View original document

The full text on this page is automatically extracted from the file linked above and may contain errors and inconsistencies.

Vol. 3, No. 10
October 2008­­

EconomicLetter
Insights from the

Federal Reserve Bank of Dall as

Fed Intervention:
Managing Moral Hazard in Financial Crises
by Harvey Rosenblum, Danielle DiMartino,
Jessica J. Renier and Richard Alm

Editor’s note:
Federal agencies
and regulators have
taken decisive steps
to combat the
financial crisis that
began in the
summer of 2007
and continued into
the fall of this year.
This Economic
Letter focuses on key
Federal Reserve
actions through
early October.

At the end of September 2008, U.S. policymakers had been working
for more than a year to contain the shock waves from plunging home prices
and the subsequent financial market turmoil. For the Federal Reserve, the
crisis has given new meaning to the adage that extraordinary times call for extraordinary measures. The central bank has dusted off Depression-era powers
and rewritten old rules to address serious risks to the global financial system.
The spreading financial crisis has led the Fed to pump liquidity
into the economy and expand its lending beyond the commercial banking
sector. In March, it assisted with J.P. Morgan Chase’s buyout of Bear Stearns, a
cash-strapped investment bank and brokerage. Six months later, the Fed took
direct action again, with an $85 billion bridge loan to prevent the disorderly

Concern about moral
hazard helps explain why
the Fed has traditionally
intervened only rarely and
reluctantly, trying to do
what’s necessary, but as
little as necessary, to achieve
financial stability.

failure of American International
Group (AIG), a giant global company
heavily involved in insuring against
debt defaults.1
These Fed actions—part of a
broader U.S. government effort to contain the financial crisis—call to mind
two earlier financial interventions: in the
case of Long-Term Capital Management
(LTCM) in 1998 and in the aftermath of
the Sept. 11, 2001, terrorist attacks.
In both episodes, the Fed felt
compelled to protect the financial system from severe shocks and the overall economy from spillovers that might
produce serious downturns. Inherent
in the Fed’s moves was a natural byproduct of intervention—moral hazard
and the controversy that flows from it.
Concern about moral hazard helps
explain why the Fed has traditionally
intervened only rarely and reluctantly,
trying to do what’s necessary, but as
little as necessary, to achieve financial
stability. Markets generally should and
do self-correct. When potential financial problems arise, the Fed’s default
reaction has usually been to do nothing and let the markets work their way
through the difficulties.
On rare occasions, however, the
markets themselves are at risk of failure. In such cases, the Fed can’t fulfill
its obligation to promote financial stability without direct action. Two factors
have strengthened the case for central
bank intervention in the past decade—
the financial system’s increased globalization and the untested nature of the
new and complex financial instruments
that have come under stress.
The escalation of what’s now recognized as a global financial crisis has
changed the modus operandi of Fed
interventions. The guiding principle of
do what is necessary, but as little as
necessary, has been replaced by the
recognition—reinforced by actions—of
the importance of doing whatever it
takes to break the downward spiral in
the financial and credit markets that
has contaminated the overall economy.
With a broad understanding of the
consequences of inaction, the Fed has

EconomicLetter 2

F edera l Re serve Bank of Dall as

taken a hard turn toward intervention
in an atmosphere in which fear of
moral hazard has been displaced by
the reality of systemic risk’s unacceptable consequences.
Fed intervention helped defuse
threats to the financial system from
LTCM’s failure and the 9/11 terrorist attacks. The central bank accepted
the moral hazard from intervention as
the price for avoiding larger financial
breakdowns. In the current crisis, the
Fed’s actions have no doubt mitigated
damage to the financial system and
economy. Doing so, however, required
developing new tactics to address the
crisis, going far beyond the traditional
instruments of monetary policy.
Intervention’s By-Product
Moral hazard, a term first used
by the insurance industry, captures the
unfortunate paradox of efforts to mitigate the adverse consequences of risk:
They may encourage the very behaviors they’re intended to prevent. For
example, individuals insured against
automobile theft may be less vigilant
about locking their cars because losses
due to carelessness are partly borne by
the insurance company.
Moral hazard occurs whenever an
institution like the Fed cushions the
adverse impact of events. More to the
point, lessening the consequences of
risky financial behavior encourages
greater carelessness about risk down
the road as investors come to count on
benign intervention. Moral hazard must
be weighed carefully in responding to
financial crises.
In the cases of Bear Stearns and
AIG, some argue that the greater good
would have been served had the Fed
stood back and allowed the firms to
fail, immediately taking all management, shareholders and creditors down
with them. This course would avoid
moral hazard entirely—and satisfy the
general public’s desire for seeing Wall
Street highfliers brought low.
The Fed, however, must be ever
vigilant in its mission. The Federal
Reserve Act explicitly and implicitly

sets out several mandates to guide Fed
actions. The most important are
• Full employment and sustain-		
able economic growth;
• Price stability;
• Banking and financial system
stability.
By intervening in a financial crisis,
the Fed doesn’t allow markets to play
their natural role of judge, jury and
executioner. This raises the specter
of setting a dangerous precedent that
could prompt private-sector entities to
take additional risk, assuming the Fed
will cushion the impact of reckless
decisionmaking. So when intervention
is the only option, the Fed has the
duty to minimize micro moral hazard—that is, the benefit to any specific
firm or industry.
Minimizing micro moral hazard
starts with imposing tough terms—generally the orderly closure of the troubled firms that benefit from intervention. The Fed didn’t just shovel money
at Bear Stearns’ and AIG’s problems.
It demanded collateral for the loans
and charged interest—in AIG’s case, at
high rates.
Minimizing micro moral hazard
means keeping information about the
targets, timing and terms of any potential intervention as vague as possible,
a tactic sometimes called “constructive
ambiguity.”
Minimizing micro moral hazard
also means aiding selected firms only
as a last resort. Federal authorities
found alternative solutions short of
direct intervention for some financial
giants. The Fed expedited the reclassification of investment banks Goldman
Sachs and Morgan Stanley to bank
holding companies. Private-sector buyers acquired Merrill Lynch, Washington
Mutual and Wachovia.
When direct intervention does
take place, the Fed’s duty goes beyond
minimizing micro moral hazard. The
central bank has the equally important
responsibility to maximize macro moral
hazard—a somewhat counterintuitive
term that captures the greater good
of preventing unnecessary damage to

financial markets and the economy.2
Maximizing macro moral hazard recognizes the Fed’s obligation
to reduce the risks of recession and
price instability and the risks stemming
from an unstable banking and financial system. By fostering a more stable
macroeconomic environment, the Fed’s
policy actions reduce the private sector’s pain from bad decisionmaking.
The outright, uncontrolled collapse of Bear Stearns or AIG could
have harmed millions of households
and companies as financial market
troubles brutalized retirement accounts,
paralyzed the flow of capital, and
ultimately led to layoffs, stunted consumption and a severe recession. The
goal of Fed intervention is to prevent,
or at least forestall, such macroeconomic spillovers.3
Hedge Fund on the Edge
Long-Term Capital Management
provides an apt starting point for a
discussion of Fed intervention because
it involved the first financial disruption
after the rapid expansion of the shadow
banking system, a shorthand term for
the financial services segment that
includes big brokerage firms, hedge
funds and innovative financial products
like structured investment vehicles.4
These entities aren’t subject to the same
supervision as banks, so they don’t
hold as much capital to cushion themselves against losses.
A high-profile hedge fund founded
in 1993, LTCM brought together the
best minds of academia and Wall Street.
John W. Meriwether, former manager of
one of Salomon Brothers’ most profitable bond divisions, recruited renowned
Ph.D.’s such as Myron Scholes and
Robert Merton, soon-to-be winners of
the 1997 Nobel Prize in economics,
and former Fed Vice Chairman David
Mullins. The partners’ aim was to profit
from market-price anomalies using complex mathematical models.
At its peak, the fund earned
stunning returns of more than 40 percent. In 1997, as increased competition began squeezing margins, LTCM

F ederal Reserve Bank of Dall as

When intervention is the only
option, the Fed has the duty
to minimize micro moral
hazard—that is, the
benefit to any specific firm
or industry.

3 EconomicLetter

The threat of systemic risk
led the Fed to help arrange
a managed unwinding of
LTCM’s affairs, which would
let the fund fail and avoid a
fire sale of its assets.

reached for high returns by leveraging its capital through risky securities
repurchase contracts and derivatives
transactions. By some accounts, the
fund used capital of $2.3 billion to
support investments of $125 billion.
The first sign that LTCM might
be in trouble came when the fund
lost 10 percent on its investments in
June 1998. The situation worsened in
mid-August, when a deep decline in
oil prices left the economies of Russia
and other oil-exporting countries in a
precarious state. Russia’s debt default
and devaluation of the ruble prompted
a massive flight of investors from risky
securities to U.S. Treasuries and a dramatic widening in interest rate spreads.
Global bond markets plunged,
and in August alone, LTCM lost $1.8
billion—44 percent of its capital.
Losses piled upon losses and reached
$4.8 billion. As LTCM faced increasing
margin calls, default was imminent.
The speed with which LTCM spiraled out of control recalls an old saying in financial circles: If I owe a bank
a million dollars and I can’t pay, I’m in
trouble. If I owe a bank a billion dollars and I can’t pay, the bank’s in trouble. If I owe a dozen banks billions of
dollars each and I can’t pay, the banking system could be in trouble.
The threat of systemic risk led
the Fed to help arrange a managed
unwinding of LTCM’s affairs, which
would let the fund fail and avoid a
fire sale of its assets. On Sept. 23, the
New York Fed facilitated a meeting
with top executives from 14 Wall Street
and international banking firms. With
the exception of Bear Stearns, which
declined to participate, the financial
institutions agreed to back a capital
infusion of $3.5 billion. The deal transferred oversight and veto power and a
90 percent equity stake to the consortium, leaving a 10 percent stake for the
LTCM partners as an incentive to close
down operations in an orderly fashion.5
In his Oct. 1, 1998, congressional testimony, Fed Chairman Alan
Greenspan explained why the Fed
decided to intervene: “Had the failure

EconomicLetter 4

F edera l Re serve Bank of Dall as

of LTCM triggered the seizing up of
markets, substantial damage could
have been inflicted on many market participants, including some not
directly involved with the firm, and
could have potentially impaired the
economies of many nations, including
our own.”
The Fed’s action helped contain
possible spillovers, but it didn’t preserve LTCM. The hedge fund failed,
but in a way that minimized the
impact on financial markets and the
economy—at the cost of both micro
and macro moral hazard.
Financial Crisis Averted
On Sept. 11, 2001, terrorists
hijacked four planes, crashed two into
New York’s World Trade Center, a
third into the Pentagon and a fourth
in a field in Pennsylvania. The nation
watched in horror as both WTC towers
collapsed. The financial system wasn’t
the target per se, but it was thrown
into disarray. The most direct impact
was the closure of U.S. financial markets for four days—only the seventh
time they’d shut down for such a long
stretch. A secondary impact came from
the closure of U.S. airspace, which
stopped the movement of mail and
checks around the country.
Exacerbating the situation was
the backdrop against which the events
occurred. The U.S. economy was
in the sixth month of a recession,
although this wasn’t widely recognized at the time, not even within the
Fed. And financial markets were skittish, mired in the biggest bear market
since the Great Depression. By early
September, the Standard & Poor’s 500
Index was down 29 percent from its
March 2000 peak and the Nasdaq had
lost 67 percent of its value.
Immediately after the attacks, the
S&P 500 futures declined precipitously,
and chaos reigned on the streets near
the New York Fed, the New York
Stock Exchange and elsewhere in the
financial district—all within blocks of
the fallen towers. It became apparent
that U.S. financial markets couldn’t

open. At 10 a.m., 74 minutes after the
first plane hit the World Trade Center
and 30 minutes after the stock market’s
scheduled opening, the Fed released
a statement: “The Federal Reserve
System is open and operating. The
discount window is available to meet
liquidity needs.”
Though the financial markets
would remain closed for the rest of the
week, the Fed did indeed remain open.
In the days after the terrorists struck:6
• The discount window lent $45.5
billion on Sept. 12, compared
with the Wednesday average of
$59 million the previous two 		
months.
• Check float jumped to $22.9 		
billion that day, well above 		
the two-month average of $720
million.
• The New York Fed used open
market operations to inject $61
billion in liquidity into the economy on Sept. 12, then added 		
another $38 billion on Sept. 19.
• The Fed arranged foreign 		
exchange swap lines with the
European Central Bank, the 		
Bank of England and the Bank
of Canada to provide dollar 		
liquidity to global markets.
When the markets reopened
Sept. 17, the Federal Open Market
Committee (FOMC) held an emergency
conference call and cut the fed funds
rate, which applies to banks’ shortterm borrowing from one another,
from 3.5 percent to 3 percent. As
other short-term rates fell in response
to the Fed’s move, many businesses
and individuals saw their borrowing
costs decline. The statement the Fed
released in announcing its action reiterated the central bank’s commitment
to providing liquidity and keeping the
fed funds rate below target, as needed.
Although the Dow Jones industrials suffered what was, until the current crisis, its worst one-day point loss
on Sept. 17, panic was averted.7 The
payments system returned to normal
within days, and the recession ended
two months later.

In the wake of 9/11, the Fed cast
a wide and deep safety net to prevent the systemic risk that could have
resulted from a meltdown of the financial system spreading to the U.S. and
other economies around the globe.
Despite the obvious need for intervention, the Fed’s actions entailed some
degree of moral hazard.
The Current Crisis
Signs of trouble began surfacing
in February 2007, when a handful of
financial companies took losses on
assets related to U.S. subprime mortgages. What would become the worst
financial crisis since the Depression
wasn’t widely acknowledged for six
more months—not by financial markets, not by policymakers.8
Since then, banks, brokerages,
investment houses and hedge funds
worldwide have revealed a seemingly
endless succession of losses, writedowns and outright failures. Behind
the crisis is the collapse of a five-year
boom in housing prices that had been
fueled by risky and exotic mortgage
financing backed by unprecedented
levels of leverage.
Some subprime loans offered
low initial interest rates; others only
required interest payments, needed no
down payment or were made with no
proof of income. The mortgages were
bundled into multilayered securities
graded by risk, then sold to hedge
funds, investment banks, insurance
companies and other investors, many
of which sought to reduce risks associated with the mortgages by purchasing
credit default swaps (CDS).
A relatively new entry in the
financial derivatives market, these
instruments committed one party to
cover its counterparty’s losses should
an investment go sour. In 2000, the
CDS market was $1 trillion; by 2008,
it was $62 trillion, roughly 4.5 times
U.S. gross domestic product. These
derivatives helped fuel the surge in
mortgage-backed securities by reducing perceived default risk.
When the housing bubble burst,

F ederal Reserve Bank of Dall as

In the wake of 9/11, the Fed
cast a wide and deep safety
net to prevent the systemic
risk that could have resulted
from a meltdown of the
financial system spreading
to the U.S. and other
economies around the globe.

5 EconomicLetter

default risk far exceeded what investors had anticipated, and the market
for mortgage-backed securities cratered. Financial institutions found
themselves holding large portfolios of
hard-to-value assets that could only be
sold at fire-sale prices.
As assets deteriorated, we began
to hear a lot about counterparty risk.
What if CDS sellers couldn’t fulfill their
obligation to insure assets against losses? If a major player in the vast, tangled credit derivatives market were to
collapse, it could start a chain reaction
in which one counterparty’s default

undermines the ability of other firms to
fulfill their obligations. Markets would
begin doubting the counterparties, and
investors would flee these companies,
leaving them to face the grim task of
attracting new capital in skeptical markets. If they can’t, they sink into trouble. A significant number of troubled
firms would trigger systemic risk.
Credit default swaps and other
financial innovations hadn’t been tested under adverse conditions. What’s
more, they took off at a time when
markets and the economy had become
more globalized and technology-driv-

Minimizing Micro Moral Hazard: The Fed Rarely Intervenes

No

Take no action
• Customary response
• No moral hazard

Potential
Financial
Crisis

Assess economic
and financial conditions
• Initial conditions matter

• Markets self-correct

Threat to Fed’s goals?
• Full employment/sustainable
economic growth
• Price stability
• Banking/financial system
stability

Yes

Manage moral hazard
in least costly way
• Rare response
• Contain the problem
• Support the financial system
• Intervention targets ultimately
fail, but in orderly way

This decision tree summarizes how the Fed
responds to potential financial crises. After getting a

strives to manage the resulting moral hazard in the

bled investment bank and brokerage with sufficient

least costly way.

remaining collateral to support the intervention.

reading on the economy’s vital signs, the Fed deter-

The first choice entails the Fed’s acting as an out-

When private partners aren’t willing to step up, the

mines whether the threat at hand might compromise

side coordinator to bring together private institutions

Fed can act alone if troubled firms still have sufficient

the central bank’s three primary goals.

to defuse the threat. It’s a strategy that minimizes

collateral. In September 2008, the Fed arranged a

If the Fed sees little risk, no action is taken, avoid-

public-sector risk, and the central bank used it with the

purely public intervention for AIG, a huge financial

ing moral hazard and leaving the markets to sort out

Long-Term Capital Management hedge fund in 1998.

services company.

the difficulties. The Fed reacts this way to nearly all

When this option isn’t feasible, the Federal Reserve

If remaining collateral is insufficient to support

Act provides the authority to deal directly with press-

taxpayer-financed actions, the Fed under current law

potential troubles in the financial sector.
A pervasive threat to the overall economy or the

ing threats. The preferred strategy involves forging

is obliged to let the markets decide a troubled firm’s

financial system can justify direct action. The Fed

partnerships with private institutions, a course the

fate. The Fed accepted this outcome with Lehman

rarely makes these interventions; when it does, it

Fed took in March 2008 with Bear Stearns, a trou-

Brothers in 2008.

EconomicLetter 6

F edera l Re serve Bank of Dall as

en, factors that both made the financial
universe more complex and increased
uncertainty about how to respond to
potentially widespread failures of these
new instruments.
The Fed didn’t sit idly by as tremors shook the financial markets. As
with the 9/11 threat, its initial response
focused on injecting liquidity into the
financial system. On Aug. 17, 2007,
the Federal Reserve Board cut a half
percentage point off the discount rate,
making it cheaper for commercial
banks to borrow short-term funds from
the Fed. On Sept. 18, the FOMC sur-

prised financial markets by reducing
the fed funds rate to 4.75 percent. The
Board also cut the discount rate a half
point. Over the next year, the FOMC
cut the fed funds rate eight more
times, dropping it to 1 percent at the
end of October.9 The Board gradually
reduced the discount rate from 5.75
percent on Sept. 18, 2007, to 1.25 percent on Oct. 29, 2008.
Unlike the Long-Term Capital
Management and 9/11 episodes, which
resolved themselves quickly, the latest
financial turmoil continued to bubble
throughout 2008, leading the Fed to

Target Firm Fails
100% private-sector
solution possible

Public–private hybrid
• Example: Bear Stearns

• Example: LTCM

Sufficient collateral
available
• Invoke Federal Reserve Act

100% private-sector
solution not possible

• Minimize public-sector risk

Government control/
ownership

Insufficient collateral
available

Firm declares
bankruptcy

• Fed and Treasury legally

• No moral hazard

§ 13.3

constrained

• Example: AIG

• Market solution
• Example: Lehman Brothers

F ederal Reserve Bank of Dall as

7 EconomicLetter

The central bank opened its
lending operations to
different kinds of financial
institutions, granted longerterm loans and accepted a
broader range of collateral.

take unorthodox steps to make money
available to the financial system. The
central bank opened its lending operations to different kinds of financial institutions, granted longer-term loans and
accepted a broader range of collateral.
In December 2007, the Fed introduced the first of several new lending
mechanisms—the term auction facility,
which lends to banks for longer periods and usually at a lower rate than
they could secure via the discount
window. Part of the reasoning behind
the new facility was to avoid the perception that discount window borrowing is a sign of financial weakness.
A stickier issue was capital constraints at primary dealers, a class of
lenders not regulated by the Fed and
without access to its credit facilities.
(See box titled “Primary Dealers’ Critical
Role.”) The term securities lending
facility, established in March 2008, provides extra liquidity through a 28-day
program that allows, for a fee, primary
dealers to acquire Treasury-grade assets
by using riskier assets as collateral.
The primary dealer credit facility, also created in March, extends the
Fed’s safety net by opening discount
window loans to primary dealers.
As the financial crisis deepened, the
Fed created lending programs to add
liquidity to other segments of the
financial markets. In September, for
example, the central bank made money available to foreign central banks,
commercial paper investors and money
market funds.
No lending facility could effectively address the kind of crisis of
confidence that befell Bear Stearns, an
investment bank and brokerage that
had been a Wall Street fixture since
1923, surviving even the stock market crash of 1929 without laying off
employees.
On Monday, March 10, 2008,
rumors hit European trading floors
that Bear Stearns might be unable to
fulfill commitments for its trades. The
company’s management was quick to
address the reports but couldn’t quash
the mounting speculation. The rumors

EconomicLetter 8

F edera l Re serve Bank of Dall as

became self-reinforcing, compelling
some trading partners to pull back
from doing business with Bear Stearns.
A de facto run had begun.
On Thursday, Bear Stearns’ CEO
reached out to the New York Fed
and the Treasury Department, setting
into motion a whirlwind that would
bring an end to an institution that had
accumulated $1.6 billion in losses and
write-downs. Two days later, a firm
that had a peak market value of $25
billion in January 2007 was offered to
J.P. Morgan Chase for $236 million, a
mere 3 cents on the dollar.
When Bear Stearns sought help,
the New York Fed could have done
what the Fed usually does when a ship
is at risk of sinking on its watch: nothing. Bear Stearns would have been
allowed to fail, and the Fed would have
stood witness to a company reaping
what its missteps had sown. The tale
would have been tragic in the same
vein as the fates suffered by Drexel
Burnham Lambert, the Wall Street
brokerage that fell victim to the junk
bond bust of the 1980s, and Enron, the
energy giant that toppled in 2001.
The Fed did nothing for Drexel or
Enron. However, it supported the J.P.
Morgan deal with an unprecedented
$29 billion loan to an entity created to
purchase largely mortgage-related Bear
Stearns assets. The agreement calls for
the loan, made at the discount rate
for up to 10 years, to be repaid as the
assets are sold. If they appreciate by
more than operating expenses, the Fed
stands to make a profit. It will bear any
losses beyond the $1.15 billion contributed to the entity by J.P. Morgan.
The Fed decided to facilitate the
Bear Stearns sale because it feared dire
consequences for the financial system.
Bear Stearns had open trades with no
fewer than 5,000 other firms. On a
much grander scale, the firm was one
of the world’s largest counterparties,
reporting in a Nov. 30, 2007, Securities
and Exchange Commission filing that
its derivative holdings had total leverage of $13.4 billion. The company
was involved in 750,000 contracts in

March 2008, according to the New
York Fed. Allowing the company to
default would have triggered the first
stress test of the fast-growing, interwoven derivatives market, an event that
would undermine the Fed’s ability to
meet its legal mandates for growth,
price stability and financial stability.
The Fed actions were aimed at
reducing risks to the financial system,
not helping Bear Stearns’ owners.
The company’s stock price peaked
above $171 a share in January 2007,
representing a market capitalization of
some $25 billion. Despite the financial
turmoil of early 2008, it was at $70 a
share just before the ill-fated week of
March 10–17. It’s difficult to fathom
how much more the Fed could have
adhered to its commitment to minimize
micro moral hazard, considering the
$2 a share price reached during the
negotiations. To keep Bear Stearns
out of bankruptcy court, J.P. Morgan
Chase eventually raised its offer to
$10 a share, or $1.4 billion, still a faint
shadow of where the market had valued Bear a year earlier.
The authority to intervene in
Bear Stearns can be found in a 1932
amendment to the Federal Reserve
Act, allowing the central bank to make
direct loans outside the banking system “in unusual and exigent circumstances.” The power was last used in
the Great Depression.10
The Fed used this authority again
when AIG appeared on the brink. The
company’s sound businesses were
being threatened by the excessive CDS
risks taken by its London-based AIG
Financial Products unit. After a year in
which AIG took $18 billion in losses,
the company faced a cash crunch after
mid-September downgrades to its credit rating. It needed a $13 billion capital
infusion in a week in which investors
showed their lack of confidence in the
company by driving down its stock
price 80 percent.
When AIG couldn’t raise money
in the private sector, it turned to the
Fed and the Treasury. The central
bank provided a two-year, $85 billion

Primary Dealers’ Critical Role
Primary dealers are banks and securities broker-dealers that trade in U.S. government
securities with the Federal Reserve Bank of New York. They’re vital to monetary policy because
the New York Fed’s Open Market Desk trades on behalf of the Federal Reserve System.
Purchasing government securities in the secondary market adds reserves to the banking
system; selling securities drains them.
The New York Fed established the system in 1960 with 18 primary dealers. The number
peaked at 46 in 1988 before starting to decline in the mid-1990s. By 2007, it was down to 20.
The main reason for the dwindling number of dealers has been consolidation, as firms have
merged or refocused their core lines of business. (A list of primary dealers can be found on the
New York Fed’s website at www.newyorkfed.org/aboutthefed/fedpoint/fed02.html.)
In addition to their role in monetary policy, primary dealers are important in keeping the
nation’s fiscal house in order. The federal government tends to spend more each year than
it takes in from tax revenue. To keep Washington open and operating, and the government
functioning around the world, the Treasury raises money by selling bills, notes and bonds to
investors. In recent years, more than half the money raised has come from foreigners.
Primary dealers handle the bulk of the underwriting—that is, the buying, handling and
distribution of the U.S. debt. In addition to distributing new Treasury securities, the dealer
network makes a deep, broad and liquid secondary market for previously issued Treasury
securities.
A liquid secondary market enhances the marketability of Treasury debt and lessens the
burden of financing government operations for taxpayers. Without this network of dealers, the
Treasury would be hard-pressed to reliably finance essential government services.
An efficient primary dealer network is important for other reasons. Nearly all debt is
priced off of interest rates on similar maturity Treasury securities. The Treasury rate is the
so-called risk-free rate in the economy. Private-sector borrowers pay the risk-free rate, plus a
premium to compensate for potential default risk.
The U.S. and global financial systems, not to mention the U.S. economy and its millions
of businesses and households, are absolutely dependent upon a smoothly functioning and
reliable Treasury market for financing their credit needs. If the Treasury market is closed or not
working properly because of problems with the primary dealer network, credit can’t be priced
and can’t flow, leaving the private sector starved for credit.
With the primary dealers’ pivotal role in mind, on March 16 the Federal Reserve Board
invoked the emergency provisions of the Federal Reserve Act, authorizing the New York Fed
to extend the discount window’s safety net to primary dealers. In its announcement, the Fed
said it created the primary dealer credit facility to “bolster market liquidity and promote orderly
market functioning.” The action left no doubt about primary dealers’ important role: “Liquid,
well-functioning markets are essential for the promotion of economic growth.”

line of credit, secured by warrants,
to purchase nearly 80 percent of the
company if AIG fails to raise enough
money through asset sales or other
means to repay the loan. The Sept. 16
agreement’s interest rate was steep—
indeed, punitive—at 8.5 percent above
the London interbank offered rate
(Libor), an industry benchmark.11

F ederal Reserve Bank of Dall as

9 EconomicLetter

Interestingly, some critics
who chastised the Fed for
creating moral hazard with
Bear Stearns declared that
moral hazard should have
been disregarded in the case
of Lehman.

Like Bear Stearns, AIG had invested heavily in CDS markets. At the
end of September 2007, its Financial
Products unit had $505 billion in exposure, stretching into many parts of the
world. A year later, AIG had written
down a fifth of its exposure but still
stood on the precipice. In announcing
its decision on Sept. 16, the Fed said
it saw enough risk to conclude that “a
disorderly failure of AIG could add to
already significant levels of financial
market fragility and lead to substantially higher borrowing costs, reduced
household wealth and materially weaker economic performance.”
Many critics contend that Bear
Stearns and AIG were “bailed out.”
Former Treasury Secretary Paul O’Neill
refuted this notion in a New York
Times exchange on Bear Stearns:12
Times: Do you think it was
appropriate for the Federal Reserve to
lend a helping hand to Bear Stearns
and save a private investment company from its own bad decisions?
O’Neill: I would say they didn’t
save Bear Stearns. They saved the
financial system from a panic collapse.
I reject the notion they helped Bear
Stearns. Bear Stearns was destroyed.
[Emphasis added]
Times: No it wasn’t. It was purchased by J.P. Morgan, which will
keep it alive.
O’Neill: They’re going to keep
the book alive. But the institution
of Bear Stearns has been destroyed.
They’ve gone from $158 to $2 of equity. It’s wallpaper. It’s not even good
wallpaper. It’s butcher paper.
The Lehman Decision
Roughly six months after the Bear
Stearns intervention and amid AIG’s
unraveling, another Wall Street investment bank and primary dealer found
itself on the brink. Round-the-clock
efforts by the Fed and Treasury to find
a buyer for Lehman Brothers Holdings
over the weekend of Sept. 13–14 fell
apart. On Monday, Lehman became the
largest bankruptcy in U.S. history, listing liabilities of $613 billion in its filing.

EconomicLetter 10

F edera l Re serve Bank of Dall as

The impact—both predictable and
unpredictable—of Lehman’s failure
reverberated immediately through global financial markets. The fallout spread
to individuals and businesses with
seemingly no connection to Lehman.
In the LTCM and Bear Stearns
interventions, the Fed contended its
actions were necessary to keep financial markets from seizing up and to
minimize the negative spillovers on the
broad economy. The Fed feared that
the quick and disorderly failures of
some financial enterprises would have
systemic effects on the nation and
likely, around the globe.
In April 3, 2008, testimony to
Congress about the Fed’s intervention in
Bear Stearns, New York Fed President
Timothy Geithner described the adverse
consequence the Fed sought to avoid:
“Asset price declines … led to a reduction in the willingness to bear risk
and to margin calls … [resulting in] a
self-reinforcing downward spiral of …
forced sales, lower prices, higher volatility and still lower prices.”
Geithner cataloged the possible
spillover effects from Bear Stearns’ collapse—protracted damage to the financial system, widespread insolvencies
and ultimately higher unemployment
and borrowing costs, and a lower
standard of living because of losses to
retirement savings.
Why didn’t similar arguments persuade the Fed to prevent the collapse
of Lehman, an investment bank and
primary dealer comparable to Bear
Stearns in size and importance? The
answer, according to Fed Chairman
Ben Bernanke and Treasury Secretary
Henry Paulson, came down to untenable taxpayer losses and doubts about
the legal authority to intervene in this
particular case.
A few weeks after Lehman’s bankruptcy, Bernanke addressed the issue:
“Facilitating the sale of Lehman …
would have required a very sizeable
injection of public funds … and would
have involved the assumption by taxpayers of billions of dollars of expected losses…. Neither the Treasury nor

the Federal Reserve had the authority
to commit public money in that way;
in particular, the Federal Reserve’s
loans must be sufficiently secured to
provide reasonable assurance that the
loan will be fully repaid. Such collateral was not available in this case.”13
Lehman had months to find
private buyers for all or parts of its
enterprise. None could be found, not
even with the help of the Fed and the
Treasury. And the firm’s condition had
deteriorated to the point where the
Fed couldn’t find sufficient collateral
for a primary dealer credit facility loan.
Within hours of Lehman’s bankruptcy filing, the negative consequences contemplated by Geithner in Bear
Stearns’ case began to unfold. Losses
tied to holdings of Lehman debt forced
one of the oldest money market funds
to sink below the purchase price of
$1 a share, financial markets seized
up, stock markets around the world
plunged, and governments were eventually forced to inject capital directly
into their banking systems and extend
deposit insurance safety nets.
In some ways, the Lehman episode was as close as possible to a
controlled experiment in the realm of
economics. By not intervening, the Fed
created no moral hazard. Interestingly,
some critics who chastised the Fed
for creating moral hazard with Bear
Stearns declared that moral hazard
should have been disregarded in the
case of Lehman.
Little will be gained by debating
the what-ifs surrounding Lehman. By
the time Lehman filed for bankruptcy,
the cost to insure the debt of other
investment banks had also skyrocketed.
A prohibitively expensive Lehman rescue would have merely forestalled one
failure, but many other at-risk investment banks would have remained as
the financial system buckled under
intense leverage. What Lehman
revealed was the need to give authorities better tools to manage the threats
to firms considered key to the nation’s
and the world’s financial infrastructure.14
What are the lessons of Lehman’s

demise? In particular, should moral
hazard be categorically and systematically avoided? With the interconnectedness of the global economic and
financial systems, it’s clear that fire
sales can spread to distant places and
impact economic entities far removed
from the initial calamity. It took the
collateral damage from Lehman’s bankruptcy for this to be widely appreciated by those who have invoked moral
hazard to argue against Fed interventions. Moral hazard has its costs, but it
also has its benefits.
The Fed’s Hippocratic Oath
A basic precept taught in medical schools is first, do no harm. All
interventions—whether they involve
medicine or finance—have potential
costs, benefits and unintended consequences. These are often difficult to
anticipate, especially in the financial
realm, where crises occur infrequently
and each differs from its predecessors
in important ways.
In keeping with the principle of
doing no harm, it is ideal to leave
markets to work their magic. When
the Fed does intervene, it tries to do
what’s necessary—but as little as necessary—to achieve financial stability.
This is as it should be.
Unfortunately, defining “as little as
necessary” is rarely easy. In turbulent
times, the challenge regulators face is
that maps charted during past crises are
all but irrelevant. Each crisis requires
judgment calls that must be executed
in real time, often using incomplete
and partly accurate information.
In the current financial crisis’ first
year, the Fed’s response has been
measured, reflecting the commitment
to doing only what’s necessary. The
central bank began with the hope that
the routine tools of monetary policy
would be sufficient to lessen the
danger to the markets and the economy. The Fed turned to unorthodox
solutions—the new lending facilities
and direct intervention—only when
faced with a deepening crisis. Direct
intervention has been rare, taken only

F ederal Reserve Bank of Dall as

Like it or not, central
bankers face the reality that
managing moral hazard
is an inescapable part of
their job description. Seeking
to minimize micro moral
hazard during tumultuous
times is as far as they
can go.

11 EconomicLetter

EconomicLetter

when stakes were high and other
options were exhausted.
Intervention in the financial markets in general, or in the affairs of a
single financial institution, remains a
red-button option, reserved solely for
tangible threats to the Fed’s primary
goals. The Fed prefers to rely on the
self-correcting mechanisms of market
forces. This discipline flows from a
guiding principle: No one entity is too
big to fail; only the financial system is
too big to fail. Some entities may be
so caught in the intricate weave of the
financial system that their problems
can’t be resolved quickly. Using this
metaphor, Bear Stearns and AIG were
single threads that, if pulled, could have
unraveled the entire financial system.
As ideal as it would be to
eliminate moral hazard, the Fed—the
central bank for the world’s largest
economy—can’t do that and fulfill its
legal mandates. Like it or not, central
bankers face the reality that managing
moral hazard is an inescapable part of
their job description. Seeking to minimize micro moral hazard during tumultuous times is as far as they can go.
Rosenblum is executive vice president and director of research, DiMartino is a financial analyst,
Renier is a research analyst and Alm is senior
economics writer in the Research Department at
the Federal Reserve Bank of Dallas.
Notes
1

The Fed has worked closely with the Treasury

Department to mitigate the financial crisis.

the “whole alphabet soup of levered up non-bank
investment conduits, vehicles, and structures.”
See “Teton Reflections,” Global Central Bank
Focus, August/September 2007.
5

Alan Greenspan, testimony before the House

Committee on Banking and Financial Services,
Oct. 1, 1998. One solution to the problem of socalled too-big-to-fail banks would be forced recapitalization by competitors. See “What Reforms
Are Needed to Improve the Safety and Soundness
of the Banking System?” by Harvey Rosenblum,
Federal Reserve Bank of Atlanta Economic Review,
First and Second Quarters, 2007.
6

“Taking Stock in America: Resiliency,

Redundancy and Recovery in the U.S. Economy,”
by W. Michael Cox and Richard Alm, Federal
Reserve Bank of Dallas 2001 Annual Report.
7

The Dow suffered its worst one-day point loss

on Sept. 29, 2008, when it lost 777.68 points.
8

For more on this, see “From Complacency to

Crisis: Financial Risk Taking in the Early 21st
Century,” by Danielle DiMartino, John V. Duca
and Harvey Rosenblum, Federal Reserve Bank of
Dallas Economic Letter, December 2007.
9

One of these cuts, made at the depth of the

crisis on Oct. 8, was unprecedented in that the
FOMC acted in coordination with five other central banks. The FOMC cut the fed funds rate by a
half point—from 2.25 percent to 1.75 percent.
10

“The History of a Powerful Paragraph,”

by David Fettig, Federal Reserve Bank of
Minneapolis The Region, June 2008.
11

The Fed and U.S. Treasury later modified the

terms of the government’s financial support for
AIG. The new terms included a lower interest
rate at 3 percent over Libor and reduced fees on
undrawn funds. They also included a lengthening

In early September, for example, Treasury

of the lending facility from two to five years.

took control of the Federal National Mortgage

12

“Market Leader,” New York Times Magazine,

Association and Federal Home Mortgage Corp.,

March 30, 2008.

two federally sponsored investors in the housing

13

sector.

Ben Bernanke speech to the National Association

2

For more on this subject, see “Fed Policy and

“Current Economic and Financial Conditions,”

for Business Economics 50th Annual Meeting,

Moral Hazard,” by Harvey Rosenblum, Wall

Washington, D.C., Oct. 7, 2008.

Street Journal, Oct. 18, 2007.

14

3

Timothy Geithner, testimony before the Senate

“Reducing Systemic Risk,” Ben Bernanke

City’s Annual Economic Symposium, Jackson

Affairs, April 3, 2008.

Hole, Wyo., Aug. 22, 2008.

See Geithner’s remarks in “Brokers Threatened

by Run on Shadow Bank System,” MarketWatch,
June 20, 2008. The term shadow banking system
was coined by Paul McCulley, who used it for

Richard W. Fisher
President and Chief Executive Officer
Helen E. Holcomb
First Vice President and Chief Operating Officer
Harvey Rosenblum
Executive Vice President and Director of Research
W. Michael Cox
Senior Vice President and Chief Economist
Robert D. Hankins
Senior Vice President, Banking Supervision
Executive Editor
W. Michael Cox
Editor
Richard Alm
Associate Editor
Monica Reeves
Graphic Designer
Gene Autry

speech at the Federal Reserve Bank of Kansas

Committee on Banking, Housing and Urban
4

is published monthly
by the Federal Reserve Bank of Dallas. The views
expressed are those of the authors and should not be
attributed to the Federal Reserve Bank of Dallas or the
Federal Reserve System.
Articles may be reprinted on the condition that
the source is credited and a copy is provided to the
Research Department of the Federal Reserve Bank of
Dallas.
Economic Letter is available free of charge
by writing the Public Affairs Department, Federal
Reserve Bank of Dallas, P.O. Box 655906, Dallas, TX
75265-5906; by fax at 214-922-5268; or by telephone
at 214-922-5254. This publication is available on the
Dallas Fed website, www.dallasfed.org.

Federal Reserve Bank of Dallas
2200 N. Pearl St.
Dallas, TX 75201