View original document

The full text on this page is automatically extracted from the file linked above and may contain errors and inconsistencies.

Vol. 7, No. 1
January 2012

EconomicLetter
Insights from the

Federal Reserve Bank of Dall as

Increased Real House Price Volatility
Signals Break from Great Moderation
by Adrienne Mack and Enrique Martínez-García

The shift toward more
volatile real house price
growth, unaccompanied
by a shift in the volatility
of real GDP growth, offers
evidence that house price
dynamics and real output
growth may have diverged
beginning around the
2001 recession.

U

.S. house price increases consistently outpaced the rate of inflation
beginning in the mid-1990s before peaking in 2005. Residential construction
accelerated in many advanced economies—not just the U.S.—with housing
accounting for a larger share of real gross domestic product (GDP) as prices
rose. Many investors, homeowners and even some policymakers seemed to
assume that house prices would never fall.
By 2007, emerging strains in housing markets and financial turmoil
plunged the world economy into a deep and protracted recession from
which recovery is ongoing. In the aftermath of that recession, the growth
of real (inflation-adjusted) house prices appears to have moved out of step
with the growth of real economic activity—indicating a possible break with
the recent past.
Our findings indicate that the 2007 global downturn wasn’t strikingly
different from other post-1984 recessions, based on real GDP. After 1984—a
period known as the Great Moderation because of diminished macroeconomic volatility—stretches of heightened volatility in real GDP growth became
shorter, roughly corresponding with U.S. recessions. Volatility increased with
the 2007 downturn, as had happened in other post-1984 recessions.
The findings paint a different picture for real house prices. Volatility in
house price growth decreased at the onset of the Great Moderation in the
U.S. A similar decline in volatility extended more broadly to include most
developed countries in the Organization for Economic Cooperation and
Development (OECD), starting in the mid-1990s. However, volatility in house
price growth substantially reemerged following the 2001 recession, signaling
a departure from the norm under the Great Moderation.1

Data on House Prices and GDP Growth
The findings are derived from the
Federal Reserve Bank of Dallas’ new
database of international house prices,
assembled from available national sources for 19 OECD countries on a quarterly
basis from first quarter 1975 to fourth
quarter 2010.2 The house price index
selected for each country was chosen to
be comparable to the Federal Housing
Finance Agency quarterly U.S. house
price index for existing single-family
houses (formerly the Office of Federal
Housing Enterprise Oversight index).3
Each nominal index is expressed in real
terms (adjusted for inflation), using the
applicable country’s personal consumption expenditure (PCE) deflator.
The developed-country index of
real house prices aggregates the 19
country indexes, each weighted relative to that nation’s 2005 GDP. Similarly,
a weighted, average real GDP is calculated for the group. U.S. figures are
separately investigated.4 House price
and GDP growth rates for the aggregated 19 OECD countries and the U.S.
are computed on a quarter-over-quarter,
annualized basis (Chart 1). U.S. recessions, as designated by the National
Bureau of Economic Research (NBER),
are identified and appear to indicate that
OECD-19 and U.S. downturns tend to
be highly correlated.
Chart 1 offers some support for
an OECD (2005) claim that real house
prices became “strikingly out of step
with the business cycle” beginning in
the 1990s. Real house price growth
in the OECD-19 bottomed out following the 1991 recession and began
increasing in the second half of the
1990s.5 The house price growth rate
kept climbing until around 2005,
even though real GDP growth didn’t
similarly increase and even weakened
around the 2001 recession. This apparent divergence is somewhat less evident for the U.S., but it can be argued
that house price growth in the U.S.
also resumed in the 1990s and outperformed real GDP growth in the first
half of the 2000s.
Even so, these observations alone

Modeling the Data
We model real house price
growth as alternating between two
regimes, each characterized by different dynamics. Specifically, we allow
the expected rate of real house price
growth and its volatility to differ across

cannot validate the view that real
house price and real GDP growth have
become more dissimilar over time.
Modeling the dynamics of these series
may provide more robust empirical support and clues as to what accounts for
the apparent break.

EconomicLetter 2

Chart 1

Real House Price Growth and Real GDP Appear
to Diverge Beginning in 1990s
A. OECD-19
Percent
20
15

OECD 19:
Real GDP growth

10
5
0

OECD 19:
Real house
price growth

–5
–10
–15

’75

’77

’79

’81

’83

’85

’87

’89

’91

’93

’95

’97

’99

’01

’03

’05

’07

’09

’01

’03

’05

’07

’09

B. United States
Percent
20
U.S.: Real GDP
growth

15
10
5
0

U.S.: Real
house price
growth

–5
–10
–15

’75

’77

’79

’81

’83

’85

’87

’89

’91

’93

’95

’97

’99

NOTES: Shaded areas represent official National Bureau of Economic Research recessions for the U.S. Individual country
sources and the aggregation method are detailed in the Federal Reserve Bank of Dallas international house price database.
All series plotted are growth rates computed on a quarter-over-quarter, annualized basis.
SOURCES: Haver Analytics; OECD Economic Outlook 89 database; individual country sources; authors’ calculations.

F edera l R eserve Bank o f Dall as

the two regimes. Applying this model
to the data—for both the OECD-19
and U.S.—we obtain estimates of
expected growth and volatility in
each regime, as well as the probability of switching from one regime to
the other.

Given those probabilities, we
can infer for any given quarter in our
sample how likely it is that real house
price growth in the OECD-19 and U.S.
is best characterized by one regime or
the other, based on the data observed
to that point.6 We model real GDP

Chart 2

Modeling Shows High Real House Price Volatility
After 2001 Recession
A. OECD-19
Probability
1.0

.8

OECD 19:
High real house
price growth
volatility

.6

OECD 19:
High real GDP
growth volatility

.4

.2

0

’75

’77

’79

’81

’83

’85

’87

’89

’91

’93

’95

’97

’99

’01

’03

’05

’07

’09

’99

’01

’03

’05

’07

’09

B. United States
Probability

1.0
U.S.: High real
house price
growth volatility

.8

.6
U.S.: High real
GDP growth volatility
.4

.2

0

’75

’77

’79

’81

’83

’85

’87

’89

’91

’93

’95

’97

NOTES: Shaded areas represent official National Bureau of Economic Research recessions for the U.S. Individual country
sources and the aggregation method are detailed in the Federal Reserve Bank of Dallas international house price database.
SOURCES: Haver Analytics; OECD Economic Outlook 89 database; individual country sources; authors’ calculations.

F ederal R eserve Bank o f Dall as

growth for the OECD-19 and U.S. in
an analogous way.
Our estimates show that for both
real house price and real GDP growth—
in the OECD-19 and U.S.—low expected growth goes hand in hand with
high volatility. As it turns out, though,
differences across regimes in expected
growth are small compared with differences in the volatility of growth. Thus,
in what follows, we focus on the differences in volatility and, for simplicity,
refer to our regimes as “high volatility”
and “low volatility.”
The probabilities that real house
price growth and real GDP growth
are in their high-volatility regimes
are shown in Chart 2. The series are
derived independently so that the
probabilities of high volatility in real
house price growth are not affected
by the strength of real economic activity or by the occurrence of the highvolatility regime for real GDP growth.
How do we interpret these probabilities? For example, consider the
real house price series for the U.S.
From 1993 to 2003, the probability
of being in the high-volatility regime
is below 0.2 and is often quite a bit
lower. Based on this, real house price
growth was almost certainly in its lowvolatility regime over that period. In
contrast, throughout the most recent
recession, real house price growth was
almost certainly in its high-volatility
regime, with implied probabilities uniformly close to 1.
With this illustration in mind to
help us interpret the empirical evidence
presented in Chart 2, we see that U.S.
real house price growth has been in the
low-volatility regime considerably more
often than OECD-19 growth has been.
For U.S. house price growth, volatility fell around the mid-1980s—roughly
coinciding with the onset of the Great
Moderation—and remained low almost
continuously through the early 2000s,
interrupted only by the 1990–91 recession. For OECD-19 house price growth,
the transition from high to low volatility
occurred later, around the mid-1990s.
However, both the U.S. and OECD-19

3 EconomicLetter

EconomicLetter
appear to have returned to high-volatility regimes after the 2001 recession, with
estimated volatility around six times
greater than in the low-volatility regimes.
Real GDP growth was rather volatile in the OECD-19 and U.S. during
the 1970s and early 1980s—a period
when real house price growth was also
very volatile. Since around 1984, occurrences of the high-volatility regime have
become rare in both the OECD-19 and
U.S.—this is characteristic of the Great
Moderation. Moreover, occurrences of
the high-volatility regime for real output growth have become closely associated with NBER-designated recessions
in the U.S.
OECD-19 and U.S. probabilities
and recessions are highly synchronized,
especially after 1984. Thus, the corresponding probabilities of high volatility appear to be a coarse indicator of
recession.
However, we fail to detect a sustained shift toward high volatility in real
GDP growth preceding the 2007 global
downturn similar to the one in the early
2000s for real house price growth. In
fact, by this metric, the latest recession is
indistinguishable from the two preceding ones, in 1990 and 2001. The shift
toward more volatile real house price
growth, unaccompanied by a shift in
the volatility of real GDP growth, offers
evidence that house price dynamics and
real output growth may have diverged
beginning around the 2001 recession.
Beyond the Empirical Facts
A shift in the volatility of real house
price growth appears to have occurred
over the last decade without a similar
change in real GDP growth. Our empirical findings don’t provide an economic
rationale for the high- and low-volatility
periods documented in the data, but
they suggest a break in the low-volatility
era that began after 1984 with the Great
Moderation. Therefore, something other
than the normal business cycle seems
to have altered the growth dynamics of
real house prices toward the high-volatility regime. That possibility is a promising avenue for additional research.

Mack is a research analyst and Martínez-García is
a senior research economist at the Federal Reserve
Bank of Dallas.
Notes
1

Interestingly, expected real house price growth

has remained only slightly below the 3 percent
expected real GDP expansion rate estimated for
the U.S. and the OECD since the mid-1970s.
2

For more on the database, see www.dallasfed.

is published by the
Federal Reserve Bank of Dallas. The views expressed
are those of the authors and should not be attributed
to the Federal Reserve Bank of Dallas or the Federal
Reserve System.
Articles may be reprinted on the condition that
the source is credited and a copy is provided to the
Research Department of the Federal Reserve Bank of
Dallas.
Economic Letter is available free of charge by
writing the Public Affairs Department, Federal Reserve
Bank of Dallas, P.O. Box 655906, Dallas, TX 752655906; by fax at 214-922-5268; or by telephone at
214-922-5254. This publication is available on the
Dallas Fed website, www.dallasfed.org.

org/institute/houseprice/index.cfm. The OECD19 are Australia, Belgium, Canada, Denmark,
Finland, France, Germany, Ireland, Italy, Japan, the
Netherlands, New Zealand, Norway, South Korea,
Spain, Sweden, Switzerland, the U.K. and the U.S.
A similar OECD database is used to investigate
housing markets across the OECD-19. See “A
Bird’s Eye View of OECD Housing Markets,” by
Christophe André, Organization for Economic
Cooperation and Development Working Paper no.
746, January 2010.
3

Each country’s house price index is extended to

1975 with historical sources whenever necessary,
seasonally adjusted over the entire sample period
and then re-based to 2005 = 100. For more
details on country data sources and data treatment, see the appendix and methodological
companion to the house price database available at
www.dallasfed.org/institute/wpapers/2011/0099.
pdf.
4

House price indexes for all 19 OECD countries

are deflated using the PCE deflator and aggregated
using constant, purchasing power parity-adjusted
GDP weights for 2005. Real GDP in 2005 purchasing power parities is averaged across all 19
countries using the same constant weights as for
real house prices.
5

“Recent House Price Developments: The Role

of Fundamentals,” Organization for Economic
Cooperation and Development Economic Outlook,
no. 78, December 2005.
6

Economists and statisticians refer to this

framework as a Markov-switching model. We
incorporate up to six lags for each variable we
estimate to account for other features of the data

Richard W. Fisher
President and Chief Executive Officer
Helen E. Holcomb
First Vice President and Chief Operating Officer
Harvey Rosenblum
Executive Vice President and Director of Research
Robert D. Hankins
Executive Vice President, Banking Supervision
Director of Research Publications
Mine Yücel
Executive Editor
Jim Dolmas
Editor
Michael Weiss
Associate Editor
Kathy Thacker
Graphic Designer
Samantha Coplen

that cannot be fully captured by this simple tworegime Markov-switching model specification. For
further details on the estimation, see the technical
appendix under “Related Reading” at www.
dallasfed.org/institute/houseprice/index.cfm.

Federal Reserve Bank of Dallas
2200 N. Pearl St.
Dallas, TX 75201