View original document

The full text on this page is automatically extracted from the file linked above and may contain errors and inconsistencies.

May 27, 2020

Economic Impact of COVID-19
“Flattening the Curve”: What Does it Cost,
and What Does it Buy Us?
By John Mullin, Jessie Romero, and Sonya Ravindranath Waddell
In mid-March, states and localities across the
United States began taking measures to reduce
or delay the acceleration of new cases of novel
coronavirus infection and the related illness,
COVID-19, which epidemiologists refer to as
“flattening the curve.” The goal has been to avoid
exceeding existing healthcare capacity, while
also buying time to increase that capacity and
develop potential treatments and vaccines. But
flattening the curve involves trade-offs that are
both highly complicated and consequential; and
indeed, some policymakers and citizens are
becoming increasingly concerned that the costs
of “social distancing” mandates and
recommendations have started to outweigh the
benefits.
Modeling a Virus
Economists have attempted to provide insights
into the nature of the trade-offs by building and
analyzing macroeconomic models of epidemics.
Some of these macroeconomic models expand
on the epidemiological models of William Ogilvy
Kermack and A. G. McKendrick, which were first
published in the 1920s and 1930s but remain
relevant today.1 In Kermack and McKendrick’s
basic model, the number of new infections
hinges on the number of contacts between those
who are infected and those who are susceptible.

The rate of new infections increases in the
earliest stage of an epidemic as the number of
infected people grows relative to the number of
susceptible people. Barring a seasonal break or
the introduction of a successful vaccine, the rate
of new cases eventually peaks and then declines
as the susceptible, yet-to-be infected population
becomes smaller. (The basic model assumes that
those who are infected cannot rejoin the ranks
of the susceptible). According to the theory, the
time plot of new infections takes the shape of a
bell curve — a pattern that has fit many historical
epidemics.
Macroeconomists have extended such epidemiological models by allowing for the interaction between economic decisions and rates of
infection. Marin Eichenbaum, Sergio Rebelo,
and Mathias Trabandt, for instance, developed a
model in which infection rates depend not only
on the populations of infected and susceptible
people, but also on levels of consumption and
production.2 In their model, consumption activities (think of shopping and dining) and production activities (think of working in an office or
in a restaurant) increase human interaction and
thereby increase the rate of new infections.
When faced with an epidemic, economic agents

Page 1
May 2020 – Richmond Fed

in their model voluntarily cut back on consumption
and work. These decisions reduce the severity of the
epidemic as measured by total deaths, but they also
deepen the recession caused by the epidemic.
One of their key findings is that the outcomes predicted by the model are not optimal from a social
point of view. The reason is that, while individuals
tend to adjust their behavior to lower their own risk
of infection, they do not fully account for the effect
of their consumption and work decisions on the
overall spread of the virus. As the authors emphasize,
“This market failure does not reflect a lack of good
intentions or irrationality … It simply reflects the
fact that each person takes economy-wide infection
rates as given.” They conclude that this market failure
provides a rationale for government containment
measures that reduce consumption and production
but raise overall welfare by reducing mortality.
Their model also addresses the possible discovery
of a successful vaccine. In the absence of a possible
vaccine, the epidemic would need to eventually run
its course until the population achieved “herd immunity.” In this case, containment policies would mostly
ensure that the health care system does not become
overwhelmed. But with the anticipation of a successful vaccine, there is much more value in continuing
to flatten the curve. Thus, they find that optimal
containment policies become more stringent as the
prospect of a successful vaccine becomes more likely.
Economic Costs
Voluntary and government-mandated measures to
contain the virus have already exacted a significant
toll on American households, workers, and businesses. Unemployment claims skyrocketed to an unprecedented 3.3 million in the week ending March 21; the
following week, an additional 6.9 million Americans
filed for unemployment. By May 16, almost 40 million
claims had been filed in the nation. The unemployment rate in April climbed to 14.7 percent. GDP fell
at a 4.8 percent annualized rate in the first quarter.
While uncertain, the corresponding rate for second

quarter GDP is generally expected to be more
than -30 percent, which is easily the lowest on
record. All sectors of the economy have been affected; the 20.5 million net job losses from March
to April spanned industries. But, not surprisingly,
the greatest losses have been in the industries
most affected by social distancing measures. Employment in leisure and hospitality, for example,
was halved in April.
Surveys conducted by the Richmond Fed indicate that both manufacturers and service providers saw a decline in activity. The composite index
of manufacturing for the District fell to -53 in
April and remained well below zero — at -27 in
May — indicating that conditions worsened for
most manufacturers from April to May. Meanwhile, the headline revenues index for the service
sector plummeted to -87 in April and remained
low, at -48 in May. For both of these measures,
the April reading was the lowest in a 25-year history. Preliminary results from a special survey on
COVID-related declines indicate that just over a
quarter of respondents were in danger of insolvency if conditions did not improve and most expected it to take at least six months before they
would be back to pre-COVID levels of activity. In
a survey conducted in late March by economists
from the University of Illinois, Harvard University,
and the University of Chicago, nearly 40 percent
of small businesses thought it was unlikely or
only somewhat likely they would still be open
at the end of 2020.3 The future viability of small
businesses is a top concern for the public and
policymakers.
No Simple Trade-off
While macroeconomic models of epidemics are
useful for understanding the nature of some of
the trade-offs, their conclusions can be difficult
to translate into operational policy. It is difficult
to measure a particular policy’s effect on either
economic activity or the loss of life. And there is
even more uncertainty and disagreement about
the appropriate trade-off between the two.

Page 2

Economists — practitioners of the dismal science —
have conducted numerous studies of labor market
data to estimate the trade-offs that workers make
between fatality risk and wages. Based on these
analyses, economists have developed a measure
called the value of a statistical life, or VSL, which
policymakers use to weigh the benefits and costs of
various risk reduction policies. The concept has been
widely applied to assess product and workplace
safety standards, and it also plays an important role
in healthcare cost-benefit analyses. In the United
States, estimates of the VSL vary widely, but the average is about $10 million. If this number were to be
used to inform the trade-off between the loss of life
and the loss of economic value, it would imply that
it is worth sacrificing 1 percent of U.S. GDP (or $200
billion) to save 20,000 lives. It has been widely noted,
however, that those most vulnerable to COVID-19
are often older and/or in poor health. Whether and
how such considerations should affect their estimated VSLs are difficult questions to answer.4
More realistically, however, we do not face a simple
trade-off between forgone GDP and COVID-19
fatalities. Indeed, there is reason to believe that the
current economic downturn may contribute to fatalities in and of itself. Numerous studies in the United
States and abroad have found a relationship between unemployment and poor mental and physical
health outcomes.5 Researchers have also found a
link between stress and social isolation and higher
rates of domestic violence,6 and police departments
across the country have reported an increase in
domestic violence calls. The Charlotte-Mecklenburg
police department received 517 more calls in March
of 2020 compared to March of 2019, an 18 percent
increase. Suicide rates also tend to increase during
economic downturns, which could be exacerbated
by social isolation and decreased access to community support and mental health care.7
Social distancing measures may also have longlasting costs for children. More than 54 million K-12
students were out of school at the end of March.

Research suggests home schooling is an imperfect
substitute for in-person instruction, and families
vary widely in the time and resources they have to
devote to instruction. In 2017, more than 14 percent
of children between 3 and 18 years old did not have
internet access at home, according to the National
Center for Education Statistics, and many school districts have reported that large numbers of students
are not attending school online.8 In addition, state
and local governments will likely have to sharply
reduce their future expenditures, which could affect
education spending once schools reopen. A large
body of research has demonstrated the importance
of education for long-term outcomes and the potentially long-lasting effects of educational disruptions.9
While these considerations suggest that mitigation
efforts may impose costs above and beyond the loss
of current GDP, a recent study of the 1918 Spanish
Flu puts mitigation efforts in a much more favorable light. Examining the economic performances
of various U.S. cities between 1914 and 1919, Sergio
Correia, Stephen Luck, and Emil Verner presented
two key findings. First, the pandemic had negative
effects on manufacturing activity. And second, cities
that intervened earlier and more aggressively did not
perform worse and, if anything, grew faster during
the period studied.
A number of recent papers using high frequency
data such as electronic transactions records also suggest that government-mandated mitigation efforts
may have relatively modest effects on economic activity. For example, Denmark and Sweden faced similar exposure to COVID-19, but it was only in Denmark
that the government significantly restricted social
and economic activities. In a recent paper, researchers at the University of Copenhagen and the Center
for Economic Behavior and Inequality estimated that
aggregate spending dropped around 25 percent in
Sweden but only an additional 4 percentage points
in Denmark. These results suggest that the economic
contractions were largely caused by the virus and the
societies’ voluntary responses to it and that government policy may have played a secondary role.10

Page 3

What Are the “Right” Policies?
Are current U.S. social distancing efforts “worth it”?
Economic theory provides a rationale for government-mandated mitigation measures that tend to
reduce mortality at the cost of reduced GDP. And
evidence based on the 1918 Spanish Flu pandemic
seems to suggest that mitigation efforts do not necessarily entail a trade-off between fatalities and the
economy, although the service-intensive economy of
today is much different from the more agriculturaland manufacturing-intensive economy of the World
War I era.
Clearly, the costs of social distancing are high, and
people are hurting. Against this backdrop, the debate over the merits of government-mandated social
distancing has become more highly charged and
politicized in recent weeks. But it appears that there
is still a broad consensus about two things: First, a
certain level of social distancing is wise. And second,
we would all like to see the economy opened up as
quickly as is safely possible.
In order to maintain this (clearly non-unanimous)
consensus, it may be important to recognize that the
impact of social distancing measures varies greatly
among different demographic groups and job
categories. Many of the people who are bearing the
greatest income losses associated with containment
measures are small business owners and relatively
young service-sector workers whose fatality risk is
relatively low. And many people with the highest
fatality risk are elderly and retired and are therefore
losing relatively little income. Arguably, the unequal distribution of costs and benefits associated
with containment measures creates a rationale for
government transfer payments to at least partially
compensate for the discrepancy.11
It also will be important to have well-articulated and
transparent standards for reopening. Perceptions of
favoritism or that regulations do not apply equally
to everyone could undermine the legitimacy of the
social distancing mandates still deemed necessary
by public officials.

Finally, it is difficult to know the extent to which easing social distancing restrictions will boost economic
activity, as consumers may be cautious about returning to their previous levels of shopping, dining,
and other interactions.12 New health protocols and
widespread COVID-19 testing and contact tracing
will likely support consumer confidence and encourage a more robust economic recovery.13
John Mullin is a senior economics writer, Jessie
Romero is director of publications, and Sonya Ravindranath Waddell is a vice president and economist
in the Research Department at the Federal Reserve
Bank of Richmond.
Endnotes
1

W
 illiam Ogilvy Kermack and A. G. McKendrick, “A contribution to the mathematical theory of epidemics,” Royal Society
Publishing, 1927, vol. 115, no. 772, pp. 700-721.
W. O. Kermack and A. G. McKendrick, “Contributions to the
mathematical theory of epidemics, II. – The problem of endemicity,” Royal Society Publishing, 1932, vol. 138, pp. 55-83.
W. O. Kermack and A. G. McKendrick, “Contributions to the
mathematical theory of epidemics, III.—Further studies of the
problem of endemicity,” Royal Society Publishing, 1933, vol.
141, pp. 94-122.

2

M
 artin S. Eichenbaum, Sergio Rebelo, and Mathias Trabandt,
“The Macroeconomics of Epidemics,” National Bureau of Economic Research Working Paper No. 26882, April 2020.

3

A
 lexander W. Bartik, Marianne Bertrand, Zoë B. Cullen, Edward
L. Glaeser, Michael Luca, and Christopher T. Stanton, “How Are
Small Businesses Adjusting to Covid-19? Early Evidence from a
Survey,” National Bureau of Economic Research Working Paper
No. 26989, April 2020.

4

T homas J. Kniesner and W. Kip Viscusi, “The Value of a Statistical Life,” Forthcoming, Oxford Research Encyclopedia of
Economics and Finance; Vanderbilt Law Research Paper No.
19-15, April 2019.

5

L arisa Antonisse and Rachel Garfield, “The Relationship
Between Work and Health: Findings from a Literature Review,”
Henry J Kaiser Family Foundation, August 2018.

6

A
 shley Abramson, “How Covid-19 may increase domestic
violence and child abuse,” American Psychological Association,
April 8, 2020.

7

M
 ark A. Reger, Ian H. Stanley, and Thomas E. Joiner, “Suicide
Mortality and Coronavirus Disease 2019—A Perfect Storm?”
JAMA Psychiatry, April 10, 2020.

8

D
 ana Goldstein, Nikole Hannah-Jones, and Adam Popescu, “As
School Moves Online, Many Students Stay Logged Out,” New
York Times, April 6, 2020.

Page 4

9

J ohn Bailey Jones and Santiago Pinto, “The Long-Term Effects
of Educational Disruptions,” Federal Reserve Bank of Richmond, May 22, 2020.

10

A
 sger Lau Andersen, Emil Toft Hansen, Niels Johannesen, and
Adam Sheridan, “Pandemic, Shutdown and Consumer Spending: Lessons from Scandinavian Policy Responses to Covid-19,”
manuscript, May 2020.

11

A
 ndrew Glover, Jonathan Heathcote, Dirk Krueger, and JoséVíctor Ríos-Rull, “Health versus Wealth: On the Distributional
Effects of Controlling a Pandemic,” manuscript, May 2020.

12

F or example, see Saabira Chaudhuri and Paul Hannon, “Why
the Economic Recovery Will be More of a ‘Swoosh’ Than VShaped,” Wall-Street Journal, May 11, 2020.

13

T om Barkin, “Restoring Consumer Confidence after COVID-19,”
Federal Reserve Bank of Richmond, April 8, 2020; and Paul
Romer, “Roadmap to Responsibly Reopen America,” April 23,
2020.

This article may be photocopied or reprinted in its
entirety. Please credit the authors, source, and the
Federal Reserve Bank of Richmond and include the
italicized statement below.
Views expressed in this article are those of the authors
and not necessarily those of the Federal Reserve Bank
of Richmond or the Federal Reserve System.

Page 5