

5
Mexico

4
3
2

United
States

1

Canada

Peru
0
–1
Argentina

–2
0

10

20

30
40
50
Income Gini coefficient, 1960

60

70

80

NOTES: The income Gini is an index that rises with income inequality. Some countries identified for illustration purposes.
SOURCES: World Bank; Penn World Table Version 6.2, by Alan Heston, Robert Summers and Bettina Aten, Center for
International Comparisons of Production, Income and Prices, University of Pennsylvania, September 2006.

Fe deral Reserve Bank of Dall as

tion of the variance in growth across
countries.
Even so, a growing body of
empirical work finds that inequality
remains significantly correlated with
future growth even after controlling
for other important factors, such as
nations’ initial level of development.
Furthermore, the correlation between
inequality and growth seems particularly strong among certain subgroups
of nations—for example, those in
which private credit is scarce.
Several caveats are in order. First,
the empirical exercises don’t imply
that causation runs from inequality
to growth. Second, most studies rely
on measures of inequality of income
rather than wealth. Because the theoretical work focuses on the distribution of productive resources, wealth
inequality would be preferable, but
little data exist on it. Finally, changing
estimation techniques and time periods yields different results.4
Although cross-country studies
have produced mixed results, they
do suggest that inequality may not
be conducive to growth. The statistical associations, however, reveal
little about why. A historical example
can shed some light on the mechanism through which inequality might
impede economic growth.
If we look at the Western
Hemisphere, we see that the United
States and Canada have emerged as its
strongest economies (Chart 2), with
per capita GDP five to six times the
South American average.5
It was not always this way. In the
century before the U.S. was founded,
Caribbean islands such as Barbados
and Cuba produced 50 to 70 percent
more output per person than did
colonial America. Large swaths of
South America, including Brazil, were
also ahead of the U.S. and Canada.
Contemporary observers routinely predicted that fortune could be found in
these nations, rather than the U.S. or
Canada, a belief borne out by migration patterns that show most Atlantic
crossers headed to the Caribbean and

South America.
What gave the United States and
Canada their eventual edge over other
apparently better-positioned nations?
To answer this question, it’s important to look at past structural differences between Western Hemisphere
economies.
Caribbean and certain South
American nations relied primarily on
such high-value agricultural crops as
sugar, which entail substantial economies of scale in production. These
societies developed with large numbers of laborers working for relatively
few landowners. The results were a
vastly unequal distribution of income
and little prospect that citizens could
escape their station through upward
mobility.
Much of Canada and the U.S.,
on the other hand, offered land in
abundance but lacked the physical
conditions conducive to large-scale
farming in the colonial era. This led
to societies in which newcomers with
few assets could compete on relatively
level playing fields with longer-term

In the Western Hemisphere,
the United States and
Canada have emerged as
its strongest economies,
with per capita GDP five
to six times the South
American average. It
was not always this way.

Chart 2

North and South: Economic Divergence
in the Western Hemisphere
GDP per capita (international dollars)
30,000
United States
25,000

Canada
Argentina
Mexico

20,000

Brazil

15,000

10,000

5,000

0
1870

1885

1900

1915

1930

1945

1960

1975

1990

2005

NOTES: Units expressed as 1990 International Geary-Khamis dollars.
SOURCE: The World Economy: Historical Statistics, by Angus Maddison, Organization for Economic Cooperation and
Development, Development Centre Studies, 2003.

Fe deral Reserve Bank of Dall as

 EconomicLetter

residents. The results were a relatively
equal distribution of income and a
relatively large amount of movement
between income classes.
These fundamental economic
realities led the rest of the hemisphere
to develop institutions that were very
different from the U.S. and Canada.
When income and power are in the
hands of a few, institutions tend
to reinforce that concentration and
perpetuate a high degree of income
inequality. It was difficult for poor
workers in many Caribbean and South
American nations to acquire land, start
corporations, secure patents or do any
of the other things that generally go
along with entrepreneurial success.
A more equal distribution of
income and power makes it more difficult to create institutions that concentrate influence in the hands of a few.
In the U.S and Canada, economically
disadvantaged groups had a greater
say in policy and more incentive
to use their influence because they
could hope to become prosperous
themselves.
Comparing suffrage across countries provides some support for these
notions. It’s well known that the U.S.
initially restricted voting to white
males of privilege, which led to participation rates that would be regarded
as pitiful by today’s standards. In the
1850s, for example, 13 percent of
American citizens voted in presidential
elections, and participation rose to a
still-low 18 percent in 1900. Yet, voting rates at the dawn of the 20th century were far lower in other Western
Hemisphere nations—1.8 percent in
Argentina, 2.4 percent in Brazil, 4.4
percent in Chile.
While the U.S. and Canada
moved far more slowly toward universal suffrage than many would have
liked, their polities were far more participatory than those of their Western
Hemisphere counterparts. And empirical evidence supports the notion that
expanded suffrage tends to produce
governments whose programs are
more likely to be directed toward the

interests of the broad populace, not a
small elite.6
The provision of public education
in the Americas provides at least some
evidence of a correlation between
inequality and suffrage. If highly
skewed income distributions produce
highly skewed institutions that reinforce the status quo, we would expect
relatively equal societies to provide
universal schooling to their children,
and relatively unequal societies to be
less likely to do so.
This is indeed what we’ve seen in
the Western Hemisphere over the past
two centuries. The U.S. and Canada
achieved literacy rates in excess of
80 percent by the 1870s, even if we
include newly freed U.S. slaves (Chart
3). Institutions—usually state and
local governments—understood and
embraced the notion that education
would help bring prosperity to the
citizenry.
Other nations in the hemisphere
with more unequal distributions of
income and power were far below the
U.S. and Canada in literacy in 1870.
With the exception of tiny Barbados,
no other Western Hemisphere nation

EconomicLetter 

had achieved 80 percent literacy rates
half a century later. At least some have
argued that this dearth of educational
opportunity is due to suboptimal institutions’ focus on protecting the few
rather than enriching the many.7
New Theories
These empirical arguments have
prompted the development of new
theories that provide explanations for
why inequality might hinder economic
growth. A lot of this work focuses on
situations in which market mechanisms falter, whereas the classical
theorists often assumed properly functioning markets.
The new work points out, for
instance, that dispersion in factor
endowments implies different rates
of return when resource owners are
unable to trade with one another — at
least under the standard assumption
that returns to factors are diminishing.
In other words, high-return uses of
resources coexist with much lowerreturn ones. Redirecting resources
toward the more productive enterprises should bolster growth and make
income more equal.8 However, market

Chart 3

Literacy Rates Circa 1870
Percent
90
80
70
60
50
40
30
20
10
0
Argentina

Brazil

Chile

Cuba

Jamaica

Canada

United States

SOURCE: “Inequality, Institutions, and Differential Paths of Growth Among New World Economies,” by Stanley L. Engerman,
Stephen Haver and Kenneth L. Sokoloff, in Institutions, Contracts, and Organizations, ed. Claude Menard, 2000.

Fe deral Reserve Bank of Dall as

impediments short-circuit this process,
leading to more inequality and slower
growth.
Another strand of recent work
starts with the assumption that borrowers exert more effort when their
stakes in projects are higher. Under
that premise, it’s possible to envision
an environment where a more even
distribution of resources gives more
participants a significant interest, leading to a higher average level of effort
and greater output.9 We get similar
results under the simple assumption that insufficient collateral leads
some borrowers to forgo high-return
projects.10
Another branch of inquiry focuses
on political-economy questions and
finds that greater inequality increases
public support for redistribution,
which leads to higher tax rates on
capital accumulation and slower
growth of the overall economy.11
These models show links
between equality and growth, but they
don’t generally account for movements
up and down the income distribution
ladder. In some countries, it’s difficult
for people to leave the economic strata into which they were born. Other
nations exhibit a great deal of upward
mobility, often because of better education systems and well-functioning
markets.
A fair amount of empirical work
suggests that market-oriented economies such as the U.S. facilitate income
mobility.12 When citizens believe greater wealth may be in their future, they
may vote as if they were “richer” than
they actually are — a phenomenon that
suggests a relatively equal distribution
of opportunity may be a more important determinant of growth than a relatively equal distribution of income.13
These theoretical constructs
provide a possible explanation for
the observed negative relationship
between inequality and growth and,
in some cases, a potential rationale for
redistribution. But it should be noted
that these theories emphasize imperfections—be they barriers to trade or

financial market access—that may be
difficult to overcome through standard
income-redistribution programs.
Moreover, the classical notion
that redistribution distorts incentives
to save and work can’t be dismissed,
creating trade-offs between redistribution’s potential economic gains and its
adverse consequences. Models typically find a hill-shaped relationship,
where redistribution adds to growth
for a while but eventually reaches a
point where it becomes a drag on the
economy.14
Institutional Links
One of the distinguishing features
of developing nations is the inefficiency
of their basic economic institutions,
such as property rights enforcement
and the ability of ordinary people to
undertake market transactions. Among
many negative consequences, these
imperfections limit access to financial
markets throughout the developing
world. Less credit stifles growth, leading

to lower per capita incomes (Chart 4).
Understanding the links between
inequality and institutional development requires that we explain how
better institutions help markets operate
more effectively and devise a method
for distributing the burden of institution building across taxpayers.15 Setting
aside political constraints, this framework predicts that economies with
more inequality should be more willing to develop institutions conducive
to trade among their citizens because
greater inequality means potentially
higher returns from exchange between
the relatively rich and relatively poor.
This prediction seems puzzling
in light of the historical evidence for
the Western Hemisphere. In that case,
nations with the most unequal distributions of wealth and income developed the least market-friendly institutions, while nations with more equal
distributions developed the strongest
institutions.
This outcome becomes more

Chart 4

Economic and Financial Development by Nation
Ratio (private capital/GDP)
2.4

Canada

United States

1.2
Luxembourg

.64
Kenya
.32
.16
.08

Cambodia

.04

Albania

.02
0

250

500

1,000

2,000
4,000
8,000
GDP per capita (international dollars)

16,000

32,000

64,000

NOTES: Units expressed as standard purchasing power parity dollars. Data graphed on a log scale. Some countries identified
for illustration purposes.
SOURCES: “A New Database on Financial Development and Structure,” by Thorsen Beck, Asli Demirgüç-Kunt and Ross
Levine, World Bank Economic Review 14, 2000, pp.597–605; Penn World Table Version 6.2, by Alan Heston, Robert Summers and Bettina Aten, Center for International Comparisons of Production, Income and Prices, University of Pennsylvania,
September 2006.

Fe deral Reserve Bank of Dall as

 EconomicLetter

The new theories
are strongly consistent
with the hypothesis that
persistent inequality
generally hinders
institutional
development and
thereby slows growth.

reasonable once we take a broader
perspective. The link from the distribution of investment returns to growth
and institution building depends in
sometimes counterintuitive ways on
the distribution of resources across
individuals.
In Latin America, for instance, the
concentration of productive resources
has historically been high not only
with respect to physical capital and
land but also education and other
forms of human capital. To the extent
that physical and human resources are
complementary in production, inequality may in fact be associated with very
little dispersion in marginal products.
Institutions conducive to trading
physical resources may not have much
effect on growth rates unless resourcepoor individuals acquire more human
capital. Redistribution schemes that
target physical resources may be ineffective for similar reasons.
This suggests that educational
investments via, for instance, public
education can play an important role
in successful institutional development. And as our case study illustrates, Latin America has historically
lagged far behind the U.S. and Canada
in educational achievement.
If anything, the new theories are
strongly consistent with the hypothesis
that persistent inequality generally
hinders institutional development and
thereby slows growth, even before
taking into account strategic political
considerations. Just as important, they
suggest that inequality should have limited impact on growth when effective
institutions are in place.
The empirical literature has, indeed, found that the impact of inequality on growth is stronger in
nations where markets function poorly.16 We can illustrate this by taking
a second look at the relationship between income inequality in 1960 and
growth over the next four decades.
This time, we divide the sample into
three groups based on the effectiveness of their market institutions, reflected by each country’s score on the

EconomicLetter 

Fe deral Reserve Bank of Dall as

Fraser Institute’s rankings for regulation of credit, labor and business.17
These scores include factors such as
price controls, mandatory hiring costs
and the availability of capital to the
private sector.
Among the third of countries with
the weakest market institutions, we
see a negative relationship between
inequality and growth, echoing our
earlier results (Chart 5A). When we
isolate the third of countries with the
strongest institutions, however, inequality has a barely discernible impact on
economic growth (Chart 5B).
We don’t have data on whether
countries did have effective market
institutions in the past, which helps
explain why our findings in these
charts are fairly weak. Despite the
data constraints, differences are present, suggesting that the quality of market-related institutions matters to the
relationship between inequality and
growth.
Obstacles to Development
While recent work has enhanced
our understanding of the interplay
between inequality and growth, much
remains to be done before we can
confidently describe the policy mix
that will give nations the best chance
to grow and reduce poverty.
To date, little effort has been
made to carefully quantify the importance of the channels emphasized by
the new theories on inequality. Once
devised, these models should enable
us to better weigh the consequences
of redistribution.
On a more basic level, a wide gap
remains between the variables these
theories highlight and the available
data. Most obviously, data on wealth
inequality remain scarce, even for
industrialized nations, let alone developing nations. We also need a deeper
understanding of the link between
available measures of inequality and
the dispersion of returns to competing
uses of resources.
Finally, we have chosen to concentrate on the impact of inequality

on growth, but it’s clear that growth,
in turn, affects inequality. A large
literature studies this direction of
causality. The famous Kuznets hypothesis — that growth initially increases
inequality but eventually reduces
it—has been challenged by the recent
increase in earnings inequality in
much of the industrialized world.
Satisfactory theories of the relationship between growth and inequality
will have to account for these recent
patterns.
Even at this early stage, however, strong themes are emerging
from studies of inequality. One seems
particularly important: To the extent
inequality is detrimental to growth, the
impact rises with the severity of market imperfections. This suggests that
dealing with these deficiencies—for
example, by better protecting property rights and removing obstacles to
financial development—is a key step
toward economic development and
poverty reduction.

Chart 5

Inequality and Growth by Nation
A. Countries in Bottom Third of Fraser Ranking for Regulation of Credit, Labor
and Business

Average real GDP growth, 1960–2000 (percent)

7

4
3
2

Ecuador

1
Rwanda

0

Argentina

–1
–2
10

20

30

40
Income Gini coefficient, 1960

50

60

70

B. Countries in Top Third of Fraser Ranking for Regulation of Credit, Labor
and Business

Average real GDP growth, 1960 – 2000 (percent)

7
6
Hong Kong

Notes

5

See “The Poverty-Growth-Inequality Triangle,”
4

by François Bourguignon, unpublished paper,

Luxembourg

World Bank, March 2004.
2

China

5

Quintin is a senior economist and policy advisor
and Saving a senior economist in the Research
Department of the Federal Reserve Bank of Dallas.

1

Taiwan

6

3

This article draws heavily from various survey

papers, particularly “Inequality and Economic

United
States
Canada

2

Chile

Growth: The Perspective from New Growth
Theories,” by Philippe Aghion, Eve Caroli and

1

Cecilia García-Peñalos, Journal of Economic

0

Literature, vol. 37, December 1999, pp. 1615 –

10

60, and “Inequality and Growth,” by Roland

30

40
Income Gini coefficient, 1960

50

60

70

NOTES: The income Gini is an index that rises with income inequality. Some countries identified for illustration
purposes.

Benabou, NBER Macroeconomics Annual, 1996.
3

20

See, for example, “Political Equilibrium, Income

SOURCES: The Fraser Institute; World Bank; Penn World Table Version 6.2, by Alan Heston, Robert Summers and
Bettina Aten, Center for International Comparisons of Production, Income and Prices, University of Pennsylvania,
September 2006.

Distribution, and Growth,” by Roberto Perotti,
Review of Economic Studies, vol. 60, October
1993, pp. 755 – 76; “Redistributive Policies and

This is interpreted as evidence that the negative

Economic Growth,” by Alberto Alesina and Dani

4

Rodrick, Quarterly Journal of Economics, vol.

than cross-sectional evidence leads to very

relationship between inequality and growth holds

109, May 1994, pp. 465 – 90; and “Is Inequality

different conclusions. See “A Reassessment

in the long run but may not hold over shorter

Harmful for Growth?” by Thorsten Persson and

of the Relationship Between Inequality and

horizons.

Guido Tabellini, American Economic Review, vol.

Growth,” by Kristin Forbes, American Economic

5

84, June 1994, pp. 600 – 21.

Review, vol. 90, September 2000, pp. 869 – 87.

Lessons: Institutions, Factor Endowments, and

For instance, using panel evidence rather

Fe deral Reserve Bank of Dall as

This section draws heavily from “History

 EconomicLetter

EconomicLetter
Paths of Development in the New World,” by

12

Kenneth Sokoloff and Stanley Engerman, Journal

the United States, see Myths of Rich and Poor,

of Economic Perspectives, vol. 14, Summer

by W. Michael Cox and Richard Alm, New York:

2000, pp. 217–32.

Basic Books, 1999.

6

See “The Effect of the Expansion of the Voting

13

For further information on income mobility in

See “Preferences for Redistribution in the

Franchise on the Size of Government,” by

Land of Opportunities,” by Alberto Alesina and

Thomas Husted and Lawrence Kenny, Journal of

Eliana La Ferrera, Journal of Public Economics,

Political Economy, vol. 105, February 1997, pp.

vol. 89, June 2005, pp. 897–931, and “Social

54–82.

Mobility and the Demand for Redistribution,” by

7

For more on this subject, see “Why Isn’t the

Roland Benabou and Efe Ok, Quarterly Journal of

Whole World Developed?” by Richard Easterlin,

Economics, vol. 116, May 2001, pp. 447–87.

Journal of Economic History, vol. 41, March

14

See Benabou (note 2).

1981, pp. 1–19.

15

For such a framework, see “Inequality and

8

This argument is formalized in Aghion, Caroli

and García-Peñalos and Benabou (note 2).
9

See “A Theory of Trickle-Down Growth and

Growth: The Institutional Link,” by Thorsen
Koeppl, Cyril Monnet and Erwan Quintin, Federal
Reserve Bank of Dallas, unpublished paper,

Development,” by Philippe Aghion and Patrick

2007.

Bolton, Review of Economic Studies, vol. 64,

16

See Benabou (note 2) for a detailed discussion.

April 1997, pp. 151–72.

17

Data are from Economic Freedom of the

10

See, for instance, “Imperfect Capital Markets

World: 2007 Annual Report, by James D.

and the Persistence of Initial Wealth Inequalities,”

Gwartney and Robert A. Lawson, Fraser Institute,

by Thomas Piketty, London School of Economics

2007, www.fraserinstitute.org/Commerce.Web/

Working Paper no. TE/92/255, 1992.

product_files/EFW2007BOOK2.pdf.

11

is published monthly
by the Federal Reserve Bank of Dallas. The views
expressed are those of the authors and should not be
attributed to the Federal Reserve Bank of Dallas or the
Federal Reserve System.
Articles may be reprinted on the condition that
the source is credited and a copy is provided to the
Research Department of the Federal Reserve Bank of
Dallas.
Economic Letter is available free of charge
by writing the Public Affairs Department, Federal
Reserve Bank of Dallas, P.O. Box 655906, Dallas, TX
75265-5906; by fax at 214-922-5268; or by telephone
at 214-922-5254. This publication is available on the
Dallas Fed web site, www.dallasfed.org.

See Alesina and Rodrick and Persson and

Tabellini (note 3).

Richard W. Fisher
President and Chief Executive Officer
Helen E. Holcomb
First Vice President and Chief Operating Officer

The Economy in Action
Come to the Dallas Fed web site for data, analysis and resources on the
Texas, Mexico and border economies. We’ve made it easy for you to
access state and metro business-cycle indexes, employment
statistics, manufacturing data, energy updates and more.
Simply go to www.dallasfed.org and
click on Economic Research,
The Economy in Action.
Bookmark it!

Harvey Rosenblum
Executive Vice President and Director of Research
W. Michael Cox
Senior Vice President and Chief Economist
Robert D. Hankins
Senior Vice President, Banking Supervision
Executive Editor
W. Michael Cox
Editor
Richard Alm
Associate Editor
Kathy Thacker
Graphic Designer
Ellah Piña

Federal Reserve Bank of Dallas
2200 N. Pearl St.
Dallas, TX 75201