View original document

The full text on this page is automatically extracted from the file linked above and may contain errors and inconsistencies.

First Quarter 2021
Volume 6, Issue 1

The Graying of
Household Debt
in the U.S.
Isolating the Effect
of State Business
Closure Orders on
Employment
Banking Trends
Research Update
Q&A
Data in Focus

Contents
First Quarter 2021

A publication of the Research
Department of the Federal
Reserve Bank of Philadelphia
Economic Insights features
nontechnical articles on monetary
policy, banking, and national,
regional, and international
economics, all written for a wide
audience.
The views expressed by the authors are not
necessarily those of the Federal Reserve.
The Federal Reserve Bank of Philadelphia
helps formulate and implement monetary
policy, supervises banks and bank and
savings and loan holding companies, and
provides financial services to depository
institutions and the federal government. It
is one of 12 regional Reserve Banks that,
together with the U.S. Federal Reserve
Board of Governors, make up the Federal
Reserve System. The Philadelphia Fed
serves eastern and central Pennsylvania,
southern New Jersey, and Delaware.

Volume 6, Issue 1

1

Q&A…

2

The Graying of Household Debt in the U.S.

8

Isolating the Effect of State
Business Closure Orders on Employment

with Ryan Michaels.

Household debt has grayed significantly over the last several decades.
As Wenli Li explains, this has important implications for policymakers.

Ryan Michaels takes a closer look at the data to see just how much the stateissued essential-business lists increased unemployment during COVID-19.

17

Banking Trends:
How and Why Bank Capital Ratios Change
Over the Business Cycle
Post-2007 capital regulation tries to ensure that banks are well-capitalized.
PJ Elliott examines whether banks’ capital decisions make them stronger or
more fragile when the economy faces a downturn.

Patrick T. Harker
President and
Chief Executive Officer
Michael Dotsey
Executive Vice President and
Director of Research
Adam Steinberg
Managing Editor, Research Publications
Brendan Barry
Data Visualization Manager

ISSN 0007–7011

Connect with Us
We welcome your comments at:
PHIL.EI.Comments@phil.frb.org
E-mail notifications:
www.philadelphiafed.org/notifications
Previous articles:
https://ideas.repec.org/s/fip/fedpei.html
Twitter:
@PhilFedResearch
Facebook:
www.facebook.com/philadelphiafed/
LinkedIn:
https://www.linkedin.com/company/
philadelphiafed/

23

Research Update

29

Data in Focus

Abstracts of the latest working papers produced by the Philadelphia Fed.

Livingston Survey.

About the Cover
Bank of North America
Founding a new country means having to create almost everything from scratch,
including banks. The first chartered bank in the new United States—the loftily
named Bank of North America—opened its doors on Philadelphia's Chestnut
Street in 1782. This three-story building was largely indistinguishable from the
neighboring tanner and currier. Only its entrance portico, with two columns
holding aloft a flat architrave, hints at the coming of the grandiose Federal style
in architecture. The Bank of North America's founding stockholders included
former Virginia Governor Thomas Jefferson and Alexander Hamilton, former chief
staff aide to General George Washington. A decade later, as cabinet secretaries
to President Washington, the two men would become bitter adversaries over
whether the new federal government needed to replace the struggling Bank of
North America with a congressionally chartered First Bank of the United States.
Illustration by Brendan Barry.

Q&A…

with Ryan Michaels, an
economist and economic
advisor here at the Philadelphia Fed.

Where did you grow up?
In Elkhart, Indiana, which had the distinction in the Great Recession of experiencing
the largest rise in unemployment of any
region in the country. It was heavily
manufacturing, although my folks worked
in white-collar jobs. I didn’t know how
heavily concentrated Elkhart was in manufacturing until I was older.

Did learning about manufacturing in
Elkhart pique your interest in labor
market economics?
I got interested in labor markets even
before then. You only had to look at the
headlines to see how fast manufacturing
employment fell everywhere, particularly
starting in 2000.

Ryan Michaels
Before joining the Federal Reserve Bank
of Philadelphia in 2015, economist and
economic advisor Ryan Michaels taught
macroeconomics at the University of
Rochester. He first became interested in
his primary areas of research, macroeconomics and labor markets, while
pursuing his doctorate in economics at
the University of Michigan.

A lot of your work is about layoffs and
rehirings. Was anybody in your household growing up laid off or rehired?
Fortunately, no, because both of my folks
had very long-term relationships with
their employers. Then, in grad school,
I read about the other side of the market,
which experiences a lot more volatility.
And a lot of that is layoffs and job destruction. Since our household had experienced
job stability, that seemed awfully unsettling to me. That’s what got me interested.

models. What was the state of labor
market modelling when you began
graduate school, and how did you
come to think these models needed
improvement?
When I began graduate school, the most
popular kind of job search model treated
a firm like it was just a single manager
who hires one worker. That bothered me,
because there was an enormous amount
of scholarship that looked at establishmentlevel microdata and characterized the
heterogeneity across firms. You want to
integrate plausible models of individual
firms into macro models of job search so
you can speak to firm dynamics as well
as unemployment, vacancies, and layoffs.
That led to one of the papers I co-wrote.1
That’s been the direction of a lot of the
literature since then, which seems to me
a profitable direction.

Your last Economic Insights article was
about the long-run decline in men’s
labor force participation.2 During the
COVID-19 pandemic, there’s also been
a decline in women’s labor force
participation. What are your thoughts
about that?
Women’s workforce participation has
been much more responsive than it
typically is in recessions, and the decline
in nonemployment is most pronounced
among single mothers. Being out of the
labor force is a hit to their human capital
production—typically, you learn on the
job, developing more skills. However, if
as an employer I see someone who hasn’t
had a job for a while, I don’t have to guess
as to why they didn’t have a job. There’s
usually the concern, “Is this person not
that committed? Do I really want to hire
them?” Well, we’ve had an obvious aggregate event, so they might have less trouble
reengaging with the labor market.

Your article in this issue evaluates
COVID-19 mitigation policies such as
essential-business lists. What about
vaccines? How would you evaluate
their effect as a mitigation policy?
There is variation across states in how they
have managed the logistics of the rollout
and how they have prioritized who gets the
vaccine. Should you try to vaccinate people (like frontline workers) who are more
likely to be infected by, and spread, the
disease, or should you try to vaccinate
those who are most likely to die if infected?
My impression is that states at first took
different approaches, so you could see how
the spread of the disease varied depending on who was vaccinated as well as the
total number of vaccinations.

Notes
1 Michael W. L. Elsby and Ryan Michaels.
“Marginal Jobs, Heterogeneous Firms, and Unemployment Flows,” American Economic
Journal: Macroeconomics, 4:1 (2013), pp. 1–48.

Much of your work addresses the
inadequacies of canonical labor market

2 Ryan Michaels. “Why Are Men Working Less
These Days?” Economic Insights (Fourth Quarter
2017), pp. 7–16.

Q&A

2021 Q1

Federal Reserve Bank of Philadelphia
Research Department

1

The Graying
of Household
Debt in the U.S.
Photo: Ryan McVay/iStock

America is aging, and older Americans are now borrowing more than they used to.
This has consequences for both fiscal and monetary policymaking.
By Wenli Li
Senior Economic Advisor and Economist
Federal Reserve Bank of Philadelphia
The views expressed in this article are not
necessarily those of the Federal Reserve.

2

Federal Reserve Bank of Philadelphia
Research Department

S

ince the late 1980s, older American
households have accounted for an
increasing share of household debt,
particularly residential mortgages. This
trend can be partly explained by an aging
American population: As the youngest
Baby Boomers approach retirement age,
there are more older households available
to take out loans.1 But there is another,
related explanation: persistently low and
continuously falling real interest rates.
Although all households have increased
their borrowing in the presence of these
low interest rates, older households,
because they have benefited more from
asset appreciation, have also extracted
home equity. Doing so has allowed them
to smooth their consumption—that is, maintain their previous level of consumption
even after retirement—but it has also left
them with a larger share of household debt.

The aging of American household debt
has important policy implications. Older
households are less likely to default on
their loans, but when they do default, it is
harder for them to recover financially
because they have fewer years left in which
to recover and fewer opportunities for
increasing their income.
The redistribution of household debt
also affects consumers’ collective response to fiscal and monetary policies. As
these policies alter households’ wealth,
older households are more likely to
change their consumption than are middleaged households (but less likely than are
young households).2

An Aging Population
Is Only Part of the Story

Economists have begun to document and

The Graying of Household Debt in the U.S.
2021 Q1

analyze the aging of American debt. For
example, Ohio State University economist
Meta Brown and her coauthors used credit
bureau and survey data to examine demographic changes among borrowers from
2003 to 2015. They found that older consumers experienced the steepest growth in
real per capita home-secured debts.
But older borrowers have also increased
their obligations in other major debt categories. In 2018, George Washington
University economist Annamaria Lusardi
and her coauthors analyzed data from
the Health and Retirement Study and
documented substantial increases in other
household debt, such as credit card debt
and medical debt, over time among 56- to
61-year-olds who are close to retirement.
In this article, I use the Survey of
Consumer Finances (SCF), the same survey
used by Brown and her coauthors, to
demonstrate the changing distribution of
household debt over the last 30 years.
The SCF is a triennial statistical survey
of the balance sheets, pensions, incomes,
and other characteristics of American
families. I define total debt as the sum of
housing debt (mortgages, home equity
loans, and home equity lines of credit),
installment loans (such as student debt
and auto loans), and credit card balances
after last payment. Young households are
those whose heads are between 25 and
34; middle-aged households between 35
and 54; and old households between
55 and 85. I chose 55 as the lower bound
for old households so I can group all
Baby Boomers in the same category.3

FIGURE 1

FIGURE 3

Old Households Account for
an Increasing Share of Total
Household Debt

The Graying of Household Debt
Has Coincided with the Aging of
the American Population

Share of total debt holdings by households
of different age groups, 1989–2016
70%

Share of households by age of head, 1989–2016
70%
60%

60%
50%

Middle-aged

40%

Old

30%

50%

Old

40%

Middle-aged

30%
20%

20%

Young

10%
Young

10%
0%

1989
2016
Source: Survey of Consumer Finances.
Note: Household's age group is determined by the
age of the household head.

From 1989 to 2016, old households
accounted for an increasing share of total
household debt, from 20 percent in 1989
to 38 percent in 2016, while the shares of
total debt held by the other two groups
fell (Figure 1).
Among household debt, housing debt
experienced the most aging during this
period. Specifically, the share of total
mortgages held by old households doubled from 1989 to 2016. The increase is
particularly prominent after 2000 (Figure
2, panel a).
Auto loans, student loans, and credit
card debt also aged. The share of auto
loans held by old households is still

0%

1989

2016

Sources: Survey of Consumer Finances and U.S.
Census Bureau.

relatively small, but the increase has been
significant (Figure 2, panel b). Student
loans showed moderate signs of graying.
The share of student loans held by old
households increased mostly after 2000
(Figure 2, panel c). The share of credit
card debt held by old households also grew,
rising from 20 percent in 1989 to about 40
percent in 2016 (Figure 2, panel d).
The graying of household debt has
coincided with the aging of the American
population. The youngest Boomers, born
in 1964, are now approaching retirement
age. The share of households headed by
older people went from 37 percent in 1989
to 46 percent in 2016 (Figure 3).

FIGURE 2

Housing Debt Experienced the Most Aging

The share of total mortgages held by old households doubled.

Share of different types of household debt held by households of different ages, 1989–2016
Old

Middle-aged

Young

Mortgage Debt
70%

70%

70%

70%

60%

60%

60%

60%

50%

50%

50%

50%

40%

40%

40%

40%

30%

30%

30%

30%

20%

20%

20%

20%

10%

10%

10%

10%

0%

0%

0%

0%

1989
2016
Source: Survey of Consumer Finances.

Auto Debt

Student Debt

Credit Card Debt

1989
2016
1989
2016
Note: Household's age group is determined by the age of the household head.

The Graying of Household Debt in the U.S.

2021 Q1

1989

Federal Reserve Bank of Philadelphia
Research Department

2016

3

However, if we hold households’
borrowing constant at its 1989 level (and
thus isolate the share based on changing
demographics alone), we explain about 5
percentage points (30 percent) of the rise
in the share of debt held by old households (Figure 4). An important part of the
aging of American debt must be due to
behavioral changes.

More Old Households
Borrowed, and
They Borrowed More

The graying of total debt has occurred as
more old households owe debt, and old
households that owe debt have borrowed
more on average than before. The shares
of young and middle-aged households that
owe some form of debt did not change
much between 1989 and 2016 (Figure 5,
panel a). The share of old households owing debt, on the other hand, went from 52
percent in 1989 to over 70 percent in 2016.
Prior to 2007, the average amount of
debt held by indebted households rose
slightly faster for old households than
for young and middle-aged households
(Figure 5, panel b). After 2007, all households held less debt. The deleveraging,
however, was less severe for old households, leaving them with a greater share of
their pre-2007 debt.
Mortgages remain the largest household
debt for most households, despite the
recent surge in student loans. Homeownership rates rose for all three groups
prior to the Great Recession. After that,
homeownership rates dropped for
all households (Figure 6, panel a). Old
households saw the largest increase in
the share of homeowners with a mortgage
(Figure 6, panel b). However, conditional
on borrowing, the average amount of
a mortgage is larger for young and middleaged households (Figure 6, panel c) and
the average home equities are larger for
old homeowners (Figure 6, panel d).
Old and middle-aged households are
more likely than young households to refinance their mortgages, and they are more
likely to take out cash while refinancing
their mortgages. Additionally, old and
middle-aged households are more likely
to take out home equity loans (Figure 7).

FIGURE 4

40%

Household Debt Has Aged
Faster Than the Population

Behavioral changes have played an important role in the aging of American debt.

Share of total debt held by old households, 1989–2016
Due to:

Population aging

Behavioral changes

30%
20%
10%
0%

Source: Survey of Consumer Finances.

Federal Reserve Bank of Philadelphia
Research Department

2016

FIGURE 5

All Borrowers Borrowed More, and More Old Households Owed Debt

The deleveraging after 2007 was less severe for old households, leaving them with
a greater share of their pre-2007 debt.
Households' debt holdings by age, 1989–2016

Fraction of Households with Debt

Average Total Debt, ‘000s

90%

Middle-aged
Young
Old

60%

30%

0%

$200
$150

Middle-aged

$100

Old
Young

$50

1989

$0

2016

1989

2016

Source: Survey of Consumer Finances.
FIGURE 6

Mortgage Debt Looms Large for Most Households

Old households saw the largest increase in the share of homeowners with a mortgage.
Homeownership, mortgages, and home equities by household age, 1989–2016

Homeownership Rate

Share of Homeowners with Mortgages

100%

100%

80%

Old

80%

60%

Middle-aged

60%

40%

Young

40%

20%
0%

Young
Middle-aged
Old

20%
1989

0%

2016

Average Mortgage, ‘000s

$350
$300

$250

$250
Middle-aged

$200

Old
Young

$150

$100
$50
$0

2016

Old

Middle-aged

$150

$50
$0

The Graying of Household Debt in the U.S.
2021 Q1

2016

$200

$100

1989

1989

Average Home Equities, ‘000s

$350
$300

Source: Survey of Consumer Finances.

4

1989

Young
1989

2016

To differentiate between existing loans and new originations,
Brown and her coauthors used credit bureau data to examine
household borrowing by age before and after the Great Recession.
They uncovered evidence that old households carried more
debt through the Great Recession and had more loan originations
after the Great Recession.

Falling Real Interest Rates

Persistently falling interest rates over the last 30 years made
borrowing cheap (Figure 8), which in turn
led to increased demand for houses and
See Why Interest
subsequently significant appreciation of
Rates Have
house prices (Figure 9). All households
Declined.
borrowed more relative to house value and
total household income over time. Not surprisingly, the increase
is much more evident relative to income than to house value.

For most households, housing remains the single largest
asset. As housing is indivisible and it is costly to change houses,
one way for households to access housing wealth as they age is
to borrow against the value of their home. This is particularly
true when house price appreciation is unanticipated.4 Indeed,
old households extracted more cash from their houses than did
middle-aged and young households, and they held the highest
level of home equity loans.
In recent years, an acceleration of mortgage lending—leading
to the Great Recession and the subsequent slowdown—has also
contributed to more mortgage debt held by older households.5
This is because old households defaulted less and carried more
debt after the recession. Additionally, old households on average
are more creditworthy and, hence, were less affected by the
tightening of lending standards after the Great Recession.

FIGURE 7

Old and Middle-Aged Households Are More Likely to Refinance,
Take Out Cash While Refinancing, and Take Out Home Equity Loans
Mortgage refinancing and home equity lines of credit (HELOCs), 1989–2016
Old

Middle-aged

Young

% of Refi Cond. on Mortgage
45%
40%

% of Cash Refi Cond. on Mortgage
45%
40%

35%

35%

30%

30%

25%

25%

20%

20%

15%

15%

10%

10%

5%
0%

5%
0%

1989
2016
Source: Survey of Consumer Finances.

1989

2016

% with HELOCs Cond. on Mortgage
25%

HELOC Bal. Cond. on Mortgage, ‘000s
$10

20%

$8

15%

$6

10%

$4

5%

$2

0%

1989

2016

$0

1989

2016

FIGURE 8

FIGURE 9

Persistently Falling Interest Rates Over
the Last 30 Years Made Borrowing Cheap

Falling Interest Rates Have Led to Increased
Demand for Houses and Subsequently
Significant Appreciation of House Prices

Nominal reported mortgage interest rate by household age,
compared to Freddie Mac rate, 1989–2016

Real mortgage rates and growth rates of real house price index (HPI),
adjusted for inflation, 1989–2016

12%

15%

10%

10%

8%

Old

6%

Middle-aged

4%

Young

2%

Freddie Mac
30-yr fixed

0%

1989

2016

Sources: Survey of Consumer Finances and Freddie Mac.

5%

Real mortgage rates
Real HPI growth rates

0%
−5%
−10%
−15%

1975

2016

Source: Freddie Mac.

The Graying of Household Debt in the U.S.

2021 Q1

Federal Reserve Bank of Philadelphia
Research Department

5

Policy Implications of
Aging Household Debt

Both debt-to-income and debt-to-asset
ratios have increased for households of all
age groups, but the debt-to-income ratio
has increased faster (Figure 10).6 As a result,
changes that deflate asset values threaten
the financial solvency of all households,
and they endanger old households more
than young and middle-aged households.
Although old households, because of their
steady (albeit perhaps smaller) income
and the wealth they have built up, are less
likely to default, they will have to default if
house prices drop significantly, all else
being equal.7 Should that happen, old
households will have a much harder time
recovering financially, due to their shorter
remaining life span and limited income
potential. Thus, the large increase in homesecured debt carried by middle-aged
households into retirement constitutes a
new source of financial risk in retirement.8
We may already be seeing the effect of
this change. As documented by University
of California, San Diego, professor Michelle
White and me, the increases in the
percentages of bankruptcy filings and
foreclosures by old households since
2000 were much larger than the increase
in their population.9
Another policy implication of the
graying of American
debt pertains to the
See The Macrocollective houseeconomic
hold response to
Perspective.
monetary and fiscal
policies.
To summarize, household debt in the
U.S. has grayed significantly over the last
several decades, caused by the nation’s
aging demographics and by the behavioral
responses of households to persistently
low real interest rates. This graying of
debt creates financial risks for relatively
old households. It also has important implications for policymakers as demographics
plays a role in households’ varying
consumption responses to changes in
wealth and income.

F I G U R E 10

Debt as a Share of Income Has Usually
Increased Faster than Debt as a Share of Assets

And because they are typically retired, old households
are more vulnerable to changes that deflate asset values.

Total debt holdings relative to assets and income by age group, 1989–2016
Average Total Debt Over Assets
2.0%

Median Total Debt Over Assets
2.0%
Young

1.5%

1.0%

1.0%
Middle-aged
0.5%

Old

0.0%

Federal Reserve Bank of Philadelphia
Research Department

Young

0.5%

Middle-aged
Old

0.0%
1989

1989

2016

Average Total Debt Over Income
2.0%

2016

Median Total Debt Over Income
2.0%
Middle-aged
Young
Old

1.5%

1.5%
Middle-aged
Young

1.0%

1.0%

Old
0.5%

0.5%
0.0%

1989

2016

0.0%

1989

2016

Source: Survey of Consumer Finances.

Why Interest Rates Have Declined
Since the 1980s, real interest rates in the
U.S. have steadily declined. There are
two explanations for this decline: the global
savings glut and secular stagnation.

rate consistent with output at potential—
leading to a chronically binding zero lower
bound. In other words, the economy has
a long-term lack of demand.10

In 2005, Fed Chair Ben Bernanke suggested
that a global savings glut, caused by
increased capital flows from crisis-prone
economies to the relatively safe haven of
the U.S., were responsible for the very low
longer-term interest rates in the U.S.

Both explanations almost certainly played
a role in the decline in real interest rates, and
so did an aging population. An aging population means a smaller working-age
population, which in turn leads to a reduction
in the economy’s productive capacity.
Hence, a lower real interest rate is needed to
support the economy. Furthermore, as life
expectancy increases, individuals save more,
which increases the supply of loanable
funds that banks can lend out and decreases
interest rates.11

In 2014, former U.S. Secretary of the
Treasury Larry Summers identified another
cause of persistently low interest rates:
secular stagnation, which he defined as
a persistently low or negative natural rate
of interest—the equilibrium real interest

6

1.5%

The Graying of Household Debt in the U.S.
2021 Q1

Notes
1 Baby Boomers are the demographic cohort
born from 1946 to 1964, during the postWorld War II spike in the national birth rate.
2 See, among others, Campbell and Cocco (2007)
and Li and Yao (2007) for detailed analyses and
discussions of the differential life-cycle marginal
propensities to consume out of wealth.
3 The empirical observations presented later
in the article are largely robust if we define old
households as those aged between 65 and
85 instead of 55 and 85. Not surprisingly, the
graying of household debt using this latter
definition would be less severe.

9 See Li and White (forthcoming). A higher likelihood of financial solvency doesn’t necessarily
imply lower welfare ex ante or before the
realization of house price shocks. It may simply
indicate that households are more effectively
using all financial options, including default,
to smooth their consumption in different economic situations.
10 This argument was later quantified by Eggertsson et al. (2019b). Demographic aging in
developed economies is one of the reasons behind the secular stagnation (Eggertsson 2019a).
11 For more detailed discussion see the article
by Carvalho et al. (2017) and papers cited in
the article.

4 See Bartscher et al. (2018).

American Debt,” in Olivia S. Mitchell and
Annamaria Lusardi, eds., Remaking Retirement:
Debt in an Aging Economy. Oxford, UK: Oxford
University Press, forthcoming.
Campbell, John Young, and João Cocco. “How
Do House Prices Affect Consumption? Evidence
from Micro Data,” Journal of Monetary Economics, 54 (2007), pp. 591–621, https://doi.org/
10.1016/j.jmoneco.2005.10.016.
Carvalho, Carlos, Andrea Ferrero, and Fernanda
Nechio. “Demographic Transition and Low U.S.
Interest Rates,” FRBSF Economic Letter (2017),
https://www.frbsf.org/economic-research/
publications/economic-letter/2017/september/
demographic-transition-and-low-us-interestrates.

12 See research cited in footnote 2.
5 See Brown et al. (forthcoming).
6 Throughout this article, I follow the SCF definition of household assets: the sum of financial
assets, such as stocks and bonds, and nonfinancial assets whose main component is the
value of the primary residence.
7 Brown et al. address recent and ongoing
trends in borrowing, repayment, and bankruptcy
among U.S. households, emphasizing the
relative financial stability of older households
and their repayment reliability.

References
Bartscher, Alina K., Moritz Kuhn, Moritz
Schularick, and Ulrike I. Steins. “Modigliani
Meets Minsky: American Household Debt,
1949–2016,” unpublished manuscript (2018).
Bernanke, Ben. “The Global Saving Glut and
the U.S. Current Deficit,” the Sandridge Lecture,
Virginia Association of Economists, Richmond,
Virginia, April 14, 2005.
Brown, Meta, Donghoon Lee, Joelle Scally,
and Wilbert van der Klaauw. “The Graying of

8 See Lusardi et al. (2018).

The Macroeconomic Perspective
Old households are more likely to consume
out of both wealth and income than are
middle-aged households but less likely than
are young households.12 This heterogeneity in consumption responses across age
groups implies that monetary and fiscal
policies will have different outcomes as the
U.S. population grows older.
For the ease of exposition, let’s compare
two hypothetical economies populated entirely by homeowners where 30 percent of
households are middle-aged. In one economy, 60 percent of households are young
and 10 percent are old. In the other, 10
percent are young but 60 percent are old.
Using a marginal propensity to consume
(MPC) of 10 percent for the young, 3 percent

for the middle-aged, and 6 percent for the
old, and assuming that an expansionary
monetary policy leads to a 100 percent
appreciation of house prices, total consumption would increase by 7.5 percent for
the first economy but only 5.5 percent for
the second. Since some states in the U.S.
age faster than others due to migration, this
heterogeneity across age groups in policy
transmission will translate into heterogeneity in policy response across geographical
regions.

Eggertsson, Gauti B., Manuel Lancastre, and
Lawrence H. Summers. “Aging, Output Per
Capita, and Secular Stagnation,” American
Economic Review—Insights, 1:3 (2019a), pp. 325–
342, https://doi.org/10.1257/aeri.20180383.
Eggertsson, Gauti B., Neil R. Mehrotra, and
Jacob Robbins. “A Model of Secular Stagnation:
Theory and Quantitative Evaluation,” American
Economic Journal: Macroeconomics, 11:1
(2019b), pp. 1–48, https://doi.org/10.1257/
mac.20170367.
Li, Wenli, and Rui Yao. “The Life-Cycle Effects of
House Price Changes,’’ Journal of Money, Credit,
and Banking, 39:6 (2007), pp. 1375–1409, https://
doi.org/10.1111/j.1538-4616.2007.00071.x.
Li, Wenli, and Michelle White. “Financial
Distress Among the Elderly: Bankruptcy Reform
and the Financial Crisis,” in Olivia S. Mitchell
and Annamaria Lusardi, eds., Remaking Retirement: Debt in an Aging Economy. Oxford, UK:
Oxford University Press, 2020.
Lusardi, Annamaria, Olivia S. Mitchell, and
Noemi Oggero. “The Changing Face of Debt
and Financial Fragility at Older Ages,” in
American Economic Association Papers and
Proceedings, 108 (2018), pp. 407–411,
https://doi.org/10.1257/pandp.20181117.
Summers, Lawrence. “U.S. Economic Prospects:
Secular Stagnation, Hysteresis, and the Zero
Lower Bound,” Business Economics, 49:2
(2014), pp. 65–73, https://doi.org/10.1057/
be.2014.13.

The Graying of Household Debt in the U.S.

2021 Q1

Federal Reserve Bank of Philadelphia
Research Department

7

Photo: Cindy Shebley/iStock

Isolating the Effect
of State Business
Closure Orders
on Employment

A closer look at the data reveals the extent to
which state policies in response to COVID-19
may have increased unemployment.

By Ryan Michaels
Economist and Economic Advisor
Federal Reserve Bank of Philadelphia
The views expressed in this article are not necessarily those of the Federal Reserve.

8

Federal Reserve Bank of Philadelphia
Research Department

I

n late 2020, numerous states again
imposed restrictions on business
activity and personal travel in order to
halt another wave of COVID-19 cases. These
policies represented the most significant
interventions since March and April of
2020, when almost all state governments
substantially restricted, if not outright
prohibited, the operation of businesses
in several industries. The economic effects of the “shutdowns” last spring can
potentially guide how we interpret the
effects of more recent policies and how
we shape mitigation efforts in future
public health crises.
However, the effect of such orders
on business activity, and in particular on
employment, is unclear. Even before states
intervened in March 2020, many fewer
consumers were visiting establishments
such as movie theaters, restaurants, and
salons as anxious households limited their
exposure to the coronavirus. Thus, even
in the absence of a business closure order,
it’s likely that these establishments would
have laid off workers. Can we isolate the
exact effect of state business closure orders
on employment?

Isolating the Effect of State Business Closure Orders on Employment
2021 Q1

A Taxonomy of Mitigation Policies

To mitigate the spread of the pandemic, state and local
governments sought to restrict business activity in
certain sectors. These restrictions took several forms,
some more comprehensive than others.
In many states, the initial closure orders targeted
only a few sectors in which social distancing was
viewed as impractical. The affected sectors included
amusement and recreation industries, which were
subject to limitations on large gatherings. Casinos,
museums, sports stadiums, and theaters typically
had to shut down. Food service establishments were
also nearly universally closed for dine-in. Personal
care establishments, such as barbershops and salons,
were often told to close, too.
Nearly 40 states went further and issued a broad
call to restrict business activity except in those sectors
deemed essential. These states published detailed
lists of essential-business exemptions; establishments
in sectors not on the list had to cease on-site operations. (An order is treated as an “essential list” if it
addresses a broad spectrum of industries. If an order
only addresses, say, inessential retail, as in New
Jersey, it is not classified as an essential list.) Telework
was permitted, so a nonessential designation did
not necessarily shut down all activity in a sector.
Following a burst of initial closure orders in midMarch, the issuance of essential-business lists
stretched out over three weeks in March and April
(Figure 1). Initial orders were adopted by most states
over the course of just a handful of days: Over half
of the states implemented such a policy on March 16
and March 17 alone. Among these same states, the
adoption of essential-business lists was spread over
the period of March 20 through March 30. In a few
cases, though, the two orders coincided: The essential list was also the first appreciable prohibition on
business activity.1
Although the initial closure orders likely weighed
on employment, I focus on the essential-business
lists to streamline the presentation. When I considered
the effects of both orders on job loss, the essential
lists, which affect a broader share of activity, proved
to be the more significant intervention.
Academics and the media have also written extensively on stay-at-home (SAH) orders, which directed
residents to shelter in place as much as possible.
(It was understood that some travel, such as trips to
the grocery store, was still necessary, and specific
recreational activities, such as outdoor exercise,
were permissible.) SAH orders were often issued in
conjunction with essential-business lists, but the two
did not always go hand in hand. In several states,
business closure orders preceded SAH mandates.
Pennsylvania, for example, closed “non-life-sustaining
businesses” on March 19—one of the first orders
of its kind in the U.S.—but its SAH order did not take

FIGURE 1

Most States Quickly Ordered at Least Some Businesses Closed
But it took longer for most to issue more-comprehensive essential lists.

Dates of first state-level business-closure order and state-level essential-business list, 2020
State and delay
between initial
order and lists

1st order
15

Ohio
California
Connecticut
DC
Delaware
Illinois
Indiana
Maryland
Michigan
New Hampshire
New Mexico
New York
Washington
Colorado
Hawaii
Kansas
Louisiana
Massachusetts
Minnesota
North Carolina
Vermont
Wisconsin
Kentucky
Maine
Missouri
Florida
Montana
Texas
West Virginia
Arizona
Tennessee
Alaska
Mississippi
Georgia
Alabama

8d
4d
7d
9d
8d
5d
9d
7d
8d
12d
7d
5d
7d
9d
8d
13d
6d
7d
8d
13d
8d
8d
8d
7d
6d
8d
8d
7d
4d
10d
9d
4d
10d
10d
7d

Pennsylvania
Nevada
Idaho
Oklahoma

0d
0d
0d
0d

New Jersey
South Carolina
Iowa
Oregon
Rhode Island
Utah
Arkansas
North Dakota
Wyoming
Virginia
Nebraska

N/A

MAR

Essential lists issued
22

1st week

MAR

2nd week

29
MAR

3rd week

Initial Orders Are Essential Lists

Did Not Issue Essential Lists
N/A
N/A
N/A
N/A
N/A
N/A
N/A
N/A
N/A
N/A

Did Not Issue Either
South Dakota

N/A

Source: Author’s tabulations based on published statements from Offices of the Governor and
state health departments. County-level orders used in some states.

Isolating the Effect of State Business Closure Orders on Employment

2021 Q1

Federal Reserve Bank of Philadelphia
Research Department

9

effect until April 1. Conversely, some states, such as Oregon
and Virginia, issued SAH orders but never published an extensive essential list.
Nevertheless, I focus on essential lists rather than SAH orders
because the lists more directly affect a broad base of employment.
Indeed, SAH orders per se did not restrict travel for employment
unless coupled with further prohibitions on nonessential
businesses. My decision deviates somewhat from the research
to date, which has tended to examine SAH orders. However,
several key results that I report do not depend significantly on
whether I consider SAH orders or essential lists.
In summary, many states substantially restricted business activity in March and April 2020 to mitigate the spread of COVID-19.
However, state policy was far from uniform, especially in regard
to essential-business lists. Twenty percent of states never issued
such a list, and among the other states, the timing of their
interventions varied. I will examine whether these differences in
timing led to differences in employment outcomes. But first,
it’s instructive to briefly consider the content of essential lists.

FIGURE 2

Essential Share of Employment Varies Across Sectors
Essential share of workers by sector, March 28, 2020
Management
Public Admin.
Extraction
Finance & Insurance
Utilities
Health Care
Transp. & Warehousing
Education
Ag. & Forestry
Construction
Information
Manufacturing
Real Estate and Rental Srvcs.
Wholesale Trade
Retail Trade
Admin. Support & Waste Mgmt.

60%

80% 100%

Other Srvcs.
Professional Srvcs.

The Content of Essential-Business Lists

Many states’ essential lists are informed by federal guidelines
issued by the Cybersecurity and Infrastructure Security Agency
(CISA) of the Department of Homeland Security. I linked the
textual descriptions in the CISA guidelines to standard industry
classifications (NAICS).2 I used the March 28 version of the guidelines, since this version was in force the longest before states
started to “reopen” their economies at the end of April. I found
that at least 69 percent of the U.S. workforce was classified as
essential according to CISA guidance.
However, the essential share of employment varies starkly
across economic sectors. In sectors such as utilities, banking,
and health care, nearly the entire workforce was classified as
essential. At the other end of the spectrum, essential shares were
zero, or nearly zero, in the food service and amusement/recreation sectors. Finally, among other sectors the essential share
varied, roughly, between 40 percent and 80 percent (Figure 2). In
some cases, such as professional services and administrative
support, the jobs can often be done from home, which illustrates
why nonessential status does not necessarily imply job displacement. A nonessential designation is more likely to imply the
stoppage of business activity in wholesale and retail trade; rental,
leasing, and other services; and manufacturing.
Many states adopted federal guidelines, but their lists were
far from uniform. Although I follow much of the research to date
by focusing on differences in the timing of states’ orders, the
scope of the orders also varied.3
A handful of states published lists of essential sectors using
a standard industry classification. These few states illustrate
the variation in the scope of essential classifications. At one end,
Vermont and Pennsylvania classified around 50 percent of their
workforce as essential. By contrast, the essential share of the workforce in Oklahoma is closer to 95 percent. Delaware is in the
middle, with an essential share of around 70 percent.
Essential shares could differ even among states whose essential lists consisted only of the sectors listed in the federal (CISA)

10

Federal Reserve Bank of Philadelphia
Research Department

Accommodation & Food Srvcs.
Entertainment
0%

20%

40%

69%

Source: Author’s classification of the Cybersecurity and Infrastructure Security
Agency’s March 28, 2020, memorandum on essential critical infrastructure workers.

guidelines. For instance, orders issued by Georgia and Michigan
largely mirrored CISA guidelines, but Michigan’s essential list
was issued earlier and based on the first (March 19) edition
of CISA guidance. After CISA substantially expanded the scope of
essential activities on March 28, Georgia adopted its guidance,
but Michigan did not incorporate CISA’s revisions. At the end of
March, the essential share of the workforce in Michigan was still
around 60 percent, but it was slightly over 70 percent in Georgia.4

Closure Orders and Job Losses

In March and April 2020, weekly unemployment insurance (UI)
claims reached previously unimagined heights. During just the
two weeks ending March 28, nearly 9 million workers filed an
initial UI claim. This figure represents 5.5 percent of the prepandemic labor force. Remarkably, another 11 million filed claims
in the succeeding two weeks.5
Importantly, the national data mask considerable differences
across states. Looking again at the two weeks ending March 28,
the UI claims rate—the number of initial claims relative to the
state’s prepandemic labor force—varied by a factor of five during
this period, ranging from over 11 percent in Pennsylvania and
Rhode Island to as low as 2 percent in South Dakota and West
Virginia. Might differences in state mitigation policies account for
some of this variation in initial claims?
Much of the research on this question applies a simple event
study framework, which attempts to uncover the effect of a
policy, or “event,” by comparing outcomes when the policy is
observed to outcomes when no policy is adopted. More exactly,

Isolating the Effect of State Business Closure Orders on Employment
2021 Q1

of the U.S.
workforce
classifies as
essential

the event study is implemented using a barebones statistical
(regression) model of, for example, initial UI claims. The model
relates the change in a state’s initial claims rate in any given
week to (i) the state’s own policy (in that week) as well as (ii)
a common “time effect,” which captures the average claims rate
across all states (in that week).
If a policy is to have an effect in this framework, it must lead
to higher initial claims upon its adoption (i) relative to the state’s
own claims rates at other dates and (ii) relative to the typical
change in claims observed across all states at that time (as captured by the time effects). In our context, the driving force
behind these common time effects is the evolving public health
risk posed by COVID-19.
Perhaps surprisingly, this event study model omits any
mention of a state’s own recent growth in COVID-19 cases. I considered the role of caseloads but found its effect to be almost
negligible, which is consistent with the results found by University
of California economists Zhixian Lin and Christopher M. Meissner.
Variation in the timing of the orders appears to reflect differences in states’ responses to a given caseload rather than big
differences in caseloads themselves. To illustrate this point,
consider that when California issued the nation’s first SAH order
on March 19, it had registered roughly the same number of
cases per 100,000 residents as Arkansas—yet Arkansas never
issued an SAH order (or any order like it).
Following recent research, I used this event study framework
to examine the effect of a specific policy, essential-business lists,
on job loss in March and April 2020. I considered three separate
indicators of job loss, starting with initial UI claims.

Weekly Initial Claims
I used weekly data on initial claims over a three-month window
around mid-March, when the first essential lists were introduced.
Each observation in the data refers to the number of initial
claims filed between a Sunday and the subsequent Saturday. The
sample includes all 50 states plus the District of Columbia (Figure 3). Thus, the sample consists of states that issued essential
lists at different times as well as states that never issued a list.6
Note that since we measure weekly claims, the date of a new
policy corresponds to the week in which it was introduced.7
Thus, the immediate impact of a policy will partly reflect when
in the week states enact it, since the effect is likely to be larger
if the policy is in force for more of the period. With the exception
of the week of March 15, when a handful of states introduced
an essential list, the dates of enactment were distributed roughly
evenly throughout a week. On average, an essential list was
implemented on the third day of the week.
Based on the event study analysis, I calculated paths for the
initial claims under two scenarios (Figure 4). One estimate (burgundy line) is the claims rate that would have been observed if
states had not enacted the essential list. The other estimate (pink
line) accounts for the policy. Thus, the difference between the
two paths indicates the effect of the essential list. Lastly, the pink
shaded area represents a “confidence band”: Every estimate is
uncertain, but there is a 90 percent probability that the “true”
path of claims implied by the essential list lies within this band.8

FIGURE 3

Weekly UI Claims Rates Varied Substantially
Across U.S. States
Number of initial unemployment insurance claims relative to the
state's prepandemic labor force, 2020
8%

6%

4%

West Virginia
Rhode Island

2%

0%

Pennsylvania
South Dakota
7

MAR

14

MAR

21

MAR

28
MAR

4

APR

11

APR

18
APR

25

APR

Source: Harvard’s Opportunity Insights institute based on the Employment and
Training Administration’s release of weekly initial unemployment claims and the
Bureau of Labor Statistics’ estimates of 2019 state labor force levels.

FIGURE 4

The Closure of Nonessential Businesses Is Associated
with an Increase in the Initial Claims Rate
Estimated change in initial unemployment insurance claim rate (percent) before
and after state enacts an essential-business list, two scenarios
5%

4%

3%
With closure
order

2%

Without
closure order
1%

0%

−1%

4 wks

2 wks

0 wks

← Weeks before enactment

2 wks

4 wks

Weeks after enactment →

Source: Author’s estimates of event study model using weekly initial unemployment insurance claims from Harvard‘s Opportunity Insights institute.
Note: There is a 90 percent probability that the “true” path of claims implied by
the essential list lies within the shaded band.

Isolating the Effect of State Business Closure Orders on Employment

2021 Q1

Federal Reserve Bank of Philadelphia
Research Department

11

The closure of nonessential businesses is associated with an
increase in the initial claims rate. The claims rate in week 0—that
is, the week when the essential list was enacted—is predicted
to be 3.7 percent (pink line in Figure 4), whereas it would have
been roughly 2.8 percent in the absence of a policy (burgundy
line). This difference of nearly 1 percentage point between the
two estimates measures the effect of the policy. The impact of
the policy persists but diminishes in subsequent weeks. The
cumulative effect of the policy across all five weeks (that is, weeks
0–4) is just over 3.5 percentage points.9 However, the overall
claims rate rose by 14.5 percentage points over this period. By
this measure, essential lists account for no more than 25 percent
of total claims.10
The data also show, however, that initial claims generally
started to rise even before states issued their essential lists.
Importantly, this increase appears to reflect the common “time
effects” in the event study framework, which capture the average
claims rate across states independent of mitigation policy. That
is, this increase is predicted to occur even if a state did not enact
an essential list (burgundy line in Figure 4). This rise in the
average claims rate before week 0 presumably reflects concerns
about the spread of the coronavirus, which prompted households across all states to curtail their commercial and social
activities. The estimated effect of the policy (the difference
between the pink and burgundy lines) remains small prior to
week 0 and cannot be distinguished from zero with any confidence. This is an important observation: If job loss accelerated
more in policy-adopting states before essential lists took effect,
one might worry that policy merely coincided with a relative
decline in employment that was ongoing in those states and
would have continued in any case. According to these estimates,
though, this pattern, known as a pre-event trend, is not clearly
evident in the policy-adopting states.
Redoing this analysis using SAH orders yields broadly similar
findings, with two qualifications. First, the effects of SAH orders in
weeks 0–4 are even somewhat larger than I find when using
essential lists. However, and secondly, I also find more significant
pre-event trends, consistent with the fact that, in several states,
SAH orders were issued later than essential lists and after
substantial job losses.11
Differences in policies contribute to, but are not the key driver
of, the increase in initial claims. Much, though not all, of the
earlier research into mitigation policies also concluded that they
were a secondary factor behind job loss. For example, University
of Illinois economist Eliza Forsythe and her coauthors conclude
that the most striking aspect of the data is the broad-based
decline in employment across states and sectors “regardless of
the timing of stay-at-home policies.” Lin and Meissner report that
“there is no evidence that stay-at-home policies led to stronger
rises in jobless claims,” an even starker conclusion than my own.12
Indiana University economist Sumedha Gupta and her coauthors
consider SAH orders as well as interventions akin to what I have
termed initial closures, which often applied narrowly to certain
retail and recreational establishments. They find that initial
closures did increase claims in the week in which the policy was
adopted, but the estimated effect of the policy amounted to 15–20
percent of the overall increase in claims.13

12

Federal Reserve Bank of Philadelphia
Research Department

Weekly Private Sector Employment
Aside from initial UI claims, the labor market indicators published
by the U.S. government are available, at best, on a monthly
basis. Monthly data are even less suitable than weekly data for
an event study of the COVID-19 crisis, which evolved rapidly in
March and April.
Fortunately, Harvard’s Opportunity Insights institute has
made available state-level employment data at a higher frequency.
The institute culled the data from payroll-processing firms,
time-tracking software, and paycheck deposits. The employment
records cover a reasonably representative cross section of the
nonfarm private sector.14
In principle, the employment series is daily. However, the
data are reported as a seven-day moving average, making it
akin to a weekly series. Indeed, we can extract from the moving
average a measure of weekly employment growth between
each Sunday and Saturday. This weekly format matches the
structure of the initial claims data. Also, the seven-day decline
in employment is close in concept to initial claims, which is
a measure of the number of newly unemployed.15
An event-study analysis of these employment data indicates
that closure orders added about 1 percentage point to the
decline in employment in the week they took effect (week 0).

FIGURE 5

Closure Orders Added About 1 Percentage Point to the
Decline in Employment in the Week They Took Effect

Estimated change in employment (percent) before and after state enacts essentialbusiness list, two scenarios
4%

2%

With closure
order
Without
closure order

0%

−2%

−4%

−6%

−8%
−10%

4 wks

2 wks

0 wks

← Weeks before enactment

2 wks

4 wks

Weeks after enactment →

Source: Author’s estimates of event study model using Harvard's Opportunity
Insights institute’s reports of state-level employment growth.
Note: There is a 90 percent probability that the “true” path of claims implied by
the essential list lies within the shaded band.

Isolating the Effect of State Business Closure Orders on Employment
2021 Q1

This estimate (Figure 5) is nearly identical to what we observed
when we considered the effect of essential lists on initial UI
claims (Figure 4).
However, the cumulative effect of the closure orders over
subsequent weeks is somewhat smaller than what was implied by
our analysis of UI claims. In total, closures contributed a 2.5
percentage point decline in employment, which represents just
15 percent of the job loss over this period.
Importantly, the effects of the closure orders are also estimated less precisely than in the case of UI claims. This result is
illustrated by the width of the confidence band, which now
indicates that there is no significant difference between the
path implied by the closure orders and the path employment
would have followed in the absence of any mitigation policy.

Small-Business Employment
The COVID-19 crisis has taken a particularly large toll on small
firms in the U.S. For businesses with fewer than 50 workers,
employment fell over 25 percent in March and April—almost twice
the rate observed for larger employers.16 The causes of job loss
in smaller businesses is thus of special interest.

FIGURE 6

Employment in Small Businesses Fell More and
Earlier Than in the Corporate Sector as a Whole

Estimated cumulative change in employment (percent) in small businesses
before and after state enacts essential-business list, two scenarios
20%
10%
0%
−10%
−20%
−30%
Without
closure order

−40%
−50%

With closure
order

−60%
−70%
−80%

21 d

14 d

7d

0d

← Days before enactment

7d

14 d

21 d 28 d

Days after enactment →

Source: Author’s estimate of event study model using daily employment data
from Homebase (https://joinhomebase.com).
Note: There is a 90 percent probability that the “true” path of claims implied by
the essential list lies within the shaded band.

To measure job loss in smaller businesses, I drew on data from
the software company Homebase, whose scheduling app is
used by clients to track employees’ hours worked.17 Homebase
covered some 60,000 small firms at the onset of the pandemic
and provides daily data on employees’ hours worked, which
allows us to more precisely relate employment outcomes to the
timing of state policies. A drawback of the data is that Homebase
clients represent only a segment of the broader small-business
community: Homebase clients are disproportionately drawn from
the food service sector and are relatively small (even for small
businesses), averaging only five employees prior to the pandemic.
Employment among Homebase clients also fell far more, and
much earlier, than in the corporate sector as a whole: It fell
45 percent prior to the enactment of any essential lists (burgundy
line in Figure 6). This collapse in employment among small
food service and retail firms, which occurred in the first three
weeks of March, is likely due to the steep decline in consumer
traffic observed in all states as households sought to limit their
exposure to the virus. Indeed, reports of consumer traffic at
retail and recreational establishments show declines of 40 percent during this period.18 Small businesses have relatively little
cash on hand to meet expenses when revenues fall so steeply,
triggering job losses.19
Still, when an essential list is introduced, its impact on
Homebase clients is immediate and significant: Employment falls
6 percent and then declines further in the next several days. On
average, the essential list depresses employment by almost 10
percent over the subsequent month (the difference between the
pink and burgundy lines in Figure 6). However, even in the absence of a policy, the pandemic would have reduced employment
by 55 percent on average over this same period (the burgundy
line in Figure 6). Thus, the essential list accounts for 15–20 percent of the overall decline. The estimated share of job losses
due to the orders is consistent with the earlier results reported
in Figure 5 based on employment for a broader set of firms.20
These results largely confirm estimates in earlier research.
For their 2020 Brookings paper, University of Illinois economist
Alexander W. Bartik and his coauthors conducted virtually
the same event study analysis of Homebase data but used SAH
orders. They found that the effects of SAH orders were just
as persistent but somewhat larger than were the effects implied
by my analysis. However, they caution that such persistent
effects of a mitigation policy may be difficult to disentangle from
other trends in the state’s response to COVID-19. If such trends
are in force, the authors show, the effect of the policy after 10
days is less than half as large and then largely dissipates over the
next two weeks.
New York University economist Hunt Allcott and his coauthors
assessed mitigation policies on COVID-19 case rates, consumer
traffic, and employment outcomes, though I focus on their analysis of Homebase data. These authors collected SAH orders
for all counties, which tightens the link between the governing
policy in an area and the area’s economic outcomes. Still, the
results of my analysis of Homebase data are largely consistent
with their estimated effects and with the implied contribution
of SAH orders to the overall decline in employment.21

Isolating the Effect of State Business Closure Orders on Employment

2021 Q1

Federal Reserve Bank of Philadelphia
Research Department

13

Final Thoughts

nonfarm payroll numbers are derived. It is not immediately
clear how to reconcile these results with those based on other
employment indicators. Daily and weekly employment data
have generally been preferred in prior research, because it’s
possible to draw a tighter link between the enactment of policies
and employment outcomes. Still, these results based on monthly
data merit further attention.23

In this article, I have reviewed the effect of states’ COVID-19 mitigation policies that targeted business activity. I considered in
particular the degree to which essential-business lists contributed
to the historic rates of job loss observed in March and April 2020.
I conducted this analysis within a popular
event study framework featured in numerous research papers on COVID-19. I found
Estimated increase
that the effects of the policies vary someof essential business
what across employment indicators, but
shutdown orders on
job losses
on balance the results suggest that they
increased job losses by 15–25 percent.
This article has merely scratched the surface of the burgeoning
research on the economic effects of COVID-19 mitigation policy.
Indeed, this review, which has focused on the labor market, has
had to largely bypass related analyses of consumer activity.22
Clearly, a more integrated analysis of employment and expenditures would be worthwhile. In the meantime, I close with a few
remarks on related labor market research I did not have the space
to cover in detail.

Reopenings
A more complete evaluation of mitigation policies must also
consider the effect of lifting such mandates. Economist Raj Chetty
and his coauthors at Harvard’s Opportunity Insights institute
estimate a 1.5 percent gain in employment within two weeks
of lifting an SAH order. Interestingly, the absolute size of this effect
is smaller than, but not much different from, what I find when
looking at the effect of imposing a closure order. Estimates from
Bartik and Allcott (and their respective coauthors) also suggest
that, on balance, the effects of lifting closure policies were somewhat smaller than the effects of imposing the policies.

Job Loss
The evidence on job loss is still not settled. Whereas I have examined daily and weekly data, two studies report larger effects of
SAH orders using two prominent sources of monthly employment
data. Gupta and her coauthors examine the Current Population
Survey, which is the official source of the unemployment rate.
They find that if a state had been under an SAH order for 20
days as of mid-April, its employment rate was 3.5 percentage
points lower. This estimate represents more than 40 percent
of the decline in employment between March and April. Forsythe
and her coauthors also find relatively large effects in the monthly
Current Employment Statistics survey, from which official

Recent Policy Actions
The findings reported here and elsewhere can help interpret
recent labor market activity. There has been a deceleration in
employment growth in recent months, during which many
localities reimposed restrictions on entertainment, recreation,
and food services establishments. Research to date would
suggest that these restrictions contributed to the slowdown,
though recent policies were more targeted than the business
closure orders in March and April. However, a lesson from prior
work is that the key driver of labor market activity is likely
the substantial escalation in the spread of COVID-19 itself. Still,
further research is needed on these recent policy actions.

15–25%

Notes
1 Consider the case of Pennsylvania. Prior to publishing its essential list,
the state’s only restriction on business activity was a prohibition on
indoor dining. By contrast, initial orders in many other states effectively
shuttered the amusement and recreation sectors through limits on
gatherings and closed personal care services. In order to enforce a degree
of consistency in coding initial closures, I did not classify closing indoor
dining alone as an initial order. Accordingly, Pennsylvania’s initial closure
order is also its essential list.
2 See also Tomer and Kane (2020a, 2020b).
3 The data set underlying Atalay et al. (2020) attempts to capture much
of the variation across states and counties in the scope of their closure
and reopening orders.

14

Federal Reserve Bank of Philadelphia
Research Department

4 The “exposure” of workers to a mitigation policy can also differ across
states even if the policy is the same. For example, a given policy can have
disparate effects based on the feasibility of telework. This cross-state
variation will be considered in future research. For more on telework, see
Blau et al. (2020), who combine CISA guidance with Dingel and Neiman’s
(2020) estimates of the feasibility of telework to identify frontline workers,
the subset of essential workers who are most likely to have to work on site.
5 In March 2020, Congress temporarily extended UI eligibility to many
more workers, such as independent contractors, and increased UI
compensation. This decision surely contributed to the eightfold increase
in weekly initial claims relative to the Great Recession. However, much
of this increase reflected heightened job loss rather than a greater
propensity among the laid off to apply for, and receive, UI. The Current

Isolating the Effect of State Business Closure Orders on Employment
2021 Q1

Population Survey shows, for instance, that the number of
newly unemployed rose sixfold relative to the Great Recession.

and Karger’s results suggest that a broader county-level
analysis may be worthwhile.

6 I determined the timing of an essential list according to
county policies for six states where at least half of the
population was under county orders by the time the statewide policy was enacted. The six states were California,
Florida, Kansas, Missouri, Texas, and Utah. For detailed
analyses of the effects of county and city SAH orders on
consumer activity, see Alexander and Karger (2020) and
Goolsbee and Syverson (2020).

12 This difference in emphasis likely stems from various discrepancies in the statistical models we used. One difference
is that Lin and Meissner examine changes in the natural
logarithm of initial claims, whereas I consider changes in
the claims rate, or claims as a share of the labor force. The
natural log function can compress changes in claims
relative to the claims rate. For example, the log of claims in
North Dakota and Pennsylvania increased equally in the
latter half of March even though the change in the claims
rate in Pennsylvania was twice as large as in North Dakota.
The effect of Pennsylvania’s early business-closure policy
is more evident in the claims rate.

7 More specifically, I assume an essential list applies to
a week as long as it is enacted before the final day of the
week (i.e., by Friday). This approach recognizes that essential
lists can take effect near the end of a day, so it may be infeasible to apply for UI that week if the policy is implemented
on Saturday. Alternatively, one could assume a policy
applies to a given week only if it was introduced nearer to
the start of the week, as in Gupta et al. (2020). When I do
this, I find that the immediate effect of an essential list is
larger, as anticipated. However, the effect of the list is also
estimated to be significant even before it is introduced,
which makes sense: The list was indeed in effect before the
week marked as the date of enactment.
8 Figure 4, and related figures in this article, are computed
as follows. I draw a vector of parameter values based on
the covariance matrix of the regression estimates, and then
calculate a predicted path of the claims rate for each
policy-adopting state. The path underlying the burgundy
line is computed using only the time effects, whereas the
path underlying the pink line also accounts for the policy
effects. The calculation of each path (burgundy and pink)
takes account of the timing of the state’s order and is then
expressed in terms of weeks from the date of the order.
I compute an unweighted average of each path across
states, draw another parameter vector, and repeat. The
figure illustrates the typical path across 500 draws, and
the confidence band encompasses 90 percent of the
simulated observations.
9 If I extend the horizon beyond four weeks, the sample will
overlap with the period of the first “reopening” orders.
I wish to focus here on job loss and so avoid any interaction
with the reopening period.
10 These results persist, and indeed strengthen somewhat,
if I drop from the sample the 10 states that never issued
an essential list. Thus, the variation in the timing of orders
among essential-list-issuing states is sufficient to identify
an effect of the list.
11 Importantly, Alexander and Karger (2020) do not find
pretrends when they examine the effect of county-level
SAHs on consumer traffic and expenditure. Initial UI claims
by county can be collected from each state, and Alexander

13 Both Forsythe et al. and Gupta et al. find larger effects
of SAH orders when examining monthly data. I return to this
point a little later.
14 See Chetty et al. (2020).
15 Let nt be the number of workers at a firm on day t;
the 7-day moving average; and m the
January average. In the data, we see gt ≡ mt /m−1. Dividing
gt by gt−1 and making a few manipulations shows that
. We observe the right side of
this equation. Recalling the definition of mt , the left side is
equivalent to
. Multiplying by 7 yields a measure
of employment growth between day t−7 and day t.
16 See Cajner et al. (2020). Bartik et al. (2020b) estimate an
even faster rate of decline, although entertainment and recreation establishments are overrepresented in their survey.
17 In using Homebase (https://joinhomebase.com) data to
chart the effect of the pandemic on small businesses, I’m
following the example set by other researchers, including
Bartik et al. (2020b), Allcott et al. (2020), and Kurman et al.
(2020).
18 This estimate is based on the Mobility Reports published
by Google and derived from the Location History data of
Google users. Analyses of similar data from different vendors
(e.g., SafeGraph) have the same basic message. See Goolsbee
and Syverson (2020).
19 See Bartik et al. (2020a).
20 The initial closure orders, which typically targeted food
service and recreational establishments, do not appear to
have had a significant, immediate effect on the employment
of Homebase clients. In separate event study estimates, the
impact of the initial orders is not clear until seven days or
so after their enactment, by which point states had begun to
issue essential lists. A clear and immediate effect of the
initial orders may be difficult to detect using only differences

Isolating the Effect of State Business Closure Orders on Employment

2021 Q1

Federal Reserve Bank of Philadelphia
Research Department

15

in the timing of the orders; many states issued such orders
on very nearly the same day.
21 These authors also look at closure orders. But again, the
closure orders in this case—restrictions on “gathering venues
for in-person services”—are probably akin to what I call the
initial closures rather than to the broader essential-business
lists.
22 See, among others, Alexander and Karger (2020), Baker et
al. (2020), Coibion et al. (2020), and Goolsbee and Syverson
(2020).
23 See also Coibion et al. (2020), who report relatively large
labor market and consumer expenditure effects based on
a series of customized surveys.

References
Alexander, Diane, and Ezra Karger. “Do Stay-at-Home
Orders Cause People to Stay at Home? Effects of Stay-atHome Orders on Consumer Behavior,” Federal Reserve Bank
of Chicago Working Paper No. 2020-12 (2020), https://doi.
org/10.21033/wp-2020-12.
Allcott, Hunt, Levi Boxell, Jacob Conway, et al. “What
Explains Temporal and Geographic Variation in the Early US
Coronavirus Pandemic?” mimeo (2020).
Atalay, Enghin, Shigeru Fujita, Sreyas Mahadevan, et al.
“Reopening the Economy: What Are the Risks, and What
Have States Done?” Federal Reserve Bank of Philadelphia
Research Brief (July 2020), https://doi.org/10.21799/frbp.
rb.2020.jul.
Baker, Scott R., R.A. Farrokhnia, Steffen Meyer, et al. “How
Does Household Spending Respond to an Epidemic?
Consumption During the 2020 COVID-19 Pandemic,” Review
of Asset Pricing Studies, 10:4 (2020), pp. 834–862, https://
doi.org/10.1093/rapstu/raaa009.

Cajner, Tomaz, Leland D. Crane, Ryan A. Decker, et al. “The
US Labor Market During the Beginning of the Pandemic
Recession,” National Bureau of Economic Research Working
Paper 27159 (2020), http://doi.org/10.3386/w27159.
Chetty, Raj, John N. Friedman, Nathaniel Hendren, and
Michael Stepner. “The Economic Impacts of COVID-19:
Evidence From a New Public Database Built from Private
Sector Data,” Opportunity Insights (2020).
Coibion, Olivier, Yuriy Gorodnichenko, and Michael Weber.
“The Cost of the Covid-19 Crisis: Lockdowns, Macroeconomic
Expectations, and Consumer Spending,” National Bureau of
Economic Research Working Paper No. 27141 (2020), https://
doi.org/10.3386/w27141.
Dingel, J. I., and Brent Neiman. “How Many Jobs Can Be
Done at Home?” Journal of Public Economics, 189 (2020),
https://doi.org/10.1016/j.jpubeco.2020.104235.
Forsythe, Eliza, Lisa B. Kahn, Fabian Lange, and David
Wiczer. “Labor Demand in the Time of COVID-19: Evidence
From Vacancy Postings and UI Claims,” Journal of Public
Economics, 189 (2020), https://doi.org/10.1016/j.jpubeco.
2020.104238.
Goolsbee, Austan, and Chad Syverson. “Fear, Lockdown,
and Diversion: Comparing Drivers of Pandemic Economic
Decline 2020,” National Bureau of Economic Research
Working Paper 27432 (2020), https://doi.org/10.3386/
w27432.
Gupta, Sumedha, Laura Montenovo, Thuy D. Nguyen, et
al. “Effects of Social Distancing Policy on Labor Market
Outcomes,” National Bureau of Economic Research Working
Paper 27280 (2020), https://doi.org/10.3386/w27280.
Kurmann, Andre, Etienne Lalé, and Lien Ta. “The Impact
of COVID-19 on Small Business Employment and Hours:
Real-Time Estimates with Homebase Data,” mimeo (2020).

Bartik, Alexander W., Marianne Bertrand, Zoe Cullen, et al.
“The Impact of COVID-19 on Small Business Outcomes
and Expectations,” Proceedings of the Natural Academy of
Sciences, pp. 117–130 (2020a).

Lin, Zhixian, and Christopher M. Meissner. “Health vs. Wealth?
Public Health Policies and the Economy During Covid-19,”
National Bureau of Economic Research Working Paper 27099
(2020), https://doi.org/10.3386/w27099.

Bartik, Alexander W., Marianne Bertrand, Feng Lin, et al.
“Measuring the Labor Market at the Onset of the COVID-19
Crisis,” Brookings Papers on Economic Activity (2020b).

Tomer, Adie, and Joseph W. Kane. “How to Protect Essential
Workers During COVID-19,” Brookings Institution Report
(2020a).

Blau, Francine D., Josefine Koebe, and Pamela A. Meyerhofer. “Who Are the Essential and Frontline Workers?”
National Bureau of Economic Research Working Paper No.
27791 (2020), https://doi.org/10.3386/w27791.

Tomer, Adie, and Joseph W. Kane. “To Protect Frontline
Workers During and After COVID-19, We Must Define Who
They Are,” Brookings Institution Report (2020b).

16

Isolating the Effect of State Business Closure Orders on Employment

Federal Reserve Bank of Philadelphia
Research Department

2021 Q1

Photo: slobo/iStock

Banking Trends

How and Why
Bank Capital
Ratios Change
Over the
Business Cycle

Small-bank and large-bank
capital ratios behave
quite differently. To understand the difference, look
at the data.
By PJ Elliott
Banking Structure Associate
Federal Reserve Bank of Philadelphia
The views expressed in this article are not necessarily those of the Federal Reserve.

Banking Trends: How and Why Bank Capital Ratios Change Over the Business Cycle
2021 Q1

Federal Reserve Bank of Philadelphia
Research Department

17

B

ank capital is one key measure of a bank’s health. Capital
is an indicator of a bank’s value, and in a recession, it can
help cover losses and allow the bank to remain viable.
During an economic downturn, undercapitalized banks may
have to sell assets, restrict their lending, or worse, fail. These
actions can deepen a recession, creating ripple effects throughout the region or even nationally, economically impacting the
average bank customer. In a recession, a weak capital position
not only can hurt a bank’s own profits but also can pose problems for other banks and for the economy as a whole.1 Do
banks’ capital decisions during upturns anticipate such an
event, or might they worsen these effects? To shed some light on
this question, I closely examine the data and answer the following
questions: How do bank capital ratios—their capital divided
by assets—change over the business cycle in the U.S.? And what
factors drive the changes in bank capital ratios?
In aggregate, I find that capital ratios fall when GDP rises.
However, since 2000, the top 1 percent of banks have held over
70 percent of assets, reaching a high of 80 percent, so I examine
this correlation for different groups of the asset distribution.
At the largest banks—the top 1 percent of the asset distribution—
there is an inverse, or countercyclical, relationship between the
bank’s capital ratio and GDP growth. As GDP grows more quickly,
capital ratios at the largest banks tend to fall, and this drives
the results across the entire industry. At the smallest banks—the
bottom 50 percent—the relationship is procyclical. As GDP grows
more quickly, small-bank capital ratios tend to also rise.
This raises the question: Which part of the capital ratio is
responding to changes in GDP? It could be assets, capital, or some
combination. I find that the assets of large banks grow faster
than GDP when GDP is growing, whereas the assets of small banks
grow more slowly than GDP. Further, I find some evidence that
large banks invest in riskier assets as GDP increases.
These results provide some support for efforts to pursue more
targeted financial regulation. Since the 1980s, minimum capital
ratios have been a feature of banking regulation for all banks.
Since the Great Recession, banking regulation has shifted focus
to creating regulation for some of the
largest financial institutions. By imposing
See The Largest
more regulations specifically on the global
Banks Are
systemically important banks (GSIBs),
Subject to Difregulators aim to safeguard against industryferent Capital
wide concerns without imposing an undue
Requirements.
burden on smaller banks for which the
cost of complying with regulations can be very expensive.2 This
article provides some support for this type of regulation, as the
data documented here demonstrate key differences in priorities
for banks of varying sizes over the business cycle.

0–25%
25–50%
50–75%
75–90%
0

90–95% 95–99%

In Aggregate, Bank Capital Ratios
Are Countercyclical

Regulators monitor various measures of capital adequacy, the
aforementioned capital ratios. The most important of these
are the Risk-Weighted Capital Ratio and the Leverage Ratio.
Both measure Tier 1 Capital—also known as core capital—which
is mostly made up of common stock and retained earnings.
However, these ratios differ in the measurement of assets.

Risk-Weighted Capital Ratio =
Tier 1 Capital / Risk-Weighted Assets
The Risk-Weighted Capital Ratio accounts for the riskiness of
a bank’s assets. For example, a Treasury security is one of the
safest assets a bank can hold, since it has a very low likelihood
of defaulting; therefore, it is weighted 0 percent. A commercial
loan is riskier, with a significant likelihood of default, so its
risk weight is 100 percent. If a bank holds $100 of Treasury
bonds and $100 of commercial loans, its risk-weighted assets are
$100 = $100 x (0%) + $100 x (100%).
There’s a strong argument for taking account of the risk of
default in determining a bank’s capital adequacy, but regulators
find it especially difficult to quantify these risks accurately.
Banks have an incentive to shift their portfolios toward assets
whose risk exceeds the assigned risk weights, because riskier
assets have a higher return than safer assets. Even the bestdesigned regulatory risk weights can’t fully account for all risks,
especially when banks that are better informed than regulators
about their own portfolios can profit by taking more risks.3 So
capital requirements also use a more naïve measure of assets.
Leverage Ratio = Tier 1 Capital / Assets
The Leverage Ratio considers all assets, without regard to their
riskiness. Regulatory monitoring of this metric helps safeguard
against rapid growth in unsafe portfolio strategies, as rapid
growth in portfolio risk might not be captured in the RiskWeighted Capital Ratio. Again, in our simplified example, if a bank
holds $100 of Treasury bonds and $100 of commercial loans, its
assets are $200 = $100 × (100%) + $100 × (100%).
I first constructed aggregated capital ratios using quarterly
Call Report data for commercial banks.4 The aggregate ratio is the
sum of Tier 1 Capital across all banks, divided by the sum of
assets for all banks for each quarter from 1996 to 2019. Since
the economy is growing on average, we need some way to distinguish periods in which the economy is growing more quickly
than average (an upturn) from periods in which the economy is
growing more slowly than average (a downturn). To do this,
I separate the growth trend from the business cycle for the capital
ratios and for the log of real GDP from the U.S. Bureau of Economic Analysis (BEA) via Haver Analytics.5 As GDP rises relative
to trend, bank capital ratios tend to fall, regardless of whether
we consider total assets or risk-weighted assets. Like others who

FIGURE 1

The Gap Between the Largest and Smallest Banks Is Exceptionally Large
Average real assets (millions $) by bin, 2019; each bin represents percentage of banks by size of assets
25,000

50,000

75,000

100,000

125,000

Source: Call Reports aggregated and available through the National Information Center (NIC) of the Federal Reserve System.

18

Federal Reserve Bank of Philadelphia
Research Department

Banking Trends: How and Why Bank Capital Ratios Change Over the Business Cycle
2021 Q1

150,000

have examined bank capital ratios, I find
that, in aggregate, bank capital is countercyclical to GDP.6

However, the Largest
and Smallest Banks
Behave Differently

A fundamental fact of the U.S. banking
industry is that small banks hold more
capital relative to assets than large banks.
Large banks have more diverse portfolios,
so they can participate in more industrial sectors and geographic areas than
small banks. Everything else being equal,
a bank with a diversified portfolio has
lower risk and can safely hold less capital.
When the oil and gas (O&G) industry suffers a downturn, a very large bank may
face some losses on its O&G portfolio, but
a small bank in Fort Worth, Texas, may
sustain huge losses on its entire portfolio.
I find that large and small banks’ capital ratios also change differently as GDP
changes (Figure 2).7 I divide banks into
seven bins based on their assets. Asset
percentiles keep the bin sizes proportional to the total number of banks, which has
been declining during the sample period.
For the top 1 percent of banks, which
declined in number from 120 to 60 institutions over the 30-year sample, both the
Leverage Ratio and Risk-Weighted Capital
Ratio move countercyclically, and the
relationship is statistically significant.8 Both
capital ratios also move countercyclically
for the top 5 percent of banks, although
the relationship is statistically significant
only for the Risk-Weighted Capital Ratio. In
contrast, for the bottom 75 percent of
banks, which are considerably smaller,
both capital ratios move procyclically.9
Why do small-bank capital ratios move
procyclically while capital ratios move
countercyclically in the aggregate? It is
important to remember exactly how big
a bank in the top 1 percent is compared
to a bank in the bottom 25 percent. For
example, in 2019, a bank in the top 1 percent had an average $287 billion in real
assets compared to the $63 million for the

average bank in the bottom 25 percent
(Figure 1). So, when banks are aggregated,
the largest banks, which hold the largest
share of assets, also dominate the relationship for capital ratios. Yet the capital
ratios of 75 percent of banks actually have
a procyclical relationship with GDP.

Differences in Both Asset and
Capital Growth Explain This
Divergent Relationship

Recall that the capital ratios have both
a numerator (Tier 1 Capital) and a denominator (either risk-weighted assets or total
assets). It is worthwhile to consider
whether one of these variables drives
the capital ratio changes over the business
cycle more than another. For example,
one possible reason why large banks’
capital ratio might fall is that large banks
are more aggressive than small banks in
paying out retained earnings to their
stockholders when the economy is growing. That is, the changes in the numerator
are the main source of difference between

large and small banks. Alternatively, largebank capital ratios might fall because
assets (either risk-weighted or unweighted)—
the denominator—grow faster than GDP.
Are the differences between large and
small banks driven by different payout
policies or by different opportunities for
expanding business?10
Large banks’ Tier 1 Capital is negatively
correlated with GDP, but the correlation is
statistically insignificant—that is, the
relationship is relatively weak. On the other
hand, assets and GDP are strongly positively correlated for large banks (Figure 3).
For large banks, the negative relationship
between the ratios and GDP, therefore, is
driven primarily by their assets’ stronger
response to business cycle fluctuations. In
addition, risk-weighted assets are positively
correlated with GDP for the largest 1 percent of banks. The positive relationship
between risk-weighted assets and GDP
indicates that large-bank portfolios are
not only growing larger but also increasing
in riskiness.

FIGURE 2

Assets at the Largest Banks Grow with GDP, Lowering the Leverage Ratio

At the smallest, assets shrink and capital grows as GDP grows, raising their leverage ratio.
Change in leverage ratio for largest and smallest banks, compared to change in GDP
Top 1%

Smallest 25%

Detrended GDP growth

0.03
0.02
0.01
0.00
−0.01
−0.02
−0.03

1996

2000

2005

2010

2015

2019

Source: Call Reports aggregated and available through the National Information Center (NIC) of the Federal
Reserve System

Top 1%
175,000

200,000

225,000

250,000

Banking Trends: How and Why Bank Capital Ratios Change Over the Business Cycle
2021 Q1

275,000

Federal Reserve Bank of Philadelphia
Research Department

300,000

19

The opposite is true of small banks, where assets are significantly negatively correlated with GDP. That is, assets rise more
slowly than GDP, and this drives the capital ratio up as GDP
increases. Small banks also have a stronger relationship between
capital and GDP.

The Largest Banks Are Subject to
Different Capital Requirements
Basel III is an “internationally agreed set of measures
developed by the Basel Committee on Banking Supervision” in response to the Great Financial Crisis of
2007–09.12 The Basel Committee provides regulators
with additional tools to help prevent financial crises.
Some of these standards have been in effect in the
U.S. for a long time. For varying types of capital
measurements, all banks are subject to a minimum
requirement proportional to the bank’s risk-weighted
assets. The Common Equity Tier 1 ratio is set at 4.5
percent. Common Equity includes items such as
common stock value and retained earnings. The Tier
1 Capital Ratio is Common Equity + Additional Tier 1
Capital. Tier 1 Capital adds items such as preferred
shares or minority interest, which together make
up Core Capital. The Tier 1 Capital Ratio minimum
requirement is set at 6 percent. Finally, there is the
Total Capital Ratio, which adds Tier 2 Capital, such as
bank reserves, provisions, and some additional capital
instruments. This ratio is set at 8 percent.

Why Do Large-Bank and Small-Bank
Capital Ratios Behave Differently?

One possibility is that small-bank decision-making is driven by
local rather than national economic trends. Small banks are often
referred to as community banks. As the name suggests, small
banks are often closely tied to the communities they serve, and
as a result, changes in national GDP could be the wrong metric
to use with them. Since upturns and downturns vary across
regions, we may get closer to the small banks’ economic environment by using a regional measure of GDP. The U.S. Bureau of
Economic Analysis provides such a metric for eight regions
within the U.S. For each region, I ran the same analysis using the
regional GDP, along with the capital ratios and its components
for banks that operate only in that region. I found evidence that
the relationships for small banks are generally consistent using
either local GDP or national GDP.
Another possible explanation is that a lot of regulations were
introduced following the Great Financial Crisis (GFC), most of
them falling on the largest banks, so the countercyclical relationship between capital ratios and GDP for large banks may no longer hold. When I separate the analysis into time periods around
the GFC, the correlations of interest are not greatly affected.
Although large-bank capital ratios increased following the GFC,
they are still countercyclical.
The literature suggests that there could
be a few other reasons why large banks
See The Bank
might act differently than small banks. One
Balance Sheet.
possibility is that large banks can expand

Those large banks considered GSIBs are required to
retain an additional 1 to 3.5 percent under Basel III.
Basel III also adds a leverage ratio surcharge for the
largest banks, set at 50 percent of the GSIB’s riskbased capital buffer. In 2020 the Federal Reserve
began incorporating stress test results into capital
requirements for bank holding companies (BHCs) as
well.

FIGURE 3

For the Largest Banks, Capital Falls and Assets Rise as GDP Rises
The opposite is true for the smallest banks.

Changes in Tier 1 capital and risk-weighted assets as GDP grows, 1990-2019; each bin represents percentage of banks by size of assets

GDP

GDP

GDP

TIER 1 CAPITAL

0–25%
Correlation: .31

GDP

Correlation: −.11

GDP

Correlation: −.39
R-W ASSETS

Correlation: .05

GDP

TIER 1 CAPITAL
GDP

R-W ASSETS

Correlation: .17

25–50%
Correlation: .33

GDP

Correlation: −.59
R-W ASSETS

GDP

R-W ASSETS

Correlation: .23

50–75%
Correlation: .19
TIER 1 CAPITAL

GDP

R-W ASSETS

Correlation: .43

75–90%
Correlation: .08
TIER 1 CAPITAL

GDP

R-W ASSETS

RISK-WEIGHTED ASSETS

GDP

90–95%
Correlation: .49
TIER 1 CAPITAL

95–99%
Correlation: −.18
TIER 1 CAPITAL

TIER 1 CAPITAL

Top 1%
Correlation: −.18

GDP

GDP

Source: Call Reports aggregated and available through the National Information Center (NIC) of the Federal Reserve System.

20

Federal Reserve Bank of Philadelphia
Research Department

Banking Trends: How and Why Bank Capital Ratios Change Over the Business Cycle
2021 Q1

Notes

their balance sheets by accessing sources of funds
unavailable to small banks. Large banks have broad
access to money markets they can use to expand their
assets, whereas small banks are heavily dependent
on core deposits.11 Another explanation is that small
banks may be more risk averse than large banks.
Small banks have fewer equity holders, which means
that negative equity shocks impact individual stockholders more. With individual stockholders bearing
more risk, small banks may adopt a more risk-averse
approach to their portfolios. These explanations are
not mutually exclusive, and understanding the precise
reasons for my results is a focus for future research.

1 For example, troubles at one bank may cause another bank’s
depositors and customers to worry about their own
bank’s health. In turn, they might withdraw funds or refuse
to provide credit to their bank, thereby weakening other
banks and deepening the downturn. Economists would
say that the bank’s capital decision generates a negative
externality for other banks.
2 See Quarles (2018).
3 For example, under the capital requirements in Basel II,
lines of credit with a maturity less than one year had a lower
risk weight than lines of credit with maturities greater than
one year. Banks found it profitable to provide businesses
with a 364-day line of credit, which would be rolled over
each year, rather than the more typical 3-to-5-year line of
credit. Once regulations changed with Basel III, the share
of 364-day lines of credit declined dramatically.

Conclusion

Everything else being equal, the banking system is
more resilient if banks are better capitalized when
a recession hits. The evidence presented in this article
provides some support for policymakers to pursue
regulations based on the size of the institution. I have
shown key differences in the behaviors of smalland large-bank capital ratios and provided some
explanation for how and why those differences occur.
When these differences create risk for individual
banks and the industry, regulators can rely on existing
tools and identify the need to create new ones to
help guard against worsening the effects of an unexpected downturn.

4 Unless otherwise noted, all data in this article come from
publicly available Call Reports aggregated and available
through the National Information Center (NIC) of the Federal
Reserve System.
5 This is the Hodrick-Prescott (HP) filter.
6 Previous research focusing on European banks includes
Ayuso (2004) studying Spanish banks and Jokipii and Milne
(2008) studying European BHCs. Haubrich (2020) has examined the relationship between capital and GDP for the U.S.

The Bank Balance Sheet

7 Joseph Haubrich also finds that large- and small-bank
capital ratios have moved in opposite directions since the
1990s. Haubrich’s work examines the cyclicity of bank capital over a long historical period, extending from the 1830s.
Furthering this work, I decompose the movements in capital
ratios to see whether the differences between large and
small banks arise from the changes in capital or the changes
in assets as GDP changes.

TA B L E 1

Balance Sheet of All Commercial Banks
Balance Sheet Information for FDIC Insured Commercial
Banks as of 2019, percentages
Assets (Uses of Funds)*
Reserves and Cash
Securities
Loans
Trading Assets
Other
Total

9.1
20.6
55.7
3.8
10.8
100.0

Liabilities (Sources of Funds)
Deposits
Trading Liabilities
Borrowings
Bank Capital
Other
Total

77.8
1.2
5.6
11.4
4.0
100.0

8 Statistically significant, meaning that p < 0.05.
9 These findings are not due to changes in the number of
banks in the various size categories. This is a period in which
the number of small banks was decreasing dramatically,
mainly due to mergers. To make sure that the correlations
were not driven by selection effects, I created a panel of
small banks that remained in business from 1990 to 2007.
The correlations between capital ratios and GDP also held
for the panel, although not all correlations were statistically
significant, mainly due to the smaller number of small banks
in the panel.
10 In the next section, I discuss some of the economic reasons why large- and small-bank capital ratios might move
differently.

* In order of decreasing liquidity
Source: FDIC via Haver Analytics.

Banking Trends: How and Why Bank Capital Ratios Change Over the Business Cycle
2021 Q1

Federal Reserve Bank of Philadelphia
Research Department

21

11 Core deposits are deposits insured by the federal government. The largest share of
core deposits comes from households, while other banks and financial intermediaries
provide uninsured sources of debt finance to large banks.
12 See Bank for International Settlements (n.d.).

References
Ayuso, Juan, Daniel Pérez, and Jesús Saurina. “Are Capital Buffers Pro-cyclical?:
Evidence From Spanish Panel Data,” Journal of Financial Intermediation, 13:2 (2004),
pp. 249–264, https://doi.org/10.1016/S1042-9573(03)00044-5.
Bank for International Settlements. “Basel III: International Regulatory Framework for
Banks,” https://www.bis.org/bcbs/basel3.htm?m=3%7C14%7C572.
Brainard, Lael. “Assessing Financial Stability Over the Cycle,” speech given at the
Peterson Institute for International Economics, Washington, D.C., December 7, 2018.
D’Erasmo, Pablo. “Are Higher Capital Requirements Worth It?” Economic Insights
(Second Quarter 2018), pp. 1–8, https://www.philadelphiafed.org/the-economy/
banking-and-financial-markets/are-higher-capital-requirements-worth-it.
Elul, Ronel. “The Promise and Challenges of Bank Capital Reform,” Business Review
(Third Quarter 2013), pp. 23–30, https://www.philadelphiafed.org/-/media/frbp/assets/
economy/articles/business-review/2013/q3/brq313_promises-challenges-of-bankcapital-reform.pdf?la=en&hash=5E44BB2DC52236833556E1D0936F0DD3.
Haubrich, Joseph G. “How Cyclical Is Bank Capital?” Journal of Financial Services
Research, 58 (2020), pp. 27–38, https://doi.org/10.1007/s10693-019-00331-7.
Jokipii, Terhi, and Alistair Milne. “The Cyclical Behaviour of European Bank Capital
Buffers,” Journal of Banking & Finance, 32:8 (2008), pp. 1440–1451, https://doi.org/
10.1016/j.jbankfin.2007.12.001.
Kashyap, Anil K., and Jeremy C. Stein. “What Do a Million Observations on Banks
Say About the Transmission of Monetary Policy?” American Economic Review, 90:3
(2000), pp. 407–428, https://doi.org/10.1257/aer.90.3.407.
Quarles, Randal. “Getting It Right: Factors for Tailoring Supervision and Regulation of
Large Financial Institutions,” speech given at American Bankers Association Summer
Leadership Meeting, Salt Lake City, July 18, 2018.
Shim, Jeungbo. “Bank Capital Buffer and Portfolio Risk: The Influence of Business
Cycle and Revenue Diversification,” Journal of Banking & Finance, 37:3 (2013),
pp. 761–772, https://doi.org/10.1016/j.jbankfin.2012.10.002.

22

Federal Reserve Bank of Philadelphia
Research Department

Banking Trends: How and Why Bank Capital Ratios Change Over the Business Cycle
2021 Q1

Research Update

These papers by Philadelphia Fed economists,
analysts, and visiting scholars represent
preliminary research that is being circulated
for discussion purposes.

The views expressed in these papers are
solely those of the authors and should not
be interpreted as reflecting the views of
the Federal Reserve Bank of Philadelphia
or Federal Reserve System.

Concentration in Mortgage Markets: GSE Exposure
and Risk-Taking in Uncertain Times

What Future for History Dependence in Spatial
Economics?

When home prices threaten to decline, large mortgage investors can
benefit from fostering new lending that boosts demand. We ask
whether this benefit contributed to the growth in acquisitions of risky
mortgages by the government-sponsored enterprises (GSEs) in the
first half of 2007. We find that it helps explain the variation of this
growth across regions, in particular the growth of more discretionary
acquisitions. The growth predicted by this benefit is on top of the
acquisition growth caused by the exit of private-label securitizers. We
conclude that the GSEs actively targeted their acquisitions to combat
home-price declines.

History (sometimes) matters for the location and sizes of cities and
neighborhood segregation patterns within cities. Together with
evidence on rapid neighborhood change and self-fulfilling expectations, this implies that nature might not completely determine the
spatial structure of the economy. Instead, the spatial economy might
be characterized by multiple equilibria or multiple steady-state
equilibrium paths, where history and expectations can play decisive
roles. Better evidence on the conditions under which history matters
can help improve theory and policy analysis.

WP 20-04 Revised. Ronel Elul, Federal Reserve Bank of Philadelphia
Research Department; Deeksha Gupta, Carnegie Mellon University;
David Musto, University of Pennsylvania and Visiting Scholar, Federal
Reserve Bank of Philadelphia Research Department.

WP 20-47. Jeffrey Lin, Federal Reserve Bank of Philadelphia Research
Department; Ferdinand Rauch, Oxford University.

Research Update

2021 Q1

Federal Reserve Bank of Philadelphia
Research Department

23

Can We Take the “Stress” Out of Stress Testing?
Applications of Generalized Structural Equation
Modeling to Consumer Finance
Financial firms, and banks in particular, rely heavily on complex suites
of interrelated statistical models in their risk management and
business reporting infrastructures. Statistical model infrastructures are
often developed using a piecemeal approach to model building, in
which different components are developed and validated separately.
This type of modeling framework has significant limitations at each
stage of the model management life cycle, from development and
documentation to validation, production, and redevelopment. We propose an empirical framework, spurred by recent developments in
the implementation of Generalized Structural Equation Modeling
(GSEM), which brings to bear a modular and all-inclusive approach to
statistical model building. We illustrate the “game changing” potential
of this framework with an application to the stress testing of credit
risk for a representative portfolio of mortgages; we also extend it to
the analysis of the allowance for credit loss under the novel Current
Expected Credit Loss (CECL) accounting regulation. We illustrate how
GSEM techniques can significantly enhance every step of the modeling framework life cycle. We also illustrate how GSEM can be used
to combine various risk management projects and tasks into a single
framework; we specifically illustrate how to seamlessly integrate
stress testing and CECL (or IFRS9) frameworks and champion, and
challenger, modeling frameworks. Finally, we identify other areas of
model risk management that can benefit from the GSEM framework
and highlight other potentially fruitful applications of the methodology.

The Well-Being of Nations: Estimating Welfare
from International Migration
The limitations of GDP as a measure of welfare are well known. We
propose a new method of estimating the well-being of nations. Using
gross bilateral international migration flows and a discrete choice
model in which everyone in the world chooses a country in which to
live, we estimate each country’s overall quality of life. Our estimates,
by relying on revealed preference, complement previous estimates
of well-being that consider only income or a small number of factors,
or rely on structural assumptions about how these factors contribute
to well-being.
WP 19-33 Revised. Sanghoon Lee, Sauder School of Business,
University of British Columbia and Visiting Scholar, Federal Reserve
Bank of Philadelphia Research Department; Seung Hoon Lee, School
of Economics, Georgia Institute of Technology; Jeffrey Lin, Federal
Reserve Bank of Philadelphia Research Department.

WP 21-01. José J. Canals-Cerdá, Federal Reserve Bank of Philadelphia.

24

Federal Reserve Bank of Philadelphia
Research Department

Research Update
2021 Q1

DSGE-SVt: An Econometric Toolkit for HighDimensional DSGE Models with SV and t Errors
Currently, there is growing interest in dynamic stochastic general
equilibrium (DSGE) models that have more parameters, endogenous
variables, exogenous shocks, and observables than the Smets and
Wouters (2007) model, and substantial additional complexities from
non-Gaussian distributions and the incorporation of time-varying
volatility. The popular DYNARE software package, which has proved
useful for small and medium-scale models, is, however, not capable of
handling such models, thus inhibiting the formulation and estimation
of more realistic DSGE models. A primary goal of this paper is to introduce a user-friendly MATLAB software program designed to reliably
estimate high-dimensional DSGE models. It simulates the posterior
distribution by the tailored random block Metropolis-Hastings (TaRBMH) algorithm of Chib and Ramamurthy (2010), calculates the
marginal likelihood by the method of Chib (1995) and Chib and
Jeliazkov (2001), and includes various post-estimation tools that are
important for policy analysis, for example, functions for generating
point and density forecasts. Another goal is to provide pointers on
the prior, estimation, and comparison of these DSGE models. An
extended version of the new Keynesian model of Leeper, Traum, and
Walker (2017) that has 51 parameters, 21 endogenous variables,
8 exogenous shocks, 8 observables, and 1,494 non-Gaussian and
nonlinear latent variables is considered in detail.
WP 21-02. Siddhartha Chib, Olin Business School; Minchul Shin,
Federal Reserve Bank of Philadelphia Research Department; Fei Tan;
Saint Louis University.

Using High-Frequency Evaluations to Estimate Discrimination: Evidence from Mortgage Loan Officers
We develop empirical tests for discrimination that use high-frequency
evaluations to address the problem of unobserved heterogeneity
in a conventional benchmarking test. Our approach to identifying
discrimination requires two conditions: (1) The subject pool is timeinvariant in a short time horizon; and (2) There is high-frequency
variation in the extent to which evaluators can rely on their subjective
assessments. We bring our approach to the residential mortgage
market, using data on the near-universe of U.S. mortgage applications
from 1994 to 2018. Monthly volume quotas reduce how much
subjectivity loan officers apply to loans they process at the end of the
month. As a result, the volume of new originations increases by 150%
at the end of the month, while application volume and applicants’
quality are constant within the month. Owing to within-month
variation in loan officers’ subjectivity, we estimate that Black mortgage
applicants have 3.5% to 5% lower approval rates, which explains
at least half of the observed approval gap for Blacks. When we use this
approach to evaluate policies, we find that market concentration
and fintech lending have had no effect on lending discrimination, but
that shadow banking has reduced discrimination, presumably by having
a larger presence in underserved communities.
WP 21-04. Marco Giacoletti, University of Southern California; Rawley
Z. Heimer, Boston College; Edison G. Yu, Federal Reserve Bank of
Philadelphia Research Department.

Measuring Disagreement in
Probabilistic and Density Forecasts
In this paper, we introduce and study a class of disagreement measures
for probability distribution forecasts based on the Wasserstein metric.
We describe a few advantageous properties of this measure of disagreement between forecasters. After describing alternatives to our
proposal, we use examples to compare these measures to one
another in closed form. We provide two empirical illustrations. The
first application uses our measure to gauge disagreement among
professional forecasters about output growth and the inflation rate in
the Eurozone. The second application employs our measure to gauge
disagreement among multivariate predictive distributions generated
by different forecasting methods.
WP 21-03. Ryan Cumings-Menon, U.S. Census Bureau; Minchul Shin,
Federal Reserve Bank of Philadelphia Research Department; Keith Sill,
Federal Reserve Bank of Philadelphia Research Department.

Research Update

2021 Q1

Federal Reserve Bank of Philadelphia
Research Department

25

On the Aggregation of Probability
Assessments: Regularized Mixtures
of Predictive Densities for Eurozone
Inflation and Real Interest Rates
Eviction Risk of Rental Housing:
Does It Matter How Your Landlord
Finances the Property?
We show, using a stylized model, how the financing
choice of landlords can impact eviction decisions in rental
markets. Since multifamily loans rely on timely cash flows
from tenants, strict underwriting factors can increase the
chances that landlords are able to weather income shocks.
Lender-provided relief may create further leeway for
landlords to work out a deal with tenants who default on
rental payments. Using comprehensive data on nationwide
evictions in the U.S. and performance records on multifamily mortgages, we confirm predictions from our model
by documenting a negative relation between evictions
and the financing activity by government-sponsored
enterprises (GSEs) that impose strict underwriting criteria
but generally offer borrowers relief during unprecedented
income shocks. We also quantify the eviction risks
induced by the COVID-19 pandemic for 12 U.S. cities using
our empirical model.
WP 21-05. Brent W. Ambrose, The Pennsylvania State
University; Xudong An, Federal Reserve Bank of Philadelphia; Luis A. Lopez, University of Illinois at Chicago.

We propose methods for constructing regularized
mixtures of density forecasts. We explore a variety of
objectives and regularization penalties, and we use
them in a substantive exploration of Eurozone inflation
and real interest rate density forecasts. All individual
inflation forecasters (even the ex post best forecaster)
are outperformed by our regularized mixtures. From
the Great Recession onward, the optimal regularization
tends to move density forecasts’ probability mass from
the centers to the tails, correcting for overconfidence.
WP 21-06. Francis X. Diebold, University of Pennsylvania
and Visiting Scholar, Federal Reserve Bank of Philadelphia
Research Department; Minchul Shin, Federal Reserve
Bank of Philadelphia Research Department; Boyuan
Zhang, University of Pennsylvania.

PEAD.txt: Post-Earnings-Announcement
Drift Using Text
We construct a new numerical measure of earnings
announcement surprises, standardized unexpected
earnings call text (SUE.txt), that does not explicitly incorporate the reported earnings value. SUE.txt generates
a text-based post-earnings-announcement drift (PEAD.txt)
larger than the classic PEAD and can be used to create
a profitable trading strategy. Leveraging the prediction
model underlying SUE.txt, we propose new tools to study
the news content of text: paragraph-level SUE.txt and
a paragraph classification scheme based on the business
curriculum. With these tools, we document many
asymmetries in the distribution of news across content
types, demonstrating that earnings calls contain a wide
range of news about firms and their environment.
WP 21-07. Vitaly Meursault, Federal Reserve Bank of
Philadelphia Research Department; Pierre Jinghong
Liang, Carnegie Mellon University; Bryan R. Routledge,
Carnegie Mellon University; Madeline Marco Scanlon,
University of Pittsburgh.

26

Federal Reserve Bank of Philadelphia
Research Department

Research Update
2021 Q1

Does CFPB Oversight Crimp Credit?

CLO Performance
We show that collateralized loan obligations (CLOs)
add economic value by mitigating regulatory constraints
imposed on financial intermediaries and addressing
market incompleteness. CLO assets exhibit similar
performance to loan mutual funds with nearly identical
risk exposures and fees. CLO debt and equity tranches
generate after-fee returns that are attractive relative to
public benchmarks but commensurate with their
systematic risk exposures. Before fees, equity tranches
significantly outperform public benchmarks, which
shows how managers capture the economic surplus
created by CLOs. Temporal variation in equity performance
highlights the resilience of CLOs to market volatility due
to their long-term funding structure and the erosion of
returns as the market has grown.
WP 20-48 Revised. Larry Cordell, Federal Reserve Bank
of Philadelphia Supervision, Regulation, and Credit
Department; Michael R. Roberts, The Wharton School of
the University of Pennsylvania and the National Bureau
of Economic Research; Michael Schwert, The Wharton
School of the University of Pennsylvania.

We study how regulatory oversight by the Consumer
Financial Protection Bureau (CFPB) affects mortgage
credit supply and other aspects of bank behavior. We use
a difference-in-differences approach exploiting changes
in regulatory intensity and a size cutoff below which
banks are exempt from CFPB scrutiny. CFPB oversight
leads to a reduction in lending in the Federal Housing
Administration (FHA) market, which primarily serves
riskier borrowers. However, it is also associated with
a lower transition probability from moderate to serious
delinquency, suggesting that tighter regulatory oversight
may reduce foreclosures. Our results underscore the
tradeoff between protecting borrowers and maintaining
access to credit.
WP 21-08. Andreas Fuster, Swiss National Bank and
CEPR; Matthew Plosser, Federal Reserve Bank of New York;
James Vickery, Federal Reserve Bank of Philadelphia
Research Department.

Inequality in the Time of COVID-19:
Evidence from Mortgage Delinquency
and Forbearance
Using a novel database that combines mortgage
servicing records, credit-bureau data, and loan application
information, we show that lower-income and minority
borrowers have significantly higher nonpayment rates
during the COVID-19 pandemic, even after controlling
for conventional risk factors. A difference-in-differences
analysis shows how much the pandemic has exacerbated
income and racial inequalities. We then find that government and private-sector forbearance programs have
mitigated these inequalities in the near term, as lowerincome and minority borrowers have taken up the
short-term debt relief at higher rates. Finally, we examine
modification options for an estimated 2.8 million loans in
forbearance, most with terms expiring by mid-year 2021.
WP 21-09. Xudong An, Federal Reserve Bank of Philadelphia
Supervision, Regulation, and Credit Department; Larry
Cordell, Federal Reserve Bank of Philadelphia Supervision,
Regulation, and Credit Department; Liang Geng, Federal
Reserve Bank of Philadelphia Supervision, Regulation,
and Credit Department; Keyoung Lee, Federal Reserve
Bank of Philadelphia Supervision, Regulation, and Credit
Department.

Research Update

2021 Q1

Federal Reserve Bank of Philadelphia
Research Department

27

Unexpected Effects of Bank Bailouts: Depositors
Need Not Apply and Need Not Run
A key policy issue is whether bank bailouts weaken or strengthen
market discipline. We address this by analyzing how bank bailouts
influence deposit quantities and prices of recipients versus other
banks. Using the Troubled Asset Relief Program (TARP) bailouts, we
find both deposit quantities and prices decline, consistent with
substantially reduced demand for deposits by bailed-out banks
that dominate market discipline supply effects. Main findings are
robust to numerous checks and endogeneity tests. However,
diving deeper into depositor heterogeneity suggests nuances.
Increases in uninsured deposits, transactions deposits, and deposits
in banks that repaid bailout funds early suggest some temporary
limited support for weakened market discipline.
WP 21-10. Allen N. Berger, University of South Carolina; Martien
Lamers, Ghent University; Raluca A. Roman, Federal Reserve Bank
of Philadelphia Supervision, Regulation, and Credit Department;
Koen Schoors, Ghent University.

The Future of Labor: Automation and the
Labor Share in the Second Machine Age
We study the effect of modern automation on firm-level labor shares
using a 2018 survey of 1,618 manufacturing firms in China. We exploit
geographic and industry variation built into the design of subsidies
for automation paid under a vast government industrialization program,
“Made In China 2025,” to construct an instrument for automation
investment. We use a canonical CES framework of automation and
develop a novel methodology to structurally estimate the elasticity
of substitution between labor and automation capital among automating firms, which for our preferred specification is 3.8. We
calibrate the model and show that the general equilibrium implications
of this elasticity are consistent with the aggregate trends during our
sample period.
WP 21-11. Hong Cheng, Wuhan University; Lukasz A. Drozd, Federal
Reserve Bank of Philadelphia Research Department; Rahul Giri,
International Monetary Fund; Mathieu Taschereau-Dumouchel,
Cornell University; Junjie Xia, Peking University.

28

Federal Reserve Bank of Philadelphia
Research Department

Research Update
2021 Q1

Data in Focus

Livingston Survey

The Philadelphia Fed collects, analyzes, and shares useful data
about the Third District and beyond. Here’s one example.

I

n 1946, journalist Joseph Livingston
began asking economists he knew to
share their forecasts for key economic
variables. Their answers became the basis
of his biannual column for the Philadelphia
Record, then for the Philadelphia Bulletin,
and finally for the Philadelphia Inquirer.
Livingston was eventually overwhelmed by
requests from readers for his source data,
so in 1978 the Philadelphia Fed agreed to
input his records into its computers and
share the data with interested researchers.
Upon Livingston’s death in 1989, the
Philadelphia Fed took over the survey and
continues to conduct it to the present day.
One of the Survey’s most important
variables is Total Private Housing Starts,
or the number of privately owned new
homes on which construction has started.
Housing is key to a healthy economy:
Other industries, such as banking and
construction, rely on housing starts.
Housing starts in turn reflect demand
for housing, which is itself a reflection
of the overall health of the economy.
Analysts and economic researchers look to
the Survey because it is the oldest continuous survey of macroeconomic forecasts
in the U.S.

Total Private Housing Starts

Median forecasts, annual rate, seasonally adjusted, millions, December 2020 survey

Forecasts for Months
Annualised levels
1.5

Forecasts for Years
Levels
1.5

Forecast Growth

−0.40

1.0

Forecast Growth

+6.96

1.0

percent change
Dec 2020–Jun 2021

−1.00

0.5

0.0

Dec Jun Dec

percent change
Jun 2021–Dec 2021

2020 2021 2021

percent change
2020–2021

+0.89

0.5

0.0

2020 ‘21 ‘22

percent change
2021–2022

Source: Federal Reserve Bank of Philadelphia Livingston Survey.

Learn More
Online: www.philadelphiafed.org/surveys-and-data/
real-time-data-research/livingston-survey
E-mail: phil.liv@phil.frb.org

Connect with Us
Explore a New Philadelphia Fed Website User Experience
The Philadelphia Fed launched its new website. Visit www.philadelphiafed.org to see how our
improved user-centric navigation and content gives you an easier way to find the data and information
you want—current bookmarks will need to be reset under the new navigation system—and explore
everything the Philadelphia Fed has to offer to help communities thrive.

PRESORTED STANDARD
U.S. POSTAGE
PAID
PHILADELPHIA, PA
PERMIT #583

Ten Independence Mall
Philadelphia, Pennsylvania 19106-1574

ADDRESS SERVICE REQUESTED

From Philadelphia, Pennsylvania, the birthplace of American finance, comes Economic Insights.

2016 Q1

2017 Q2

2018 Q1

2019 Q1

Featuring articles about how Americans work, invest, spend…and so much more.

2020 Q1

2020 Q2

2020 Q3

2020 Q4