View original document

The full text on this page is automatically extracted from the file linked above and may contain errors and inconsistencies.

VOL. 12, NO. 6 • MAY 2017

DALLASFED

Economic
Letter
Corporate Tax Reform: Potential
Gains at a Price to Some
by Evan F. Koenig and Jason L. Saving

}

ABSTRACT: Corporate tax
reform has become a highprofile issue amid fears that
firms are increasingly taking
their headquarters and
production facilities offshore
and booking profits abroad.
Adjustments to the tax system
can help address these
factors, though not without
potentially introducing new
issues.

C

orporate tax reform has
recently attracted greater public
attention. Existing U.S. tax rates
are said to encourage tax avoidance and motivate firms to move overseas, reducing revenue and eliminating
opportunities for U.S. workers.
Moreover, some view the tax code as
discouraging saving and investment while
incentivizing firms to use debt rather than
equity financing, distorting resource allocation and slowing economic growth. The
corporate tax system is even said to put
the U.S. at a competitive disadvantage visà-vis the country’s major trading partners.
That the U.S. corporate rate is high is
undeniable. The U.S. rate of 39.1 percent
is easily the highest among developedworld competitors and almost double the
rate that prevails in the U.K. (Chart 1).
Such a rate provides an incentive for firms
to locate elsewhere.
It’s true that many firms pay a lower
rate because of exemptions, deductions
and loopholes (Chart 2). However, the
tax-avoidance strategies necessary to do
so consume resources that could be used
more efficiently elsewhere while penalizing firms that don’t or can’t use these
tactics.
Some issues with the U.S. corporate
tax system could be addressed with relatively simple changes. To raise the return

on saving, a firm’s capital investments,
for example, could be depreciated over a
shorter period (or fully expensed in the
first year). Interest deductibility could be
limited (or even eliminated) to place debt
and equity financing on a more level playing field. And, of course, the corporate
tax rate could be lowered, though this
would increase the nation’s fiscal imbalance unless coupled with revenue-raising
measures such as a broadening of the tax
base.
But these measures would only
address in piecemeal fashion broader
issues inherent to income taxation. For
this reason, many have proposed farreaching tax reforms that would fundamentally change the U.S. tax system. One
such measure is the destination-based
cash-flow tax (DBCFT), a variation on the
consumption taxation commonly used
elsewhere in the developed world.

Destination-Based Cash-Flow Tax
Simply put, a DBCFT taxes domestic
sales minus domestic expenses. Under
this regime, goods or services purchased
within the U.S. would be taxed by the
U.S. regardless of the producer’s location;
and a purchaser acquiring goods or services outside the U.S. would not be taxed
by the U.S., even if the goods or services
were produced entirely within the U.S.

Economic Letter
Chart

1

U.S. Statutory Corporate Income Tax Rate Highest Among G-7

Percent

45
39.1

40
35

G-7 weighted average
(ex. U.S.) = 28.7

30

29.7

30.9

31.4

Germany

Japan

Italy

33.3

26.5

25
20.0

20
15
10
5
0

United
Kingdom

Canada

France

United
States

NOTE: The weighted average is calculated using each Group of Seven (G-7) country’s share of total G-7 gross domestic
product (ex. U.S.).
SOURCES: “Lessons for U.S. Business Tax Reform from International Tax Rates,” by Gary Clyde Hufbauer and Zhiyao
(Lucy) Lu, Policy Brief, Peterson Institute for International Economics, January 2017; authors’ calculations.

Chart

2

Tax Avoidance Depresses Average Effective U.S. Tax Rate

Percent

45
38.8

40
35
30
25

G-7 weighted average
(ex. U.S.) = 29.0
21.6

23.1

23.6

France

United
Kingdom

27.7

27.9

29.1

United
States

Germany

Italy

20
15
10
5
0

Canada

Japan

NOTE: The weighted average is calculated using each G-7 country’s share of total G-7 gross domestic product (ex. U.S.).
SOURCES: Annual Report of the Council of Economic Advisers, 2015; authors’ calculations.

This is at odds with the current corporate code that taxes all sales by U.S.
companies regardless of the purchaser’s
location. The current code is an issue
for U.S. exporters because the “destination” countries generally also tax those
sales, potentially placing U.S. firms at
a competitive disadvantage. U.S. firms
can generally deduct the cost of foreign

2

taxes paid, but because U.S. rates are
higher than those of developed-world
competitors, U.S. companies often face
a higher tax liability than foreign firms
when selling similar products to similar
customers.
Whether a DBCFT would reduce
corporate tax revenue depends on the
country’s trade balance. Given that

imports are taxed and exports are not,
overall corporate tax revenue will rise in
situations where a country has a negative
trade balance but fall in situations where
a country has a positive trade balance.
Because the U.S. imports more than it
exports, a cash-flow tax would generally be expected to generate revenue
for the government —about $1.2 trillion
more over 10 years, according to one
Congressional Budget Office estimate—
while shifting some of the country’s tax
burden to foreign exporters.
Fundamentally, a DBCFT taxes consumption (sales) rather than income,
making it very similar to the value-added
taxes (VATs) used almost universally outside the U.S. VATs tax domestic revenue
minus materials and capital equipment
purchased from domestic suppliers,
which roughly corresponds to the “value
added” a firm provides in the production process. DBCFTs do the same thing
except that wages paid to workers in
the home country are deductible from
domestic revenue, to avoid double
taxation.
There are several reasons consumption taxation has gained popularity
worldwide. One is that consumption is
much easier to calculate than income.1
Another is that taxing consumption
encourages investment, which ultimately
raises a country’s standard of living.2 A
third is that taxing consumption eliminates a potential incentive for firms to
locate elsewhere.
Taken together, analyses suggest the
U.S. standard of living might be 6 to 9
percent higher over the long run with
a consumption tax relative to where it
would be if the country stayed with the
current tax system, though the actual
figure could turn out to be higher or
lower than this depending on the precise
formulation of the tax and accompanying
changes.3

Assessing Trade Implications
Because imports are taxed by a
DBCFT and exports are not, the immediate impact of a DBCFT would be a more
advantageous business environment
for exporters and a less advantageous
one for importers. Thus, some observers have likened the DBCFT to a tariff
and asserted it will strengthen American

Economic Letter • Federal Reserve Bank of Dallas • May 2017

Economic Letter
manufacturing and improve the country’s
trade balance over the long run. Such an
analysis is only partially correct.
When a tariff is imposed, standard
economic theory suggests import volumes will fall on impact and then partially recover over time. On impact, imports
suddenly become more expensive, which
causes fewer of them to be purchased.
Subsequently, fewer imports reduce
U.S. demand for foreign currency to buy
those imports. This currency effect—via a
reduced exchange rate—makes imports
somewhat more affordable and partially,
though not completely, offsets the initial
decrease in import volumes.
Exempting exports from taxation produces a mirror image of the tariff analysis, with export volumes rising on impact
and then partially receding over time. In
this situation, exports suddenly become
less expensive to foreign customers,
which in turn causes more of the exports
to be purchased. Subsequently, however,
foreigners need more dollars to purchase
these exports, which causes the U.S. dollar to appreciate. This dollar appreciation
makes exports somewhat less affordable abroad and partially, though not
completely, offsets the initial increase in
export volumes.
When both of these measures are
undertaken at once, as they would with a
DBCFT, there is substantially more dollar
appreciation than would have occurred

Chart

3

if either were done alone—and therefore,
a substantially greater diminution of
exporters’ cost advantage and importers’
cost disadvantage.

Theoretical Behaviors
In fact, economic theory suggests the
combined effect should be just enough
to return import and export flows to
pre-DBCFT levels.4 A 20 percent DBCFT,
for example, would in principle produce
a 25 percent appreciation of the dollar
(Chart 3). Some—though not all—empirical work in this area finds that a complete exchange-rate adjustment is likely.5
Were this to occur, exporters would
find their tax savings exactly offset by
an erosion in the purchasing power of
foreigners, whereas importers would find
their additional tax burden exactly offset
by the stronger dollars they can now use
to obtain their merchandise.
Even if trade flows return to normal
eventually, there remains the question of how quickly that would happen.
Exporters would very likely experience a
temporary surge, while importers would
experience a temporary lull, creating
winners and losers in the U.S. economy.
While dollar appreciation would
eventually cause this effect to ebb, the
appreciation would itself create windfall gains for Americans whose debt is
denominated in foreign currencies, such
as the euro or the yen—and windfall

Analyses suggest
the U.S. standard
of living might be 6
to 9 percent higher
over the long run
with a consumption
tax relative to where
it would be if the
country stayed with
the current tax system.

Dollar Would Approach ’80s High After 25 Percent Appreciation

Index, March 1973 = 100

130

25% adjustment
= 124.8

125
120

Real, broad,
trade-weighted
value of the dollar

115
110

April
99.84

105
100
95
90
85
80

1975

1980

1985

1990

1995

2000

2005

2010

2015

NOTE: Shaded bars indicate U.S. recessions.
SOURCES: Federal Reserve Board; National Bureau of Economic Research; authors’ calculations.

Economic Letter • Federal Reserve Bank of Dallas • May 2017

3

Economic Letter

losses for Americans whose assets are
denominated in now-weaker foreign
currencies. Because the latter category is
larger than the former, estimates of this
phenomenon suggest Americans could
suffer a one-time net capital loss of 3 to
11 percent of gross domestic product, a
potentially sizable adjustment.6

Alternative Taxing Methods
A destination, or border-adjusted,
cash-flow tax would have a significant
impact on both the macroeconomy and
the well-being of firms and individuals.
On one hand, it would be expected to
increase U.S. investment, remove artificial
distortions that influence where U.S. firms
locate production facilities (and book
profits) and bring U.S. tax treatment of
corporations more into line with the rest
of the world. On the other hand, it would
bring about a one-time capital loss in
Americans’ asset portfolios and might usher in a temporary period during which U.S.
exporters would have a competitive advantage and U.S. importers a corresponding
disadvantage.
Of course, it would be possible to adopt
more limited piecemeal tax reforms rather
than the entire DBCFT package. Lowering
the corporate tax rate and exempting business investment from taxation, for example, would be an alternative way to potentially boost economic growth and encourage firms to locate production facilities in
the U.S. without uprooting the entire corporate tax code. It would risk enlarging the
federal deficit both directly through lower
rates and indirectly because there would
be no border-adjustment revenue.

DALLASFED

Offering firms a temporarily lower
rate or partial amnesty on profits currently “parked” abroad could be an alternative way to encourage the repatriation
of those profits, providing a one-time
revenue boost for the U.S. government.
However, it would leave intact the longrun distortions of the current corporate
tax code.
A border-adjustment mechanism
might be possible without switching
to a cash-flow tax, by simply grafting
an import tax and export subsidy onto
the current corporate income tax code,
though such a possibility would address
neither the high statutory rate on corporate profits nor the current bias against
corporate investment.
In short, there is no miracle cure for
all of the issues people might have with
the corporate tax code. Proposed solutions either enlarge the deficit or create
winners and losers. Of course, compensation could in theory be paid from winners to losers to offset the harmful side
effects of whatever tax reform is adopted,
but history suggests that such payment is
unlikely.
Koenig is senior vice president and
principal policy advisor and Saving is a
senior research economist and advisor in
the Research Department at the Federal
Reserve Bank of Dallas.

Notes
One key reason for this is that, under consumption
taxation, it is unnecessary to calculate the cost basis for
investments because selling or trading an investment
would no longer be a taxable event. Of course, if the
1

Economic Letter

is published by the Federal Reserve Bank of Dallas.
The views expressed are those of the authors and
should not be attributed to the Federal Reserve Bank
of Dallas or the Federal Reserve System.
Articles may be reprinted on the condition that
the source is credited to the Federal Reserve Bank
of Dallas.
Economic Letter is available on the Dallas Fed
website, www.dallasfed.org.

proceeds were used to make purchases, those proceeds
would become cash flow and be subject to tax.
2
An analysis done by William McBride at the Tax
Foundation, for example, recently found that full expensing of investment would boost long-run gross domestic
product by about 5 percent, https://taxfoundation.
org/economic-and-budgetary-effects-full-expensinginvestment.
3
See “A Summary of the Dynamic Analysis of the Tax
Reform Options Prepared for the President’s Advisory
Panel on Federal Tax Reform,” by Robert Carroll, John
Diamond, Craig Johnson, James Mackie III, Office of Tax
Analysis, U.S. Department of the Treasury, May 2006.
The increase would be closer to 6 percent, according
to “Economic Effects of a Personal Capital Income Tax
Add-On to a Consumption Tax,” by John Diamond and
George Zodrow, International Center for Public Policy
(Andrew Young School of Policy Studies, Georgia State
University), Working Paper no. 07-15, June 2007.
4
See “Border Adjustment and the Dollar,” by Alan J.
Auerbach, Economic Perspectives, American Enterprise Institute, February 2017, https://eml.berkeley.
edu/~auerbach/Borderadjustmentandthedollar.pdf.
5
A 2017 study by Caroline Freund and Joseph Gagnon
finds that, in countries with economically similar tax
systems, currencies do typically fully appreciate in relatively short order (“Effects of Consumption Taxes on Real
Exchange Rates and Trade Balances,” Peterson Institute
for International Economics, Working Paper no. 17-5).
Less-recent work by the World Bank in 2005 points
toward a substantial but not fully offsetting currency
appreciation, which could mean exporters would enjoy a
modest competitive advantage (and importers a modest
competitive disadvantage) over the medium to long run.
6
See “Notes on the U.S. Wealth Effect of Border
Adjustment,” by Alan J. Auerbach, February
2017, http://eml.berkeley.edu/~auerbach/
NotesontheUSWealthEffectofBorderAdjustment.pdf.

Mine Yücel, Senior Vice President and Director of Research
Jim Dolmas, Executive Editor
Michael Weiss, Editor
Kathy Thacker, Associate Editor
Ellah Piña, Graphic Designer

Federal Reserve Bank of Dallas
2200 N. Pearl St., Dallas, TX 75201