View original document

The full text on this page is automatically extracted from the file linked above and may contain errors and inconsistencies.

VOL. 12, NO. 10 • OCTOBER 2017

DALLASFED

Economic
Letter
Global and National Shocks Explain
A Large Share of State Job Growth
by Alexander Chudik, Janet Koech and Mark A. Wynne

}

ABSTRACT: Global and U.S.
national shocks on average
appear to equally explain more
than half of the fluctuations
in state employment growth,
an important measure of
assessing real economic
activity. The overall
assessment, however,
conceals a wide variation
among states.

E

mployment growth is a widely
used and closely watched indicator of real economic activity at the state level. Booms
are associated with rapid employment
growth, while recessions are associated
with job losses.
Employment growth in Texas, for
example, has run at almost twice the average rate of growth in the United States as
a whole since 1990. During the 2007–09
recession, job losses in Texas were less
than the national average.
There is considerable variation in the
rate of job gains and losses across the
50 states during the business cycle
(Chart 1). The gap between states with
the most job increases and the least, as
measured by year-over-year employment
growth, averaged 8.3 percentage points
from 1980 through 2016. These variations can contribute to large differences
in state unemployment rates.1
What accounts for these differences?
A state’s rate of employment growth ultimately reflects its economic structure
and the economic shocks impacting it.
Both of these, in turn, are influenced
by increased integration of the global
economy over roughly the past quarter
century, a process commonly referred to
as globalization.
Globalization affects not just national
economies, but also those of individual

states. Texas exported more than $230 billion worth of goods to the rest of the world
in 2016. So it is expected that employment
growth in Texas would at least somewhat
reflect global economic developments.
At the same time, Texas trades extensively with the rest of the U.S.—commerce
that is greatly facilitated by the absence
of trade barriers between states and by
the sharing of a single currency. Thus, the
national business cycle also affects Texas
employment growth.
This leads to the question: What is the
relative importance of global economic
shocks, national economic shocks and
residual shocks in accounting for employment growth fluctuations across the 50
states?
New econometric techniques provide
some guidance. They reveal that global
output shocks account for a quarter of the
fluctuations in employment growth across
states, with national shocks contributing
a slightly higher share at 30.7 percent. The
remaining unexplained portion—44.5
percent—results from any other shocks
affecting the states (Chart 2).2

Measuring Shocks
Identifying shocks is a challenging fundamental problem in empirical
research and a major source of dispute
among economists. In this context,
global output shocks are identified as

Economic Letter
the shocks to real (inflation adjusted)
gross domestic product (GDP) in an
aggregate of 21 foreign countries. This
grouping includes a mix of developed
and emerging-market economies that
collectively accounted for half of global
GDP in 2016.3
National shocks are identified as
shocks to U.S. national employment and
output that cannot be accounted for by

Chart

1

the global shocks. And finally, residual
shocks are constructed as the remainder
term accounting for state employment
growth fluctuations that cannot be
explained by global and national output
and employment growth fluctuations.
An econometric model known as a
global vector autoregression (GVAR) is
used to estimate contributions of these
shocks to employment growth fluctua-

U.S. Employment Growth Gap Varies Across States

Percentage points

15

Minimummaximum
range

10

Texas employment
National average

5
0
–5
–10
–15
1980

1985

1990

1995

2000

2005

2010

2015

NOTES: Employment fluctuations are computed as year-over-year growth in quarterly nonfarm payroll employment.
Shaded bars indicate U.S. recessions.
SOURCES: Bureau of Labor Statistics; Haver Analytics; authors’ calculations.

Chart

2

tions and to quantify the impact of these
shocks. An advantage of the GVAR model
is that it allows for rich interactions
between countries and states.4 We estimate the model using quarterly growth
rates from third quarter 1980 to fourth
quarter 2016.

Which Shocks Matter?
While global output shocks account
for 25 percent of the average share of
variation in employment growth, large
differences exist among states—from a
low of 0.3 percent in Alaska to a high of
42.6 percent in Illinois.
Global output shocks play essentially no role in explaining employment
growth fluctuations in the District of
Columbia, North Dakota, Louisiana and
West Virginia as well as Alaska. Given
the importance of federal government
employment in the District of Columbia,
it is perhaps not surprising that global
output shocks play a small role in
employment growth fluctuations there.
What Alaska, North Dakota and
Louisiana have in common is that they
are big energy states. Employment in
these states may be more dependent on
technological innovations in crude oil
extraction and the price of oil than on
global and national business cycles. In
Texas, over a third of employment growth

Global, National and Residual Shocks Explain States’ Employment Variation

Percent
100
90
80
70
60
50
40
30
20

Global shock, avg = 24.8%

National shocks, avg = 30.7%

Residual shocks, avg = 44.5%

SOURCE: Authors’ calculations.

2

Economic Letter • Federal Reserve Bank of Dallas • October 2017

MN
IN
CA
SC
PA
WI
TN
OH
NC

0

DC
LA
ND
AK
WV
HI
WY
MT
OK
SD
NE
NH
NM
MA
ME
VT
ID
DE
RI
CT
CO
MS
KS
AR
IA
TX
NJ
UT
NY
WA
MD
NV
AZ
VA
MO
FL
MI
OR
KY
AL
GA
IL

10

Economic Letter
fluctuations are explained by global output shocks.
National shocks contribute an average
of 30.7 percent to overall fluctuations in
state employment growth. Interestingly,
some of the same areas—the District of
Columbia, North Dakota, Louisiana and
West Virginia—that seem to be relatively
immune to global output shocks are also
immune to U.S. national shocks. National
shocks also seem to play a relatively
small role in explaining employment
growth fluctuations in Wyoming, Hawaii,
Oklahoma and Montana.
States most impacted by national
shocks include Ohio, South Carolina,
Michigan, Florida and North Carolina.
National shocks explain about a quarter
(24.7 percent) of employment growth
fluctuations in Texas, well below the average share across states.
The share of employment growth fluctuations not explained by either global or
national shocks is attributed to residual
shocks. Residual shocks are most important in the District of Columbia (accounting for about 92 percent of employment
growth fluctuations) and in the energy
states of Louisiana, North Dakota and
Alaska (where these shocks explain
upwards of 80 percent of the fluctuations).
Conversely, North Carolina, Ohio,
Tennessee, Wisconsin and Pennsylvania

Chart

3

have the lowest shares of employment
growth fluctuations explained by residual
shocks. These shares are less than half
the average size of shares across all states.
Residual shocks explain 40 percent of
Texas’ employment growth fluctuations,
slightly below the national average.

Impact over Time
A natural follow-up question is how
all of these shocks play out over time.
What is the cumulative effect over four
quarters of a global output shock on
employment growth?
Based on the model, Chart 3 shows
the effect of a 0.5 percent negative global
output growth surprise on state employment levels four quarters after the shock.
These types of simulations, known as
impulse-response functions, show the
deviations of employment growth from
baseline projections as a sole consequence of the considered global output
shock.
The findings indicate that the total
effect after a year is negative for employment growth across all states except
Alaska, where the estimated effect is not
statistically significantly different from
zero. The expected effect of a surprise
slowdown in global output growth is
most pronounced over a year in Nevada
(down 1.4 percent), Wyoming (down 1.3

percent) and Idaho (down 1.2 percent).
This is equivalent to a loss of between
3,500 and 18,100 jobs.
States less affected by a slowdown
in foreign economies are Alaska, the
District of Colombia, North Dakota and
New Jersey. Employment in Texas is
expected to fall 0.93 percent following
a 0.5 percent surprise decline in aggregate foreign output. Texas’ employment
drop over four quarters is larger than
the national average of 0.79 percent and
equivalent to a loss of 111,700 jobs.5

Decomposing Texas Job Growth
Global and national business cycles
have contributed to Texas’ employment
growth in varying amounts (Chart 4). A
slow global economic recovery has held
back the state’s employment growth
since 2012, while national factors have
positively contributed to it.
During the global financial crisis,
Texas’ employment growth fell sharply,
dragged lower by both global and
national factors, while residual factors
seem to have contributed positively to
employment growth during the period
and since.

Geographic Differences
The impact of the global business
cycle on job gains and losses in

Effect of a 0.5% Negative Shock to Foreign Output on U.S. States’ Employment Level One Year Later
(Cumulative effect one year after shock–deviations from baseline)

Percentage points

1.0
Average = –0.79

= 80% confidence interval

0

AK
AL
AR
AZ
CA
CO
CT
DC
DE
FL
GA
HI
IA
ID
IL
IN
KS
KY
LA
MA
MD
ME
MI
MN
MO
MS
MT
NC
ND
NE
NH
NJ
NM
NV
NY
OH
OK
OR
PA
RI
SC
SD
TN
TX
UT
VA
VT
WA
WI
WV
WY

0.5

–0.5

–1.0

–1.5

–2.0
NOTES: A one-year cumulative impact on national employment growth is –0.81 percent, and a one-year cumulative impact on foreign output growth is –1.16 percent. The 0.5 percentage-point magnitude
of the shock is relatively large given that the sample standard deviation (a statistical measure of a standard size of a shock) is 0.35 percentage points.
SOURCE: Authors’ calculations.

Economic Letter • Federal Reserve Bank of Dallas • October 2017

3

Economic Letter

Chart

4

Notes

Texas Employment Growth Reflects Contributions
of Various Shocks

During the global financial crisis, for example, Michigan
recorded the highest unemployment rate of 14.9 percent and
North Dakota the lowest at 4.2 percent in June 2009. That
gap between the highest and lowest unemployment rates
across U.S. states had fallen substantially to just 4 percentage points by the end of 2016.
2
Fluctuations in state employment growth not explained
by global business-cycle movements or movements in the
national business cycle are attributed to residual shocks. For
instance, oil price movements impacting state employment that are not captured by global or national shocks are
attributed to the residual shock.
3
Real GDP for the following countries were included in the
estimation of the global output shock: Argentina, Australia,
Austria, Belgium, Canada, China, Colombia, France,
Germany, Italy, Japan, Korea, Mexico, Netherlands, Peru,
1

Percentage points

1.5
1.0
0.5
0
–0.5
Residual shocks
National shocks
Global shocks
Texas employment
growth
(quarter/quarter,
detrended)

–1.0
–1.5
–2.0
–2.5

1985

1990

1995

2000

2005

2010

2015

NOTES: Texas employment growth is detrended by subtracting the historical average. Shaded bars indicate U.S.
recessions.
SOURCE: Authors’ calculations.

individual U.S. states is not negligible,
accounting for about a quarter of individual state-level fluctuations, on average, and slightly less than the contribution of the national business cycle.
The effects of global and national
business cycles are, at the same time,
highly heterogeneous across the U.S.
states. Among Federal Reserve policymakers, understanding such asymmetries is important to achieving a better
understanding of geographic propagation of U.S. monetary policy. Industry
structure, trade and financial linkages,

DALLASFED

and demographic factors might provide
additional insight into such state-by-state
differences. Such relationships may be
the subject of future research.

Portugal, South Africa, Spain, Sweden, Switzerland and the
United Kingdom.
4
An overview of the GVAR approach is provided by “Theory
and Practice of GVAR Modelling,” by Alexander Chudik and
M. Hashem Pesaran, Journal of Economic Surveys, vol. 30,
no. 1, 2016, pp. 165–97.
5
The model used is symmetric, and the effects of positive
output growth surprises will be positive, with magnitudes
equal to those from the effects of negative output growth
surprises.

Chudik is an economic policy advisor and
senior research economist and Koech is
an assistant economist in the Globalization Institute at the Federal Reserve Bank
of Dallas. Wynne is a vice president and
associate director of research for international economics in the Research Department and director of the Globalization
Institute.

Economic Letter

is published by the Federal Reserve Bank of Dallas.
The views expressed are those of the authors and
should not be attributed to the Federal Reserve Bank
of Dallas or the Federal Reserve System.
Articles may be reprinted on the condition that
the source is credited to the Federal Reserve Bank
of Dallas.
Economic Letter is available on the Dallas Fed
website, www.dallasfed.org.

Marc P. Giannoni, Senior Vice President and Director of Research
Jim Dolmas, Executive Editor
Michael Weiss, Editor
Kathy Thacker, Associate Editor
Ellah Piña, Graphic Designer

Federal Reserve Bank of Dallas
2200 N. Pearl St., Dallas, TX 75201