View original document

The full text on this page is automatically extracted from the file linked above and may contain errors and inconsistencies.

VOL. 10, NO. 9 • OCTOBER 2015­­

DALLASFED

Economic
Letter
Foreign Direct Investment:
Financial Benefits Could
Surpass Gains in Technology

}
ABSTRACT: Many emerging
markets offer financial
incentives to attract foreign
direct investment, believing
that such investment provides
advanced technology or
management skills. However,
it appears developing
economies such as China
could benefit more from
multinational corporations’
financial resources.

by Jian Wang, Janet Koech and Xiao Wang

C

ross-border capital flows have
increased substantially since
the 1990s, reaching a peak of 20
percent of world gross domestic product (GDP) in 2007. Multinational
corporations provide the majority of the
flows, known as foreign direct investment, or FDI.
FDI has long been viewed as a way to
promote the productivity of host countries, especially emerging economies.
Many less-developed countries attempt
to attract FDI by offering tax and other
financial benefits. They hope these outside investments will speed movement
toward the world technology frontier.
However, FDI’s greatest contribution
to emerging markets may lie in easier
access to global financial markets rather
than the mere acquisition of advanced
technology. Notably, the financial conditions of local firms in China improved
substantially after foreigners acquired
the companies, a recent study showed.1
Relaxed financial constraints allowed
the newly purchased firms to increase
exports and total output.
In other words, foreign ownership per
se does not significantly improve the productivity of local firms, based on a variety
of metrics. Instead, the key factor is that

capital flows from multinationals abroad
help alleviate financial market frictions in
the host countries, which enables them to
allocate resources more efficiently across
firms and sectors.2

Productivity-Driven FDI
FDI in emerging economies
increased sixfold from 1995 to 2013. In
2012, emerging markets became the primary destination for FDI for the first time
(Chart 1).
Conventional wisdom holds that
FDI can benefit host countries through
several channels. 3 FDI eases the introduction of new and better technology
and management skills to host countries.
Recipient firms can produce more than
local firms, leading to greater efficiency.
Over time, this line of reasoning suggests,
the high productivity of firms benefiting from FDI will likely spill over to local
companies through labor mobility, production integration and other channels.
Economists often consider total factor
productivity (TFP). It is a measure of output reflecting companies’ technology and
efficiency, taking into account capital and
labor inputs used in production. Higher
TFP yields more output with the same
inputs (Chart 2). Total inputs equivalent

Economic Letter
Chart

1

Emerging Markets Get Most Foreign Direct Investment

U.S. dollars (billions)

2,500
World
2,000

Developed economies
Developing economies

1,500

Transition economies
40%

1,000
500
0
1990

54%

1995

2000

2005

2010

NOTE: Developed economies are typically countries of the Organization for Economic Cooperation and Development and
new European Union members; transition economies include former Soviet Republics and countries in Southeast Europe;
developing (emerging) economies are all other countries.
SOURCES: United Nations Conference on Trade and Development; authors’ calculations.

Chart

2

Higher Total Factor Productivity Yields More Output

Output
High TFP

C

Low TFP

B

A

Inputs

NOTE: The lines labeled “high TFP” and “low TFP” present two production possibilities. High TFP produces more output
than low TFP given the same amount of input, indicating higher productivity.

to A produce output C when productivity
is higher—but a smaller amount, output
B, in a less-productive environment.
Multinational companies generally
have higher TFP than firms that do not
engage in FDI.4 It has long been believed
that multinationals’ technology and efficiency advantages have driven FDI. In the
process, the investment transfers technology, skills, innovative capacity, organization
and managerial practices from advanced
economies to less-advanced ones.

2

Output improvement can also be
achieved by mixing inputs in different
proportions—for instance, by equipping labor with more capital. However,
financial constraints in emerging markets
can limit such an efficiency gain. Firms
cannot mix labor with as much capital as
they would like to deploy (Chart 3). The
blue downward-sloping line represents
the budget constraint for a firm that pays
a higher cost for capital due to financial
constraints. The firm’s optimal output is

at point A, obtained by combining K units
of capital and L units of labor.
Once the firm’s financial constraint is
relaxed—for example, through FDI—its
budget line shifts outward to the red
downward-sloping straight line, which has
a lower unit cost of capital. With this shift,
the optimal output for the firm is now at
point B, which uses K’ units of capital and
L’ units of labor. Output B is higher than
output A—the firm is able to produce more
after equipping its labor with more capital.

Decoding the Correlation
Multinational affiliates often display
higher TFP than local firms, data show.
However, identifying a causal relationship between FDI and greater productivity is more challenging. The correlation in the data may simply reflect that
multinationals buy the most productive
local firms or hire the most productive employees rather than transfer
technology/skills.
In fact, FDI effects on productivity
may depend on many factors, including
the country of origin of the investment,
the industry receiving the investment
and the timing of the investment.
There is little evidence that additional
productivity gains accompany foreign
ownership, based on a comparison of
postacquisition performances of foreignand domestic-acquired firms in China
from 2000 to 2007.
Foreign-acquired firms were paired
with domestic-acquired firms that had
similar preacquisition characteristics.
Then the postacquisition firm performances of the two groups were compared, based on the assumption that,
owing to their preacquisition similarities,
the firms’ differences were likely attributable to the foreign ownership of foreignacquired firms.
The analysis reveals that the productivity of foreign acquisitions doesn’t
differ from that of domestic acquisitions.
Both types of acquisitions improved
target firms’ TFP relative to the domestic
firms whose ownership didn’t change.
That’s because mergers and acquisitions in general facilitate reallocation of
resources from less-productive firms to
more-productive ones. But foreign ownership doesn’t bring additional productivity gains.

Economic Letter • Federal Reserve Bank of Dallas • October 2015

Economic Letter
Governments seeking to accelerate
growth and economic transformation
have increasingly pursued policies to
attract FDI—emerging-market economies’
largest source of capital inflows (Chart
4). However, FDI-promotion policy does
not serve its purpose if FDI isn’t driven
by productivity, and such policy can be
costly, especially in terms of foregone tax
revenues.

Finance-Driven Investment
Economists have recently explored
other motivations for FDI flows. Among
these studies, several examine the financial advantages of multinational affiliates.
Firms in emerging markets often face
severe financial constraints due to underdeveloped local financial markets and
restrictions on access to foreign financial
markets. FDI to these countries can be
motivated by multinationals’ easy access to
international financial markets rather than
higher productivity.
Foreign investment improved target
firms’ financial conditions in the study of
FDI in China.
The foreign-acquired companies
became relatively less indebted, as measured by the decline in the leverage ratio
(the fraction of a firm’s total liabilities relative to its total assets). A declining leverage
ratio indicates that firms depend less on
external financing to cover operational
costs and may have fewer difficulties raising funds in the future.
Foreign-acquired firms also tended
to have a healthier liquidity ratio, which
is the difference between current assets
(cash and cash-equivalents) and current
liabilities as a share of a firm’s total assets.
A higher liquidity ratio indicates that
firms have more liquid assets to cope with
potential external financial disruptions and
hence are less financially constrained.
Following acquisitions, the leverage ratio of foreign-acquired firms in the
China study declined relative to domesticacquired firms, while the liquidity ratio of
the foreign-acquired firms increased.5 This
shows that foreign-acquired firms become
less vulnerable than their domestic counterparts to external financial shocks:
Foreign-acquired firms rely less on shortterm debt and more on internal capital
following a takeover. This is indicative of
foreign ownership’s role in relaxing credit

Chart

3

Relaxed Financial Restrictions Allow More Output at Same
Overall Cost

Labor

A

L
L'

B
Output B
Output A

K

Chart

4

K'

Capital

FDI Dominates Developing Economies’ Capital Flows

Percent of gross national income

5

Foreign direct investment (FDI)

4
3
Remittances

2
1
Portfolio equity
0
–1

1991 1993 1995 1997 1999 2001 2003 2005 2007 2009 2011 2013

SOURCE: World Bank’s World Development Indicators database.

constraints, which is largely due to easier
access to international financial markets
and foreign parent company resources.
Foreign-acquired firms gain additional
benefits, some involving international
trade. The export share of foreign-acquired
enterprises rose about 3 percentage
points relative to domestic-acquired firms.
Exporters benefit from newly available
finances to bridge the time gap between
production expenses and export payment.
Moreover, foreign-acquired firms in
emerging markets can better fund the large
fixed costs of international export trade.
FDI capital can help foreign-acquired

local firms penetrate foreign markets and
promote exports. Foreign owners can also
pass their knowledge of foreign markets to
acquired local firms.
Improved financial conditions may
also give foreign-acquired firms competitive advantages unrelated to productivity.
For instance, greater liquidity helps firms
better cope with economic shocks and
gain market share. The overall effects are
increased total output, employment and
real wages relative to domestic-acquired
firms.
However, FDI doesn’t seem to deliver
more output with the same inputs—that

Economic Letter • Federal Reserve Bank of Dallas • October 2015

3

Economic Letter

is, through TFP gains. Rather, improvement is achieved by combining labor and
capital inputs in more efficient proportions. Domestic companies, without the
same access to credit as multinationals,
can’t replicate that performance.
Finance-driven FDI is likely to be
prevalent in emerging markets where
local firms face constraints due to
underdeveloped financial markets.6
Financial repression may also play a role:
Disfavored firms can implement only
high-yield projects with short maturity,
while firms with subsidized, often outside funding choose relatively capitalintensive technologies. In this case, multinationals can bring welfare-improving
changes, such as access to a better mix of
products and inputs.

Local Market Efficiencies
A wave of rapid financial globalization
has occurred in the past two decades,
marked by a surge of FDI. Many emerging markets offer incentives to lure FDI
in the belief that such funding provides
advanced technology, management and
capital.
In China and many other emerging markets, gains from FDI may simply
reflect multinationals’ financial advantages rather than heightened productivity
per se. While most developing countries
install FDI-promotion policies, the
results vary. Providing a macroeconomic
environment that can help FDI firms
maximize their comparative advantages
is the most effective way of attracting FDI
investment.

DALLASFED

Because an important aspect of FDI
is its ability to promote international
trade, it follows that the removal of trade
barriers through free-trade agreements
and World Trade Organization membership is more effective than mechanically
providing tax and financial incentives to
multinationals.
Finance-driven FDI inflows may
reflect local financial market inefficiencies; therefore, FDI inflows should not be
the sole criterion for policy evaluation.
Emerging countries may be better served
by improving the efficiency of their financial markets through reforms instead of
ramping up incentives to attract foreign
investment. Additionally, without wellfunctioning local financial markets, spillover from FDI recipient firms to domestic
firms may be limited.7
Jian Wang is a senior research economist
and advisor and Koech is an assistant
economist in the Research Department of
the Federal Reserve Bank of Dallas. Xiao
Wang is an assistant professor of economics at the University of North Dakota.

investment). Motivated by long-term prospects for the
invested projects, FDI investors are directly involved in the
production and cannot withdraw their investment easily. In
contrast, portfolio investment is often driven by short-term
profit-seeking activities and is prone to sudden capital-flow
reversals, which can trigger financial crises in the host
countries.
4
Studies have shown that U.S. multinational corporations
are on average more productive than U.S. firms that do not
conduct FDI. For instance, see “Export Versus FDI with
Heterogeneous Firms,” by Elhanan Helpman, Marc J. Melitz
and Stephen R. Yeaple, American Economic Review, vol. 94,
no. 1, 2004, pp. 300–16.
5
This study also confirms that the improvement of financial
conditions in foreign acquisitions relative to domestic
acquisitions is mainly from the financial improvement of
foreign-acquired firms rather than the financial deterioration
of domestic-acquired firms.
6
For evidence on 15 emerging markets, see “LiquidityDriven FDI,” by Ron Alquist, Rahul Mukherjee and Linda L.
Tesar, Graduate Institute of International and Development
Studies Working Paper no. 17-2014, December 2014. Also
see note 2.
7
See “FDI and Economic Growth: The Role of Local Financial Markets,” by Laura Alfaro, Areendam Chanda, Sebnem
Kalemli-Ozcan and Selin Sayek, Journal of International
Economics, vol. 64, no. 1, 2004, pp. 89–112.

Notes
See “Benefits of Foreign Ownership: Evidence from
Foreign Direct Investment in China,” by Jian Wang and Xiao
Wang, forthcoming, Journal of International Economics.
2
These findings are consistent with arguments that limited
access to credit markets restricts local firms’ production potential. See Money and Capital in Economic Development,
by Ronald I. McKinnon, Washington, D.C.: The Brookings
Institution, 1973.
3
In addition, FDI is safer than other international capital
flows, such as bank lending and equity investment (portfolio
1

Economic Letter

is published by the Federal Reserve Bank of Dallas.
The views expressed are those of the authors and
should not be attributed to the Federal Reserve Bank
of Dallas or the Federal Reserve System.
Articles may be reprinted on the condition that
the source is credited and a copy is provided to the
Research Department of the Federal Reserve Bank
of Dallas.
Economic Letter is available on the Dallas Fed
website, www.dallasfed.org.

Mine Yücel, Senior Vice President and Director of Research
Carlos E.J.M. Zarazaga, Executive Editor
Michael Weiss, Editor
Kathy Thacker, Associate Editor
Ellah Piña, Graphic Designer

Federal Reserve Bank of Dallas
2200 N. Pearl St., Dallas, TX 75201