View original document

The full text on this page is automatically extracted from the file linked above and may contain errors and inconsistencies.

VOL. 1, NO. 9
SEPTEMBER 2006

EconomicLetter
Insights from the

FEDERAL RESERVE BANK OF DALLAS

Globalization’s Effect on
Interest Rates and the Yield Curve
by Tao Wu

In most industrialized

From June 2004 to July 2006, the Federal Open Market

nations, central bankers

Committee raised the target federal funds rate in 17 consecutive meetings,

have direct control over

taking it from 1 percent to 5.25 percent. The puzzling feature of this round

short-term interest

of monetary tightening is that long-term interest rates didn’t increase as

rates and use

much as they did in previous tightening cycles. In fact, long-term rates

them as their main

declined most of 2004 and 2005, despite the steady increases in short-term

policy instrument.

rates. In 2005, former Federal Reserve Chairman Alan Greenspan characterized this divergence in the path of short- and long-term rates as a
“conundrum.”
Recent declines in long-term rates aren’t a phenomenon peculiar
to the United States. Over the past few years, long-term rates around the

long-term rates curb aggregate consumption and investment, ultimately
helping contain inflation. Cutting
short-term rates, on the other hand,
usually leads to lower long-term rates,
providing a stimulus for economic
activity. Any lasting changes in the
links between short- and long-term
rates will thus have important implications for the timing and impact of
monetary policy actions.

world have exhibited similar declining
patterns, reaching lows unseen in the
past 25 years (Chart 1). Economists
have offered a variety of explanations
for this, but the trend has spread
across so many countries that a good
number of analysts now suspect globalization may be playing a key role in
decoupling short- and long-term interest rates. Recent decades have seen
globalization proceed at a rapid pace,
tying nations’ economies closer
together through the freer movement
across borders of goods, services,
money and ideas. This has brought
important changes in the forces that
determine interest rates.
Monetary policy’s effects on the
economy stem largely from how longterm interest rates respond to central
banks’ actions. In most industrialized
nations, central bankers have direct
control over short-term interest rates
and use them as their main policy
instrument. When central banks raise
short-term rates, it usually leads to
increases in market-determined longterm rates, including those for mortgages and commercial loans. Higher

Chart 2

Interest Rates Behave
Differently in Two Eras
A. 2004–06 Tightening
Percent
9
8
7

Long Rates’ Recent Behavior
The conventional relationship
between short- and long-term interest
rates appears to have broken down in
the most recent round of monetary
tightening. Although the target federal
funds rate has been gradually rising
over the past two years, the 10-year
Treasury yield remains about where it
was in mid-2004 (Chart 2A). Indeed,
during the first year and a half of the
monetary tightening—June 2004 to
December 2005—the 10-year Treasury
yield fell by about a quarter percentage point despite a 3.25 point increase
in the target fed funds rate.
This pattern contrasts sharply with

6
5

10-year Treasury yields

4
3

Fed funds target rate

2
1
0
June
’04

Oct.
’04

Feb.
’05

June
’05

Oct.
’05

Feb.
’06

June
’06

B. 1994–95 Tightening
Percent
9
8

10-year Treasury yields

7
6
5
4

Fed funds target rate

3

Chart 1

2

Long-Term Rates Fall Worldwide

1
0
July
’93

Percent

Nov.
’93

Mar.
’94

July
’94

Nov.
’94

Mar.
’95

SOURCE: Haver Analytics.

16
U.K.
U.S.
France
Germany

14
12
10
8
6
4
2
0
’82

’84

’86

’88

’90

’92

’94

’96

’98

’00

’02

’04

’06

NOTE: Data are monthly.
SOURCE: Haver Analytics.

EconomicLetter 2

FEDERAL RESERVE BANK OF DALLAS

past experience. For instance, during
the last round of monetary tightening
a decade ago, the 10-year Treasury
yield rose by about 1.5 percentage
points, while the target fed funds rate
rose 3 percentage points from January
1994 to February 1995 (Chart 2B). A
simple correlation analysis suggests
that over the two decades up to mid2004, a 1 percentage point increase in
the target fed funds rate was accompanied by, on average, a 0.3 percentage point increase in the 10-year

Treasury yield. If such a relationship
had persisted, the 4.25 percentage
point increase in the target fed funds
rate over the past two years would
have led to a 1.3 percentage point rise
in the 10-year Treasury yield. In other
words, the 10-year Treasury yield
would have risen to more than 6 percent, instead of hovering around 5
percent.
With short-term rates steadily rising from a very low starting level and
long-term rates steady, the yield curve
no longer exhibits its normal upward
slope; instead, it has become almost
flat or even inverted (Chart 3). In the
past, a flattening yield curve had been
a good indicator of recessions. The
yield curve inverted eight times during
the past half century, and the U.S.
economy ended up in recession seven
times.1
Lacking a clear understanding of
the new relationship between shortand long-term rates, many investors
rely on history and interpret today’s
inverted yield curve as a harbinger of
economic slowdown or recession.
This time, however, the overall economy looks strong, making the recent
behavior of long-term interest rates a
puzzle worth solving.
Explaining the Low Bond Yields
Several studies analyzing the
bond rate conundrum have shown
that the recent declines in long-term
yields are unlikely to be a sign of an
impending recession. Instead, they’re
more likely a reflection of several fundamental changes in the macroeconomy and financial markets—most
notably, increasing globalization.2
In principle, bond yields are the
product of two main components—
one related to real returns and the
other to inflation (see box). The first
component is the real interest rate,
which compensates lenders for forgoing consumption now in return for the
promise of future consumption. This
promise inherently has two parts—risk
and return—that stem from different
sources, making it useful to split them

Determining Bond Yields: A Primer
The following equation sums up the factors that determine the interest rate on bonds:

R = r + λr + π e + λπ ,
where R is the long-term bond yield, r is the expected real interest rate, λr is the real
e
rate risk premium, π is expected inflation, and λπ is the inflation risk premium. Each
of these factors stems from a potentially different source, and thus each should be
explained to clearly delineate the reasons interest rates can be high or low.

r : The real interest rate
Sometimes called the riskless real
rate, this part of R compensates
lenders for postponing consumption
to the future, under full certainty that
the terms of the loan will be honored.

Real
component

+
λr : The real rate risk premium
This part of R compensates lenders
for the risk that the loan will not be
repaid or will suffer capital loss in the
event of early redemption.

R : Long-term
bond yield

+

+
e

π : Expected inflation
This part of R compensates lenders
for the expected loss of money’s purchasing power owing to the anticipated rise in the price of goods and
services.

Inflation
component

+
λπ : Inflation risk premium
This part of R compensates lenders
for the risk that inflation will be higher
than expected, in which case the
principal and interest returned will
have less purchasing power than
anticipated.

The decline in bond yields (R) over the past 21⁄2 decades has come from reductions in
e
all four factors. Expected inflation (π ) has fallen from about 10 percent in the early
1980s to roughly 2.5 percent today, and the inflation risk premium (λπ ) is down from
about 3 percent in the early 1980s to less than 1 percent today. The real interest rate
component (r + λr) is also lower, likely due to a fall in both the expected real rate (r)
and the real rate risk premium (λr). Improved monetary policy, a more stable real
economy, the development of deeper and more integrated global financial markets,
and a global savings glut have brought lower long-bond yields virtually worldwide.
Globalization has contributed to each of these factors.

FEDERAL RESERVE BANK OF DALLAS

3 EconomicLetter

Chart 3

Yield Curves Have
Flattened
Percent
6

June 2004
June 2006

5

December 2005
June 2005

4

3

2

1

0
0

2

4

6

8 10 12 14
Years to maturity

16

18

20

SOURCES: FAME Database; Federal Reserve Board.

Chart 4

Interest Rates on InflationIndexed Securities Lower
Percent
5
4.5
4
3.5

10-year TIPS rate

3
2.5
2
1.5
1
.5
0
’99

’00

’01

’02

’03

’04

’05

SOURCES: FAME Database; Federal Reserve Board.

’06

apart conceptually and observe, if
possible, the behavior of each.
First, the expected real rate
(sometimes called the riskless real
rate) is the interest required to
reward lending under full certainty
that the loan agreement will be honored. It equilibrates the market
demand for and supply of loanable
real funds. Because the borrower
may default or either party may need
to exit the contract prematurely
(leading to possible capital loss),
however, lenders also require a risk
premium. It reflects the degree of
uncertainty, stemming primarily from
volatility in the underlying real economy (business cycle swings).
The second component is inflation related and derives from the fact
that contracts are made in terms of
money, not goods and services. As a
result, investors must be compensated for the inflation they expect and
the risk that inflation won’t be what
they anticipated.
High inflation can severely erode
the purchasing power of nominal
interest payments on bonds and the
principal repayment upon maturity.
For this reason, bond yields tend to
be lower when inflation is tame.
Similarly, when inflation volatility is
low, investors will be more confident
about receiving the real value of
their expected nominal returns and
will require lower premiums for
bearing the risk of future inflation.
Financial markets aggregate
these four forces. Changes in any
one of them will push interest rates
up or down. When inflation uncertainty or expectations recede, for
example, borrowing costs fall, reflecting increased confidence in price stability. When the economy becomes
more stable or the supply of loanable
funds expands relative to demand,
real borrowing costs decline as well.
Over the past two decades, both the
real and inflation components have
contributed to holding down longterm interest rates in many parts of
the world.

EconomicLetter 4

FEDERAL RESERVE BANK OF DALLAS

Globalization and Real
Interest Rates
Despite a recent run-up, interest
rates on 10-year Treasury InflationProtected Securities (TIPS) are about 2
percentage points below their early
2000 levels (Chart 4). The decline is
likely related to the decreased volatility in real economic activity, as reflected in the deviations from trend
growth rates of GDP and its three
major components—goods, services
and structures (Chart 5). Since the
mid-1980s, fluctuations in real GDP
growth have declined roughly 35 percent from levels seen during the 1950s
to 1970s.3 Spending on goods, services
and structures is far less volatile than
it once was. Additionally, there has
been a long-run shift of America’s
economic base from highly cyclical,
goods-producing industries to more
stable services. This “great moderation”—to borrow a phrase Fed
Chairman Ben Bernanke used in
2005—has helped investors become
more confident about future economic
stability, justifying lower risk premiums.
The substantial decline in macroeconomic volatility is largely, but not
entirely, rooted in domestic factors.
Globalization may have also played a
role. When economies are more interdependent, booms and busts may
become muted as excess demands in
one part of the globe are filled by
excess supplies in other parts, and
vice versa. The economy’s equilibrating mechanism can dampen local
shocks better when connected to a
large market of diversified sectors with
integrated flows of goods, services,
financial capital and people than
when the shock must be borne entirely locally. By helping stabilize the
business cycle and enhance investors’
confidence about future economic stability, globalization reduces the real
component of long-term rates and
thus cuts risk premiums.
At the same time, the available
pool of world savings has increased
significantly—what Bernanke has
called the “global saving glut.” It has

in recent years. U.S. inflation has been
trending downward over the past two
decades, as measured by the Consumer
Price Index and Core Personal
Consumption Expenditures Price Index
(Core PCEPI). Similar declines show up
in measures of one-year-ahead and
long-run inflation expectations (Chart
7).4 Both actual and expected inflation
have gradually fallen from around 10
percent in the early 1980s to about 2 to
2.5 percent today.
The trend toward lower inflation
has been a worldwide phenomenon,
with prices in most other industrialized countries behaving much as they
have in the U.S. Among the seven
largest industrial nations, average
annual inflation has fallen from 10
percent in 1973–83 to less than 2 percent in the past decade (Chart 8). The
sustained and widespread decline in
inflation has put significant downward
pressure on long-term bond yields in
both advanced and emerging-market
economies.
Inflation volatility and the inflation risk premium on long-term

Chart 5

Real GDP Components Show Less Volatility
Percent

Real GDP

10

0

–10
’47

’53

’59

’65

’71

’77

Percent

’83

’89

’95

’01

’06

’83

’89

’95

’01

’06

’83

’89

’95

’01

’06

Goods

10

0

–10
’47

’53

’59

’65

’71

Percent

’77

Services

10

0

–10
’47

’53

’59

’65

Percent

’71

’77

Chart 6

Structures

20

Saving Rates in
Emerging-Market
Economies Rise

10
0
–10

Savings as a percentage of GDP

–20
’47

’53

’59

’65

’71

’77

’83

’89

’95

’01

’06

Percent

NOTE: Volatility is measured by deviations from trend rates of growth.
SOURCE: Bureau of Economic Analysis.

45
China
40
35

brought additional loanable funds to
increasingly open markets, helping
hold down real interest rates worldwide. Several factors have contributed
to the savings increase: the revenues
surge of oil and commodity exporters,
the rapid income growth of high-saving East Asian households, increases
in the foreign exchange reserves held
by East Asian central banks and Latin
American countries’ reduced fiscal

Russia

deficits (Chart 6). With the development of deeper and more integrated
global financial markets, the savings
flows from these developing countries
were freely directed to the U.S. and
other advanced nations, helping keep
long-term real interest rates there low.

30
Saudi Arabia

25
India
20

Brazil
15
Argentina

10
5
0

Globalization and Inflation
Bond yields’ inflation-related
components have also moved lower

FEDERAL RESERVE BANK OF DALLAS

’95 ’96 ’97 ’98 ’99 ’00 ’01 ’02 ’03 ’04
SOURCE: World Development Indicators, World Bank.

5 EconomicLetter

Chart 7

Actual and Expected U.S. Inflation Trend Downward
Percent
12

10

Long-run inflation expectation
One-year inflation expectation
Core PCEPI inflation

8

CPI inflation

6

4

2

0
’82

’84

’86

’88

’90

’92

’94

’96

’98

’00

’02

’04

’06

NOTE: Data are monthly.
SOURCES: Blue Chip Survey; Survey of Professional Forecasters.

Chart 8

Declining Inflation Seen Around the World
Percent
25

20

U.S.

Germany

U.K.

France

Canada

Japan

Italy
15

10

5

0

–5
1970

1975

1980

1985

1990

1995

2000

2005

SOURCES: Haver Analytics.

EconomicLetter 6

FEDERAL RESERVE BANK OF DALLAS

Treasury bonds have both retreated
over the past two decades (Chart 9).5
Greater price stability has led to a substantial reduction in the inflation risk
perceived by investors, and, as a consequence, both inflation premiums
and long-term bond yields are lower.
Money has become more internationally mobile over the past two
decades. Cross-border bond and equity transactions now exceed $90 trillion
a year, and the total value of global
financial markets has reached $118
trillion, three times global GDP.6
Financial market integration has effectively increased potential competition
among national currencies, significantly contributing to the low and stable
inflation that produces greater stability
of long-term bond yields around the
world.7
Many nations once imposed rigid
controls that hindered foreigners’ ability to invest in the country and kept
their citizens from investing abroad.
Now, capital is less likely to be held
captive to nationality. In a globalized
world with highly mobile capital, it is
much easier for investors to convert
their assets into other nations’ currencies should they become concerned
about the inflation risk of their local
money. Currency competition forces
national governments to discipline
their economic policies and pursue
price stability.
The conventional wisdom, of
course, still holds: Inflation is largely a
monetary phenomenon. But nations
have resorted to various methods to
enforce the monetary discipline
required in an era of globalization.
Since the early 1990s, central banks in
a number of countries—among them,
the U.K., New Zealand, Canada,
Sweden and Australia—have adopted
an inflation-targeting approach to
monetary policy, making clear their
priority is to maintain price stability.
Setting an explicit target has substantially enhanced the banks’ credibility.
Inflation volatility and the perceived
inflation risk have declined substantially in those countries. Even in the

U.S. and other nations that haven’t
explicitly set numeric targets, central
banks’ efforts to restrain inflation have
decreased its average level and volatility, thereby strengthening investors’
confidence in long-run price stability.
Globalization’s influence on inflation isn’t limited to money and financial markets. Increased international
competition in product and labor markets has also contributed to price stability. With goods, services and information crossing borders more readily
than ever, producers are forced to
match foreign competitors’ prices and
quality by increasing productivity and
decreasing costs. Greater factor mobility has also helped lower costs and
inflation around the world because it
allows labor and capital to flow more
freely toward centers of comparative
advantage, where they can be their
most productive.
Globalization has reduced longterm interest rates and made longterm lending instruments more substitutable internationally. It has done so
in three ways: by reducing the level
and volatility of inflation across many
nations, by helping stabilize the business cycle and reduce investors’
uncertainty regarding future economic
shocks, and by encouraging the development of deeper, more integrated
global financial markets that help
direct loanable funds into a common
pool. The upshot is a higher interest
elasticity of bond demand than existed in yesterday’s more insular world.
Monetary Policy Implications
Today, investors have greater
opportunity to choose from among a
globally diverse range of assets. As
domestic and foreign financial instruments become more substitutable,
each country’s interest rates—in particular, the medium- to long-term
maturities—will be determined more
by global influences and less by
domestic factors. Central banks’ ability
to affect long-term rates may be
severely eroded, as we have seen in
the recent “conundrum” period.

Chart 9

Less Inflation Volatility Leads to Lower Risk Premiums
Percent
4
3.5
CPI inflation volatility

3
2.5
2

Inflation risk premium on
5-year Treasury bond

1.5
1
.5
0
–.5
–1
’82

’84

’86

’88

’90

’92

’94

’96

’98

’00

’02

’04

’06

NOTE: Data are monthly.
SOURCE: Bureau of Labor Statistics.

Consequently, the effects of monetary policy tightening or loosening
may be substantially weakened.
Because long rates are less sensitive
to short rates, the response of aggregate demand to monetary policy
moves may prove sluggish. One
example is the lack of response in the
mortgage and housing markets in
2004 and early 2005, when homebuyers’ borrowing costs changed little as
the Federal Reserve tightened. Low
rates kept the housing boom in high
gear, stimulating sales and providing
builders with incentives to expand
operations despite the Fed’s attempt
to slow the economy.
Globalization’s impact on the
relationship between short- and longterm interest rates poses potentially
formidable challenges for central
banks around the world. It underscores the importance of formulating
monetary policy in a credible, consistent and forward-looking way and
better communicating it to the public.
Adopting these virtues will help
anchor long-run inflationary expecta-

FEDERAL RESERVE BANK OF DALLAS

tions and decrease associated risk premiums. It will also help the public
better understand central banks’
behavior and decrease the perceived
uncertainty of future monetary policy.
Globalization may also call for greater
cooperation and coordination of policy
worldwide because international financial conditions increasingly affect the
price of credit in all major countries.
New economic realities and relationships have challenged the basic
assumptions of monetary policy in the
past. Two decades ago, for example, a
strategy of relying on monetary aggregates proved ineffective, leading the
Fed to shift its primary policy focus to
actual inflation and capacity measures.
Now, just as then, a deeper understanding of the factors in play will
allow central bankers to achieve their
mandate of non-inflationary economic
growth.
Wu is a senior economist in the Research
Department of the Federal Reserve Bank of
Dallas.

7 EconomicLetter

EconomicLetter

Notes
1

This calculation is based on the yields of
three-month and 10-year Treasury bonds.
2 For instance, “The Bond Yield ‘Conundrum’
from a Macro-Finance Perspective,” by Glenn
Rudebusch, Eric Swanson and Tao Wu, presented at the 13th Bank of Japan International
Conference, “Financial Markets and the Real
Economy in a Low Interest Rate Environment,”
Tokyo, June 1, 2006.
3 This is according to calculations found in the
following: “Has the U.S. Economy Become
More Stable? A Bayesian Approach Based on a
Markov-Switching Model of the Business
Cycle,” by Chang-Jin Kim and Charles R.
Nelson, The Review of Economics and
Statistics, vol. 81, November 1999, pp. 608–16;
also in “Output Fluctuations in the United
States: What has Changed Since the Early
1980’s,” by Margaret M. McConnell and Gabriel
Perez-Quiros, American Economic Review, vol.
90, December 2000, pp. 1464–76.
4 The one-year-ahead inflation expectation is the

year-ahead CPI inflation expectation from the
Blue Chip survey, and the long-run inflation
expectation is the 10-year inflation expectation
from the Survey of Professional Forecasters.
5 The inflation volatility in Chart 9 is measured
by the five-year trailing standard deviation of
the annual CPI inflation. The inflation premium
on a five-year Treasury bond is calculated using
a no-arbitrage-based term structure model.
6 “Internationalisation of Financial Services:
Implications and Challenges for Central Banks,”
by Hervé Hannoun, presented at the 41st
Conference of the South East Asian Central
Banks Governors, Bandar Seri Begawan, Brunei
Darussalam, March 4, 2006, and “$118 Trillion
and Counting: Taking Stock of the World’s
Capital Markets,” McKinsey Global Institute,
February 2005, www.mckinsey.com/
mgi/publications/gcm/index.asp.
7 Remarks by Federal Reserve Governor Randall
S. Kroszner at the Institute of International
Bankers, New York, June 16, 2006.

Dallas Fed
Your Source for Regional Economic Indicators

is published monthly
by the Federal Reserve Bank of Dallas. The views
expressed are those of the authors and should not be
attributed to the Federal Reserve Bank of Dallas or the
Federal Reserve System.
Articles may be reprinted on the condition that
the source is credited and a copy is provided to the
Research Department of the Federal Reserve Bank of
Dallas.
Economic Letter is available free of charge by
writing the Public Affairs Department, Federal Reserve
Bank of Dallas, P.O. Box 655906, Dallas, TX 752655906; by fax at 214-922-5268; or by telephone at 214922-5254. This publication is available on the Dallas
Fed web site, www.dallasfed.org.

Richard W. Fisher
President and Chief Executive Officer
Helen E. Holcomb
First Vice President and Chief Operating Officer
Harvey Rosenblum
Executive Vice President and Director of Research

State and Metro Employment Data
Revised early in advance of Texas Workforce Commission
Business-Cycle Indexes
Monitor economic activity in Texas and its major metros
Texas Leading Index
Predicts economic activity in the state
Beige Book
Reports anecdotal comments on current economic conditions
Texas Manufacturing Outlook Survey
Assesses current conditions and outlook, including output,
employment, prices and inventories
Texas Industrial Production Index
Measures monthly changes in overall manufacturing,
mining and utilities
Survey of Agricultural Credit Conditions
Presents bankers’ insights into agricultural lending and land values
Find these data and more at www.dallasfed.org.
E-mail alerts available

W. Michael Cox
Senior Vice President and Chief Economist
Robert D. Hankins
Senior Vice President, Banking Supervision
Executive Editor
W. Michael Cox
Editor
Richard Alm
Associate Editor
Monica Reeves
Graphic Designer
Gene Autry

FEDERAL RESERVE BANK OF DALLAS
2200 N. PEARL ST.
DALLAS, TX 75201