View original document

The full text on this page is automatically extracted from the file linked above and may contain errors and inconsistencies.

VOL. 12, NO. 4 • MARCH 2017

DALLASFED

Economic
Letter
America’s Missing Workers
Are Primarily Middle Educated
by Alan Armen and Tyler Atkinson

}

ABSTRACT: The labor force
participation rate has fallen
since 2008, partly due to an
aging population and despite
a more highly educated
one. After accounting for
aging, those whose highest
educational attainment is a
high school diploma, some
college or an associate degree
have primarily driven the
participation decrease.

S

ince the Great Recession,
the labor force participation
rate—the percent of people
employed or looking for
work—has fallen roughly 3 percentage points. Declining participation has
downside implications for the long-run
size of the economy. Policymakers are
acutely interested in understanding what
is behind the decline and what, if anything, can be done to slow it.
A well-documented explanation for
the decline is that the population has
gotten older and, therefore, is more likely
to be retired. Results from studies of
the effect of aging on participation have
ranged widely, though aging typically
poses a sizable downward impact. A
less-often emphasized point, however, is
that increases in educational attainment
over the same period partially offset the
impact of age and put upward pressure
on the participation rate.
There is no consensus on what
exactly has driven the decline in participation beyond what demographics can
explain. Whatever the cause, it appears
this decline is concentrated among those
who have only a high school degree or
some college education, while those
with less than a high school education
or a bachelor’s degree or higher are participating at a normal rate. Policies that

effectively target these middle-education
groups by either increasing their participation rates or educational attainment
levels could plausibly mitigate the overall
labor force participation rate decline.

Falling Participation
One of the simplest ways to explain
declining labor force participation is to
examine how the rate changed within
demographic groups, specifically combinations of age and educational attainment categories.1 For example, labor
force participation among high school
graduates age 35–44 was 81.8 percent in
2008 and 77.1 percent in 2016; the group
made up 6.1 percent of the population
in 2008 and 4.7 percent in 2016. Changes
in the total labor force participation rate
can be decomposed into changes in the
groups’ participation rates and changes
in their shares of the population.
Suppose that each demographic
group’s participation rate had been constant since 2008. Under such a “counterfactual,” all changes in the total participation rate since then would be accounted
for by changes in each group’s share of
the population.
In reality, participation rates within
each age group have changed, but the
counterfactual is useful nonetheless. In
particular, because the population share

Economic Letter
Table

1

If the counterfactual had been created
with only age categories, it would have
fallen to 64.9 percent by 2016—overstating the decline contributed by demographics. The aging effect is partially
offset by the population continuing along
its trend of greater educational attainment, as the more highly educated also
participate at a higher rate.
Between 2008 and 2016, the fraction
of the population age 25 and over with at
least some college education increased
from 55.3 percent to 60.2 percent. As
shown in the blue line in Chart 1, if the
educational attainment rate of each
age group in 2008 hadn’t changed, the
expected labor force participation rate
would have been 0.7 percentage points
below the actual.

Performing the same counterfactual
analysis, but for each educational attainment group on its own and also breaking
out groups by gender, reveals that an aging
population explains all of the decline in
participation for individuals with less than
a high school education or a bachelor’s
degree or higher (Table 1). These two
groups are even participating more than
one would expect, given participation
rates in 2008 and the shift in the age composition of the population through 2016.
No other explanation, such as greater
affinity for leisure pursuits or labor market
dysfunction, is necessary to explain why
these groups’ participation fell, and, thus,
it could be difficult to raise their rates
beyond current levels.
Meanwhile, for those with a high
school education or only some college,
participation rates are low relative to
2008, indicating room to rise.
The last column of Table 1 multiplies
the difference between the 2016 actual
and counterfactual participation rates for
each educational attainment and gender
group by the group’s population size in
2016. The result equals the number of
workers that could be added to (or subtracted from) the workforce by returning
to the age-expected rates.
Male and female nonparticipants
have roughly the same capacity to join or
return to the workforce. This contradicts
the often-heard narrative that the decline
in participation for lower-skill prime-age
men (age 25 to 54) is most problematic.
That may still be true over a longer time
span (1960s to present) but not for the
recession and recovery period.
The total 2.5 million workers
obtained by combining the two middleeducation groups is roughly 1 percent of
the population age 16 and over, implying that their addition to the workforce
would raise the headline participation
rate by about a full percentage point.

Missing Workers

Policy Implications

Labor Force Participation Rate
(As a percentage)
2008

2016

’08 rates,’16 age
demographics

Gap in number of
workers (thousands)

Bachelor’s degree and higher

82.7

79.7

79.2

–153

Some college or associate degree

78.3

72.0

74.1

552

High school graduate

72.4

67.6

69.4

549

Less than a high school diploma

58.5

58.2

57.3

–102

Bachelor’s degree and higher

74.1

70.9

70.7

–79

Some college or associate degree

66.8

61.6

63.3

531

High school graduate

53.1

47.5

50.3

888

Less than a high school diploma

32.6

34.1

34.1

–2

Men

Women

Total
Bachelor’s degree and higher

78.4

75.1

74.7

–232

Some college or associate degree

72.0

66.3

68.2

1,084

High school graduate

62.4

57.5

59.8

1,437

Less than a high school diploma

45.7

46.3

45.8

–104

NOTES: The “’08 rates, ’16 age demographics” column is a counterfactual, where each age group has the same labor
force participation rate (LFPR) as in 2008, but the population weights for each age group shift to their 2016 levels. It
represents the LFPR that can be explained by age demographics. The “gap in number of workers” column is the gap
between the actual and counterfactual 2016 LFPR times the population in 2016. It represents the number of workers that
could be added to the labor force to match the 2008 LFPR adjusted for aging.
SOURCES: Annual Social and Economic Supplement (ASEC) of the Current Population Survey, IPUMS-CPS (University of
Minnesota, www.ipums.org); authors’ calculations.

of older individuals—who participate at
a lower rate—has risen, the counterfactual participation rate has also declined
since 2008. The magnitude of the decline
provides a means of assessing the extent
to which changes in age and educational
attainment contributed to the fall in the
actual participation rate.
The actual participation rate for persons age 25 and over, in fact, fell from
67.3 percent in 2008 to 64.5 percent in
2016. The counterfactual participation
rate fell to 65.5 percent, implying that
demographic effects contributed 1.8
percentage points to the top-line 2.8
percentage-point decline (Chart 1).
Because movements in the counterfactual rate are solely due to demographic factors, the gap between the
counterfactual and actual gives an
estimate of how much nondemographic
factors contributed. Hence, the remaining 1.0 percentage point could be driven
by people willingly choosing not to work,
some sort of labor market dysfunction or
other factors.
The fall in the counterfactual is driven by the two opposite forces of aging
and a more highly educated population.

2

The labor force participation rate
has declined relative to 2008 by more
than simply changes in age or educational attainment would suggest.
Understanding the makeup of these
additional nonparticipants provides
clues regarding which policies may put
upward pressure on participation.

These findings suggest that a plausible policy intended to limit declining
labor-force participation rates could
focus on nonparticipating individuals
possessing a high school or some college
education, either through higher educational attainment or greater participation
within each category.

Economic Letter • Federal Reserve Bank of Dallas • March 2017

Economic Letter
According to the counterfactual in
Chart 1, a more highly educated population would participate at a higher rate.
Some of this education effect is certainly not causal. Many people become educated precisely because they plan to work,
and more highly educated individuals who
have no intent to enter the labor market
would not raise the participation rate.
But at least speculatively, policies
that increase the population’s education
level should also raise participation. For
example, if a wage is so low that working
would make a household worse off—possibly because earnings wouldn’t cover
the costs of transportation, child care,
etc.—increased education should raise the
market wage, increasing the likelihood of
workforce entry.
Even if training and education don’t
occur through traditional high schools and
colleges, policy could aim to raise the participation of the middle-education categories back to their 2008 age-adjusted rates.
Many of these middle-educated nonparticipants may be inclined to work but
face impediments that have emerged
since 2008, such as lack of proficiency in
new skills employers require. A mismatch
between the skills applicants have and
those required is often cited as a principal barrier to hiring. Implementing new
vocational training and boosting existing programs to reduce possible skills
mismatch between nonparticipants and
employers could draw people back into
the workforce.

Not Participating but Interested
If the decline in participation by these
middle-education groups were a matter
of choice—such as deciding to take care
of family members or a greater preference
for leisure—a policy to increase their participation would at best be ineffective and
possibly make people worse off, even if it
increased the size of the economy.
One study’s findings add weight to
this premise, showing that all of the
decline in the prime-age participation
rate can be accounted for by individuals
in households whose income is above
the median.2 If these individuals chose
nonparticipation because their families
could afford for them to do so, education
or training programs would be unlikely to
draw them into the workforce.

nonparticipants” in the population by
education group shows broadly similar
patterns as the earlier analysis using the
labor force participation rate (Table 2).3
The largest increases relative to 2008 were

The Current Population Survey asks
those not in the labor force (defined
as those who haven’t sought work in
the prior four weeks) if they want a job.
Analyzing the share of these “interested

Chart

1

Demographic Changes Only Account for Part
of Participation Rate’s Decline Since 2008

Percent

68.0
67.5
67.0

Demographics
contribution
= –1.8 percentage
point (ppt)

66.5
66.0

LFPR change
= –2.8 ppt

65.5

64.5
64.0
63.5

Nondemographics
contribution
= –1.0 ppt

Actual labor force participation
rate (LFPR), 25 years and up
Counterfactual: If within-group
participation had stayed at 2008 rates
Counterfactual: If within-group educational
attainment had stayed at 2008 rates

65.0

1990

1994

1998

2002

2006

Education
contribution
= +0.7 ppt

2010

2014

NOTES: The green dashed counterfactual line holds the LFPR constant to its 2008 value for each age and education
group but lets the share of the group’s population with a certain level of education and the share of the group in the U.S.
population vary. The blue dashed counterfactual line holds the share of each group’s population with a certain level of
education constant to its 2008 value, but lets each group’s LFPR and the share of the group in the U.S. population vary.
SOURCE: Annual Social and Economic Supplement (ASEC) of the Current Population Survey, IPUMS-CPS (University of
Minnesota, www.ipums.org); authors’ calculations.

Table

2

Interested-Nonparticipation Rate
(As a percentage)
2008

2016

’08 rates,’16 age
demographics

Gap in number of
workers (thousands)

Bachelor’s degree and higher

1.0

1.1

1.0

Some college or associate degree

1.5

2.0

1.6

99

High school graduate

1.7

2.1

1.7

113

Less than a high school diploma

2.2

2.1

2.2

–1

Men
23

Women
Bachelor’s degree and higher

1.2

1.4

1.2

54

Some college or associate degree

1.7

2.2

1.7

172

High school graduate

1.9

2.3

1.8

161

Less than a high school diploma

2.6

3.0

2.6

50

Bachelor’s degree and higher

1.1

1.2

1.1

77

Some college or associate degree

1.6

2.1

1.6

271

High school graduate

1.8

2.2

1.8

275

Less than a high school diploma

2.4

2.6

2.4

49

Total

NOTES: The interested-nonparticipation rate (INR) is defined as those not in the labor force who report wanting a job,
as a share of population. The “’08 rates, ’16 age demographics” column is a counterfactual, where each age group has
the same INR as in 2008, but the population weights for each age group shift to their 2016 levels. It represents the INR
that can be explained by age demographics. The “gap in number of workers” column is the gap between the actual and
counterfactual 2016 INR times the population in 2016. It represents the number of workers that could be added to the
labor force to match the 2008 INR adjusted for aging.
SOURCES: Annual Social and Economic Supplement (ASEC) of the Current Population Survey, IPUMS-CPS (University of
Minnesota, www.ipums.org); authors’ calculations.

Economic Letter • Federal Reserve Bank of Dallas • March 2017

3

Economic Letter

Chart

2

what segments of the population have
most felt the lasting damage of the Great
Recession. It also hints at what sort of
policies might boost labor force participation as the population continues to age.

Changes in Interested-Nonparticipation Rate
Since 2008 Not Demographics Driven

Percent

2.5

Actual interested-nonparticipation rate (INR),
25 years and up

2.4

Armen is a senior research analyst and
Atkinson is an economic programmer/
analyst in the Research Department of the
Federal Reserve Bank of Dallas.

Counterfactual: If within-group
interested-nonparticipation had
stayed at 2008 rates

2.3
2.2
2.1
2.0

INR change
= +0.3 percentage
point (ppt)

1.9
1.8

Notes

1.7
1.6
1.5

1994

1998

2002

2006

2010

2014

NOTES: The interested-nonparticipation rate (INR) is defined as those not in the labor force who report wanting a job, as
a share of population. The green dashed counterfactual line holds the INR constant to its 2008 value for each age and
education group but lets the share of the group’s population with a certain level of education and the share of the group in
the U.S. population vary.
SOURCE: Annual Social and Economic Supplement (ASEC) of the Current Population Survey, IPUMS-CPS (University of
Minnesota, www.ipums.org); authors’ calculations.

concentrated in the middle-income education groups, although the rate is slightly
higher for the other education groups as
well. Aging demographics have very little
effect on this rate, so the counterfactual
is essentially constant (Chart 2).
This suggests that some of the decline
in participation rates was involuntary,
especially for the middle-education
groups. However, the capacity for additional workers in the last column of
Table 2 is also noticeably smaller than
its counterpart from Table 1. The abovenormal rate of interested nonparticipants
only accounts for about 20 percent of the
unusually lower labor force participation
rate for the middle-education groups.

DALLASFED

Specifically, age categories of 25–34, 35–44, 45–54,
55–59, 60–64, 65–69, 70–74 and 75+, and highest educational attainment categories of less than a high school
diploma, high school graduate with no college, some
college or associate degree, and bachelor’s degree and
higher. Only those age 25 and older are used because
lack of employment among younger people is driven by
education rather than lower education leading to lower
likelihood of employment. Data are from the Current
Population Survey Annual Social and Economic Supplement, by Sarah Flood, Miriam King, Steven Ruggles and
J. Robert Warren, Integrated Public Use Microdata Series, Current Population Survey: Version 4.0. [dataset],
Minneapolis: University of Minnesota, 2015.
2
“Changes in Labor Participation and Household
Income,” by Robert Hall and Nicolas Petrosky-Nadeau,
Federal Reserve Bank of San Francisco FRBSF Economic
Letter, no. 2, 2016.
3
Note that this is slightly different from the usual definition of “discouraged workers,” who want a job, haven’t
looked for one in the last four weeks, but have in the last
12 months.
1

Nondemographics
contribution
= +0.3 ppt

This could mean 80 percent of the
missing workers are unwilling or unable
to join the workforce. It might also mean
that those who answer they don’t want
a job implicitly incorporate current job
prospects into their response, which
could change with circumstances.
Depending on how you slice it, there
are many different explanations for the
recent fall in labor force participation
and characterizations of the unexplained
component. Educational attainment is
one of those characterizations, because
only those with a high school diploma
or some college education are less likely
to be in the workforce than one would
have expected in 2008. This speaks to

Economic Letter

is published by the Federal Reserve Bank of Dallas.
The views expressed are those of the authors and
should not be attributed to the Federal Reserve Bank
of Dallas or the Federal Reserve System.
Articles may be reprinted on the condition that
the source is credited to the Federal Reserve Bank
of Dallas.
Economic Letter is available on the Dallas Fed
website, www.dallasfed.org.

Mine Yücel, Senior Vice President and Director of Research
Jim Dolmas, Executive Editor
Michael Weiss, Editor
Dianne Tunnell, Associate Editor
Ellah Piña, Graphic Designer

Federal Reserve Bank of Dallas
2200 N. Pearl St., Dallas, TX 75201