View original document

The full text on this page is automatically extracted from the file linked above and may contain errors and inconsistencies.

Vol. 2,  No. 4
April 2007­­

EconomicLetter
Insights from the

F e d e r a l R e s e r v e B a n k  of D a l l a s

Fiscal Fitness: The U.S. Budget
Deficit’s Uncertain Prospects
by Jason L. Saving

The inescapable
conclusion is that

Recent headlines tell us U.S. budget deficits have been shrinking in the
past few years, but Washington’s fiscal fitness remains a matter of concern.

we face a daunting

The International Monetary Fund, for example, has argued that world-

fiscal situation, one

wide economic growth will be noticeably weaker in the future if the U.S. doesn’t

with potentially

get its fiscal house in order. In January, Federal Reserve Board Chairman Ben

harmful implications

Bernanke told Congress that the U.S. faces an impending fiscal crisis if it fails to

for the U.S. economy.

address key budget issues.1
Such warnings call for a sober examination of prospects for the nation’s
budget deficits. The most recent proposal envisions eliminating them within six
years, but doing so will require lawmakers to overcome several significant obstacles. Other uncertainties emerge from the recently approved pay-as-you-go,
or paygo, rules and their effect on potential reforms of the alternative minimum

tax (AMT). Both paygo and the
AMT play important roles in another major fiscal question—the
fate of the 2001 and 2003 tax cuts.
Even if we manage to handle these
short-term issues, the long-term
challenge posed by entitlements is
significantly greater, with no easy
solutions in sight.
The inescapable conclusion is
that we face a daunting fiscal situation, one with potentially harmful
implications for the U.S. economy.
Spending Growth
The federal deficit has fallen
for three straight years — from
a record $412 billion in 2004 to
$248 billion in 2006. In February,
President Bush released a proposed budget under which red ink
would decline to $244 billion this
year and $187 billion in 2009. The
document projects a surplus of $61
billion in 2012 (Chart 1).
What assumptions underlie
these figures — and are they likely
to hold? The proposed budget
assumes 3 percent real annual
growth in gross domestic product
(GDP) and 4.8 percent unemployment between now and 2012,
figures that aren’t out of line with
most forecasts. But it also assumes
that real spending growth will be
held to 0.4 percent a year, very
low by historical standards.
Past budgets have been presented with similarly inspiring calls
to rein in government spending.
If this year’s targets were to be
similarly disregarded, what might
the deficit picture look like? To
answer this question, let’s look at
the average annual increase in real
federal outlays under the past few
administrations (Chart 2).
Real outlays have grown at
a 4.6 percent annual rate since
President Bush took office in 2001,
compared with 2.7 percent under
Ronald Reagan and 0.8 percent
under Bill Clinton. To some extent, the faster spending growth is

EconomicLetter 

Chart 1

Will Deficit Turn to Surplus by 2012?
Billions of dollars
400

Surplus

200

Projected

0

–200

–400

–600
Deficit
–800
’60

’64

’68

’72

’76

’80

’84

’88

’92

’96

’00

’04

’08

SOURCE: Fiscal year 2008 budget, Office of Management and Budget.

Chart 2

Spending Growth Has Accelerated
Annual rate (percent)
12
10

Defense

Nondefense

Total

8
6
4
2
0
–2
–4
–6

Carter
1977–81

Reagan
1981–89

*Data are through 2005.
SOURCE: Office of Management and Budget.

Fede ral Reserve Bank of Dall as

G.H.W. Bush
1989–93

Clinton
1993–2001

G.W. Bush
2001–*

’12

expected, given that we are now
using the post-Cold War “peace
dividend” to fight the war on terrorism. Defense spending has indeed been sharply higher in recent
years, but nondefense outlays have
also risen more rapidly, growing at
a real annual rate of 3.5 percent.
History creates doubts about
whether Washington can limit
spending growth to 0.4 percent
a year, suggesting that the deficit
picture may be worse in 2012 than
the budget projects. How much
worse? If one replaces the Bush
administration’s spending growth
assumption with the 4.6 percent
rate that has thus far prevailed in
the 21st century, the $61 billion
surplus turns into a $701 billion
deficit (Chart 3).
Let’s call this scenario the
pessimistic projection because it
assumes that the rapid post-9/11
defense buildup will continue. If
it doesn’t, real annual spending
growth between now and 2012
may more closely resemble its
post-Vietnam War historical average of 2.3 percent a year. In this
case, the 2012 deficit would be
$231 billion — about as large as
today’s deficit.
Under the Bush administration’s proposed scenario, the U.S.
won’t achieve a balanced budget
unless spending growth is held far
below recent trends. The paygo
procedure, which a bipartisan
House majority adopted in January,
may help. In simple terms, the
rule mandates that any entitlement
increases or tax decreases be offset
by new revenue.
A similar requirement was in
effect when deficits disappeared in
the 1990s. Several factors contributed to swinging the budget into
surplus, but social scientists who
have studied the issue conclude
that the paygo rule’s influence on
spending growth was significant.2
The paygo rule under which
the House will operate isn’t as

Chart 3

Spending Assumptions Alter Deficit Path
Billions of dollars
400

Surplus

200
Official
projection

0

–200

–400
Historical
projection
–600

Pessimistic
projection

Deficit
–800
’60

’64

’68

’72

’76

’80

’84

’88

’92

’96

’00

’04

’08

’12

SOURCES: Fiscal year 2008 budget, Office of Management and Budget; author’s calculations.

strict as meets the eye. It requires
budgetary neutrality over six-year
and 11-year windows, which
means that large spending in the
near term could conceivably be
offset by promised savings in the
future. The rule doesn’t apply to
tax and entitlement changes already signed into law. The rule can
be waived when a majority wishes
to do so.
However, most observers are
discounting the possibility of major
tax cuts or spending increases in
an era of divided government.
So fiscal policy may look as if it’s
restrained by a binding paygo arrangement over the next few years,
even if the actual rule is somewhat
less stringent.
AMT Tax Relief
Paygo poses problems for fiscal reforms that would drain the
federal Treasury. In particular, it
may complicate efforts to reduce
the AMT’s bite.
Originally designed to affect
155 households whose incomes
exceeded $1.1 million a year in
today’s dollars, the AMT now ap-

Fede ral Reserve Bank of Dall as

If one replaces the Bush
administration’s spending
growth assumption with
the 4.6 percent rate that
has thus far prevailed in
the 21st century, the
$61 billion surplus
turns into a
$701 billion deficit.

 EconomicLetter

The prospect of
enlarging already
big budget deficits
stands in the way
of AMT reform.
Scaling back the
2001/2003 tax cuts
would decrease the
cost of AMT restructuring.

plies to 120,000 households in that
income category — and an additional 3.4 million of lesser means.
If no action is taken, the total
number of households hit by the
AMT will rise to 23.4 million this
year—about a fifth of the nation’s
total. The AMT rolls will swell to
52.6 million in 2017 (Chart 4).3
The rise in households paying the AMT promises to create
a windfall for the Treasury. AMT
receipts totaled $23.9 billion last
year; they will rise to $69.8 billion
in 2007 and $265.2 billion in 2017
under current law.
Why is this happening?
AMT brackets aren’t indexed
for economic growth or inflation. So as per capita GDP and
price levels have risen, the AMT
has extended its reach from the
wealthiest segment of the population into middle — or at least
upper-middle — America.
A succession of temporary
patches had held the inflation
component at bay in recent years,
but their expiration caused this
year’s 20 million jump in AMT
households.

While it’s often difficult to find
consensus on fiscal issues, policymakers generally agree that AMT
brackets should be reset to their
2006 levels and then permanently
indexed to inflation. Such a change
would substantially slow the inexorable march of millions of households toward the AMT.
But it would be hugely expensive. Reform would reduce
projected AMT revenue by an estimated $945 billion over the next
10 years, assuming the 2001/2003
tax cuts are made permanent.
How can AMT reform be
undertaken in a paygo policy environment? To answer this question,
it’s necessary to examine the interaction between the 2001/2003 tax
cuts and the AMT. Individuals pay
the AMT only when their ordinary
income tax liability falls below
their AMT liability. Income tax rate
reductions without corresponding
cuts in the AMT inevitably swell
the ranks of AMT taxpayers, effectively raising the cost of AMT
reform.
If the 2001/2003 tax cuts are
allowed to expire at the end of

Chart 4

Alternative Minimum Tax Explodes in 2007 and Beyond
Millions of AMT taxpayers					
60

Tax revenue (billions of dollars)
Assuming 2001/2003
tax cuts made permanent

50

300

250
Projected
200

40

Taxpayers

30

150
Revenue

20

50

10

0

0
’71 ’73 ’75 ’77 ’79 ’81 ’83 ’85 ’87 ’89 ’91 ’93 ’95 ’97 ’99 ’01 ’03 ’05 ’07 ’09 ’11 ’13 ’15 ’17

SOURCE: Urban–Brookings Tax Policy Center.

EconomicLetter 

100

Fede ral Reserve Bank of Dall as

2010, as current law stipulates,
the cost of long-term AMT reform
would fall from $945 billion to a
more manageable $520 billion.4
The prospect of enlarging
already big budget deficits stands
in the way of AMT reform. Scaling
back the 2001/2003 tax cuts would
decrease the cost of AMT restructuring and give Congress more
flexibility under paygo. However,
the size of the decrease would depend heavily upon which cuts stay
and which go.
Taxes and Growth
The fate of the 2001/2003 tax
cuts will likely be among the most
hotly debated fiscal issues of the
next few years.
We can now say with reasonable certainty that the tax cuts,
which were highly controversial
when adopted, provided a fairly
modest economic tailwind at a significant cost — about $240 billion a
year in forgone revenue.
The Treasury Department
examined the projected economic
impact after 2010 if the tax cuts
were made permanent.5 It found
that investment and capital stock
such as plants and equipment
would both increase 2.3 percent
in the long run. Permanent cuts
would induce a 0.7 percent rise in
gross national product (GNP) — a
modest increase in the size of the
U.S. economy (Chart 5).
But not all components of the
2001/2003 tax cuts are created
equal (Chart 6). The dividend
and capital-gains rate reductions
would boost investment about 1.5
percent, the capital stock about 1
percent and GNP 0.4 percent. The
marginal-rate reductions would
also raise investment and the capital stock about 1 percent and boost
GNP 0.7 percent.
The remaining components—
primarily marriage penalty relief
and expanded child tax credits—
would reduce economic activity by

Chart 5

Tax Cuts Boost Economic Activity
Percent growth
2.5
2
1.5
1
.5
0
–.5
–1

Investment

Capital stock

Real GNP

NOTE: Data reflect projections from 2011 forward if tax cuts are made permanent.
SOURCE: Department of the Treasury.

Chart 6

Tax Cut Components Have Different Economic Impacts
Percent change
2.5
Dividends and capital gains
Top four ordinary rates

2

Remaining components

1.5
1
.5
0
–.5
–1

Investment

Capital stock

NOTE: Data reflect projections from 2011 forward if tax cuts are made permanent.
SOURCE: Department of the Treasury.

Fede ral Reserve Bank of Dall as

 EconomicLetter

Real GNP

The unfunded liability for
Medicare Part D alone—
the drug benefit that
took effect in January
2006—is greater
than the entire Social
Security shortfall.

modest amounts. Because they’re
the most popular elements of the
2001/2003 tax cuts, however, these
components would be the most
likely to survive in the current
political climate.
The real danger isn’t that the
wholesale expiration of the
2001/2003 tax cuts might drive
the economy into recession. Their
aggregate effect is simply too
small for that, even if full repeal
were politically feasible. Rather,
the danger is that partial repeal
could leave us with much of the
revenue loss but none of the tailwinds — or perhaps even with a
slight headwind.
The Biggest Challenge
At least in the short term,
the budget outlook is roughly
what it has been in the recent
past. The deficit will neither balloon nor vanish, and the complex
interplay among near-term fiscal
issues such as AMT relief and the
2001/2003 tax cuts poses challenges we can likely — or at least
conceivably—weather.
The long-term outlook is more
problematic, and the single greatest obstacle is entitlements. The
infinite-horizon discounted present
value of unfunded liabilities from
Social Security and Medicare—the
gap between what we take in and
what we’ve promised to pay—is
now $88.2 trillion. That’s six times
the nation’s GDP.
The potent combination of
lower birthrates, higher medical
costs and longer life expectancies
provides little reason for thinking
the situation will improve.
We can break down the
$88.2 trillion into its four primary
components (Chart 7). The funding gap for Social Security, which
President Bush and Congress have
been wrestling with the past few
years, represents the smallest part
of the problem. The unfunded liability for Medicare Part D alone —

EconomicLetter 

Fede ral Reserve Bank of Dall as

the drug benefit that took effect in
January 2006 — is greater than the
entire Social Security shortfall.
Just how big is this unfunded
liability on a per-person basis?
Dividing the $88.2 trillion evenly
among the 300 million people who
live in the United States produces
a per-person liability of about
$290,000—more than five times
the average household’s annual
income. That’s what each U.S.
resident would have to pay today
to guarantee the solvency of Social
Security and Medicare for future
generations.
This is obviously not going to
happen. Suppose we don’t act now
to reduce the shortfall but instead
use general government revenue to
pay all promised benefits. Just how
much of a burden would this pose
for future taxpayers? Social Security
and Medicare currently consume
about 4 percent of general revenue
(Chart 8). By 2030, we would need
to devote 34.2 percent of general
revenue to entitlements. By 2080,
the figure rises to 64.8 percent.

Chart 7

Medicare Dominates
Unfunded Liabilities
Trillions of dollars
90

88.2

75

Medicare D
17.1

60

Medicare B
27.7

45

30

Medicare A
29.8

15
Social Security
13.6
0

SOURCES: Social Security and Medicare Trustees
Reports.

As we grapple with avenues
through which fiscal incontinence
can be purged from the entitlement system, we must be ever
mindful that some of these avenues will be more harmful to the
economy than others.
Will policymakers rise to the
occasion or leave the nation to
face a future in which global output growth slows, pressure mounts
to monetize the federal debt and
younger generations inherit an unconscionable shortfall?
Which path will we take?

Chart 8

Entitlements Expected to Consume More of U.S. Revenue
Revenue share
70
60

Total
Medicare

50
40
30
20

Social Security
10

Saving is a senior economist in the Research
Department of the Federal Reserve Bank of
Dallas.

0
–10
2006

2010

2020

2030

2040

2050

2060

2070

2080

Notes

SOURCES: Fiscal year 2008 budget, Office of Management and Budget; Social Security and Medicare Trustees Reports;
Private Enterprise Research Center; author’s calculations.

1

“U.S. Fiscal Policies and Priorities for Long-

Run Sustainability,” International Monetary Fund
paper, January 2004; and “Long-Term Fiscal

Every other government function—
from defense to environmental
protection and education — would
have to shrink dramatically to fit
into the remainder.
A drastic, across-the-board
reordering of government priorities
doesn’t seem likely. To the extent
people think about the unfunded
liabilities at all, they assume we
will eventually address the issue
by spending less or raising new
revenue. After all, that’s how any
one of us would resolve a shortfall
in our personal finances. But either
approach is likely to reduce the
economy’s growth rate.
The government has an additional resource unavailable to
ordinary citizens: the Bureau of
Engraving and Printing. And as
policymakers debate the huge
spending cuts or tax increases
that will be needed to restore the
solvency of the entitlement system,
can we be sure they won’t come to
view inflation as the least painful
alternative?
Any long-term solution to the
entitlement quandary will require

dramatic action, and the necessary
response will be ever more drastic
the longer it’s postponed.
If past is prologue, policymakers will forgo the opportunity to
fundamentally reshape the U.S.
entitlement system and will instead
adjust the parameters of the current system, as the Greenspan
Commission did in 1983.6 Likely
proposals are a higher retirement
age, a lower cost-of-living adjustment and a more progressive payroll tax that could include elimination of the earnings cap.
While any of these measures
would begin to address the unfunded liability issue, they have
very different implications for future economic growth. For example, a higher retirement age would
be expected to boost labor-force
participation and thereby raise
GDP growth. This has occurred in
Europe over the past few years.
However, some studies suggest
that more progressive payroll taxes
would reduce labor-force participation and thereby lower GDP
growth.

Fede ral Reserve Bank of Dall as

Challenges Facing the United States,” testimony
by Ben S. Bernanke before the Committee on the
Budget, U.S. Senate, January 18, 2007.
2

See, for example, “The Budget and Economic

Outlook: Fiscal Years 2004 – 2013,” Appendix A,
Congressional Budget Office, January 2003.
3

“The Looming Challenge of the Alternative

Minimum Tax,” by Alan D. Viard, Federal Reserve
Bank of Dallas Economic Letter, August 2006;
and “The Individual Alternative Minimum Tax:
Historical Data and Projections,” by Greg
Leiserson and Jeffrey Rohaly, Urban–Brookings
Tax Policy Center, November 2006.
4

“The Individual Alternative Minimum Tax: 11 Key

Facts and Projections,” by Len Burman, Julianna
Koch and Greg Leiserson, Urban–Brookings Tax
Policy Center, December 1, 2006.
5

“A Dynamic Analysis of Permanent Extension of

the President’s Tax Relief,” Office of Tax Analysis,
U.S. Department of the Treasury, July 25, 2006.
The National Commission on Social Security

6

Reform, led by Alan Greenspan, proposed
reforms in 1983 to address looming shortterm financing problems. Among the
recommendations enacted by Congress were
increasing payroll taxes, adding employees to
the system, increasing the retirement age for full
benefits and taxing benefits.

 EconomicLetter

EconomicLetter

The Best of All Worlds
Federal Reserve Bank of Dallas
2006 Annual Report Essay

is published monthly
by the Federal Reserve Bank of Dallas. The views
expressed are those of the authors and should not be
attributed to the Federal Reserve Bank of Dallas or the
Federal Reserve System.
Articles may be reprinted on the condition that
the source is credited and a copy is provided to the
Research Department of the Federal Reserve Bank of
Dallas.
Economic Letter is available free of charge
by writing the Public Affairs Department, Federal
Reserve Bank of Dallas, P.O. Box 655906, Dallas, TX
75265-5906; by fax at 214-922-5268; or by telephone
at 214-922-5254. This publication is available on the
Dallas Fed web site, www.dallasfed.org.

Richard W. Fisher
President and Chief Executive Officer
Helen E. Holcomb
First Vice President and Chief Operating Officer
Harvey Rosenblum
Executive Vice President and Director of Research
W. Michael Cox
Senior Vice President and Chief Economist
Robert D. Hankins
Senior Vice President, Banking Supervision
Executive Editor
W. Michael Cox

Read how globalization and the knowledge
economy are boosting productivity, lowering costs,
raising living standards and transforming nations.
To receive your free copy,
call 214-922-5254 or visit

www.dallasfed.org

Editor
Richard Alm
Associate Editor
Kathy Thacker
Graphic Designer
Ellah Piña

Federal Reserve Bank of Dallas
2200 N. Pearl St.
Dallas, TX 75201