View original document

The full text on this page is automatically extracted from the file linked above and may contain errors and inconsistencies.

Economic Insights
FEDERAL RESERVE BANK OF DALLAS VOLUME 1, NUMBER 1

Rediscovering the
Value of Honest Money
Bob McTeer
President and Chief Executive Officer
Federal Reserve Bank of Dallas

I

We have stopped
thinking of sound
money as honest
money. When our
government issues
money, we have a
right to expect that
money to be worth
tomorrow what it is
today. If you think
about it, governmentissued money is a
contract with the
people. Inflation is
taxation without
representation.

t seems you can hardly
pick up a paper or turn on the
news these days without seeing something about all the
efforts on Capitol Hill to redefine the way Congress and the
president carry out their fiscal
responsibilities. The balanced
budget amendment. A lineitem veto. Legislation to limit
unfunded federal mandates.
When you stop and think
about it, you have to wonder
how things got so bad in the
first place.
Traditionally, Americans
have expected prudence in
government spending. The
government and public took
it for granted that budgets
should be balanced, except,
perhaps, in major emergencies
or extraordinary circumstances, such as war or depression. But once Keynes convinced us that the budget was
a legitimate policy tool to be
manipulated to fine-tune the
economy, the moral commitment to a balanced budget
withered away. I would argue
that much the same thing has
happened to our resolve
against inflation.
The advantages of price
stability, or a stable value of
the dollar, are many and varied. Price stability is a worthy
goal in itself, and it also offers
the best financial environment
for achieving other important

national goals, such as maximum output and employment
growth. Since many of the
advantages of price stability
are self-evident, I am somewhat perplexed as to why the
constituency for it seems so
weak among the business
community and the public.
One gets the impression that
most people are content with
3-percent inflation, even
though the rule of 72 says that
prices will double every 24
years with 3-percent inflation.
It is true that 3-percent
inflation is good by the standards of the 1970s, and even
the 1980s, but it’s not so good
by earlier standards. Recall
that President Nixon declared
a national emergency and imposed price and wage controls
in 1971 when inflation had
climbed to the dangerous level
of 4 percent.
For much of our history,
sound money was imposed
externally by our commitment
to gold convertibility, directly
or indirectly. Going off the
gold standard in the early
1970s may have been the
smart thing to do under the
circumstances; it may even
have been the only alternative
at the time. I must admit,
however, that our experience
with price stability since then
has not been as good as it was
before.
One problem with our
national commitment to sound
money probably is the
progress we have made on
inflation since the 1970s. With
that experience fresh in our
minds, we willingly underwent wrenching adjustments
in the early 1980s to break the
back of inflation. As progress
was made and our memories

faded, our determination has
waned. We have stopped
thinking of sound money as
honest money.
When our government issues money, we have a right
to expect that money to be
worth tomorrow what it is today. If that is too high a standard, shouldn’t we at least
try? We have a right to expect
that what we save for our
children’s education or for
their inheritance will hold its
value. If you think about it,
government-issued money is
a contract with the people.
Inflation is taxation without
representation.
People wiser and more articulate than I have given eloquent voice to my thoughts
about money. One was the
Rev. Robert Sirico, president
of the Acton Institute for the
Study of Religion and Liberty,
who addressed a group of
business leaders during a luncheon at the Dallas Fed. He
spoke of the concept of honest money as it is founded in
the Bible.
The other person who
stated the case for honest
money so eloquently was the
late Henry Wallich, former
college professor, columnist
and member of the Federal
Reserve Board of Governors.
He did so in a commencement
address 17 years ago. I find it
somewhat comforting that his
remarks still ring true today.
In this first issue of Economic Insights, I am sharing
the honest money messages
of Father Sirico and Henry
Wallich. I’d enjoy hearing
what you think. Please write
me at the address on the back,
or fax me your thoughts at
(214) 922-5268. ª

Honest
Money
The following is an edited
excerpt from Henry C. Wallich’s
commencement address delivered
to the Fordham Graduate School of
Business on June 28, 1978.

A

Inflation introduces
an element of deceit
into most of our
economic dealings.
Everybody makes
contracts knowing
perfectly well that they
will not be kept in
terms of constant
values. This condition
is hard to reconcile
with simple honesty.

t this time, you are presumably looking at your future role in the world in the
broadest possible sense, including a moral sense. Today,
I would like to talk to you
about one aspect of your future that has a moral dimension, although it is technically
an economic problem. I mean
the breakdown in our standards of measuring economic
values, as a consequence of
inflation.
Inflation introduces an element of deceit into most of
our economic dealings. Everybody makes contracts knowing perfectly well that they will
not be kept in terms of constant values. Everybody expects the value of the dollar
to change over the period of
a contract. But any specific
allowance made for inflation
in such a contract is bound to
be a speculation. The most
valuable part of the contract
may turn out to be the paper
it is written on. This condition
is hard to reconcile with
simple honesty.
If our contracts were
made in terms of unpredictably shifting measures of
weight, time or space, as we
buy food, sell our labor or
acquire real estate, we would
probably regar d that as
cheating and as intolerable.

Yet the case is much the
same when we are dealing
with monetary values.
The moral issues posed
by inflation go beyond what I
consider deceit. Inflation is a
means by which the strong
can more effectively exploit
the weak. The strategically
positioned and well-organized
can gain at the expense of the
unorganized and the aged.
In the eyes of economists
and of government, inflation
becomes a means of exploiting labor’s money illusion, its
supposed failure to anticipate
inflation correctly. The device
through which this mechanism operates is the wellknown Phillips curve, the alleged trade-off between unemployment and inflation. It
is believed that labor will respond to a seemingly large
wage offer that subsequently
is eroded by inflation. If labor
fails to notice the trick, it will
keep working for less than it
really had demanded, and
employment will be higher. A
government pretending to
serve a nation’s interest by,
say, misinforming the people
about its military plans would
be harshly taken to task.
Why should trading on the
people’s money illusion be
regarded any differently?
Meanwhile, planning
ahead becomes more difficult for business. Investment
lags because long-term commitments involve risks that
inflation makes incalculable.
The need to guard against
these unknowable risks
compels each party to any
transaction, buyer and seller,
employer and employee,
lender and borrower, to introduce a risk premium into
his pricing. Each must demand a little more or offer a
little less than he would under noninflationary condi-

tions. That reduces the range
of possible bargains and the
level of economic activity.
Fewer jobs and less output
in the private sector are the
results.
Inflation also undermines
the honesty of our public policies. It allows the politician to
make promises that cannot be
met in real terms because, as
the government overspends
trying to keep those promises,
the value of the benefits it
delivers shrinks.
Finally, inflation becomes
a means of promoting changes
in our economic, social and
political institutions that circumvents the democratic process. Such changes could be
forced upon a reluctant nation
because inflation may end up
making the existing system inviable. One instance is the diminishing ability of households to provide privately for
their future. Personal savings,
insurance and pension funds
all become inadequate. Money
set aside in any of these forms
for old age, for sickness, for
education could be wiped out
by accelerating inflation. One
may indeed ask whether it is
not an essential attribute of a
civilized society to be able to
make that kind of provision
for the future. But that is not
the point I want to stress.
Rather, I want to emphasize
that the increasing uncertainty
in providing privately for the
future pushes people who are
seeking security toward the
government.
By one route or another,
inflation creates a vacuum in
the private sector into which
the government moves. By
making the performance of
the economy inadequate, inflation is likely to induce expanded government activity.
Of the three great dimensions
of our society—private rather

than public ownership, decision-making by the market
rather than by central planning and democracy rather
than authoritarianism—private ownership and market
decision-making will then be
in retreat. No one can say how
long, under such conditions,
a shift also in the third dimension, away from democracy
and toward authoritarianism,
can be avoided.
What can be done? Before we look for remedies, we
must examine the causes. Inflation is like cancer—many
substances are carcinogenic,
and many activities generate
inflation. The sources of inflation can be diagnosed at
several levels. The familiar debate about the sources of violence provides an analogy. Do
guns kill people? Do people
kill people? Does society kill
people? Some assert that
money, and nothing but
money, causes inflation—the
“guns kill people” proposition.
Some assert that the entire gamut of government
policies, from deficit spending to protectionism, to minimum wage to farm price supports, to environmental and
safety regulations, causes
inflation—the “people kill
people” proposition. Some
argue, finally, that it is social
pressures, competition for
the national product, a revolution of aspirations, which
is at the root—the “society
kills people” proposition.
The first view holds the central bank primarily responsible
for inflation, the second the
government in general, the
third the people who elect
and instruct the government.
In addition, time preference, the social discount rate,
enters into the equation. Inflation usually is the final link
in a chain of well-meant ac-

tions. The benefits of a tax cut,
of increased public spending,
are felt within a few weeks or
quarters. The penalty in terms
of inflation may not come until after a couple of years or
even later. Inflation is the
long-run consequence of
short-run expediencies. Life,
to be sure, is a succession of
short runs, but every moment
is also the long run of some
short-run expediency of long
ago. We are now experiencing the long-run consequences of the short-run
policies of the past. These
consequences are as unacceptable as rain on weekends and just as easy to
change. If we continue to
meet current problems with
new short-run devices, the
bill will keep mounting.
We will not defeat inflation if we always take the
short view. We will then always find that the cost of fighting inflation is too high, the
short-run loss of output and
employment too great. We
shall find ourselves ignoring
inflation, in the hope that it
will somehow not grow
worse. That is pure selfdeception. Cancer ignored
does not become stationary,
and neither does inflation. Inflation ignored accelerates.
A long view is needed on
inflation. It is a view very different from that of the politician, who is under enormous
pressure to do quickly something that looks good. Harold
Wilson said that in politics one
week was a long time. More
charitably, the pressure is until the next election. If the
people will not instruct their
elected representatives to do
the things that are needed to
end inflation, if they turn them
out of office because the remedies take time and are temporarily painful, we will keep

getting a little more employment and output now at the
expense of much more unemployment and loss of output
later. And we will get more
inflation all along the way,
down to its ultimate consequences. We need to make
the ending of inflation our
first priority. That must be
our overall policy.
If inflation is a moral
problem, we require a moral
solution—that is, a recognition
that public policies have led
to serious inequities affecting
people in different and unequal ways and a commitment
to new policies that will correct the cumulative distortions
and contribute to desired economic progress. Nothing will
stop inflation overnight, and
in the short run, the gains will
always seem dearly won. But
without such a long-run approach, the damage will
mount and the ultimate costs
will escalate. ª
Henry C. Wallich served as a
member of the Federal Reserve
Board of Governors from 1974 to
1986. For a copy of the complete
text of his commencement address,
please write to the Federal Reserve
Bank of Dallas, Public Affairs Dept.,
2200 N. Pearl St., Dallas, Texas,
75201, or fax your request to the
Public Affairs Dept. at
(214) 922-5268.

Inflation is a
means by which the
strong can more
effectively exploit
the weak. The
strategically
positioned and wellorganized can gain
at the expense of the
unorganized and
the aged.

Examining the
Moral Dimensions of
Monetary Policy
The following excerpts are
from the Rev. Robert A. Sirico’s
luncheon address delivered at the
Federal Reserve Bank of Dallas
on February 25, 1994.

B

Certainly, if it is wrong
for individuals to
deceitfully change the
weights and measures
in their transactions,
it is also morally
incumbent upon other
institutions, especially
government, to keep
honest weights and
measures.

efore the turn of this
century, an entire generation
of preachers and ministers
concluded that a moral monetary policy was an easymoney policy. “Give the
people more money and
credit,” was the cry of the
populist ministers. “Down
with gold, up with silver.”
They mistakenly believed that
the Treasury’s printing press
was the key to earthly salvation.
Even as late as the 1940s,
this ideology is evident in film.
As much as I love the Christmas classic, “It’s a Wonderful
Life,” a careful viewer can detect its social credit homiletics.
Even today, no matter
which party holds the White
House, the Federal Reserve
consistently faces pressure to
keep interest rates artificially
low, buy more government
debt and trade quick economic fixes for long-term capital accumulation.
Yet, it seems to me, honesty and morality weigh in on
the side of the grand tradition
of sound and stable money.
Holy Scripture speaks of
money in terms of weight, just
as it was spoken of throughout history. In the list of commandments, tampering with

those weights ranked among
the behaviors condemned
from Above. Certainly, if it is
wrong for individuals to
deceitfully change the weights
and measures in their transactions, it is also morally incumbent upon other institutions, especially government,
to keep honest weights and
measures.
Allow me to provide a
few examples. God told the
Israelites that economic transactions should take place with
honest weights. Leviticus
19:35–37, instructs, “You shall
do no wrong in judgment, in
measure of weight, or capacity. You shall have just balances and just weights.”
This was long before the
followers of Keynes revealed
to us the dangerous “liquidity
trap” that might result from
such “outdated” morals.
Again, Proverbs 11:1 announces that, “A deceitful balance is an abomination before
the Lord: but a just weight is
His will.” But, of course, this
was before we discovered the
mysterious “magic” of debt
monetization.
Proverbs 20:10 says, “Diverse weights and diverse
measures, both are abominable before God.” Would that
Solomon had known about
the trade-off between inflation
and employment, as revealed
by the Phillips curve, now
back in vogue.
It is true that Isaiah (1:22)
warned that “faithless princes”
can turn silver “into dross.”
But that was before we knew
how much debtors can gain
from paying back dollars that
are cheaper than those they
borrowed.
I’ll grant that the prophets Amos (8:5) and Micah
(6:10) condemned deceitful
balances when selling wares. But
neither knew much of the bal-

ance of trade with Japan.
Actually, all these scriptural references make an important moral and economic
point. The long history of inflation reveals the tragic consequences of excessive money
creation. It can, literally, turn
a society upside down. It did
in Germany, in the famous
hyperinflationary period of
1921–23. It did in this country
in the late 1970s. It has in
innumerable developing
countries. Control of the printing presses is probably a first
order condition to a solid
economy and stable social order. So much for the magic of
credit expansion. ª
The Rev. Robert A. Sirico is founder
and president of the Acton Institute
for the Study of Religion and Liberty,
based in Grand Rapids, Michigan.

Economic Insights
is a publication of the Federal Reserve Bank
of Dallas. The views expressed are those of
the authors and should not be attributed
to the Federal Reserve System.
Please address
all correspondence to
Economic Insights
Public Affairs Department
Federal Reserve Bank of Dallas
P.O. Box 655906
Dallas, TX 75265-5906