View original document

The full text on this page is automatically extracted from the file linked above and may contain errors and inconsistencies.

April 13, 2020

Economic Impact of COVID-19
COVID-19 and Households’ Financial Distress
Part 3: How will COVID-19 affect the spending of the
financially distressed?
By Kartik Athreya, Ryan Mather, Jose Mustre-del-Río, and Juan M. Sánchez

In our previous posts (Part 1 and Part 2), we analyzed how public health policies such as social
distancing and “shelter-in-place” orders will likely
have varying employment and earnings consequences across the United States. In particular,
areas characterized by high financial distress are
more likely to suffer employment and earnings
losses due to these policies because they tend to
have higher employment shares in susceptible
industries like Accommodation and Food Services. Furthermore, we showed that the growth of
COVID-19 cases was initially highest in areas with
the least financial distress, but we predicted that
more-distressed areas would soon outpace the
others both in terms of infections and deaths.
In light of how highly financially distressed areas
may bear a disproportionate share of the economic harms, the goal of this post is to examine
what this will mean for household spending
(or “consumption”). To do this, we use a model
(described in detail in our recent working paper)
combined with the empirical results from our
previous posts and arrive at the following conclusions: First, for plausible measures of the likely
earnings losses, our framework suggests that average consumer spending will drop substantially,

April 2020 – Richmond Fed

by around 3.3 percent. Second, and perhaps
more importantly, these consumption declines
are deeply unequal—hitting those living in areas
of highest financial distress the hardest.
Our model is ideal for the present analysis because it features a rich description of household
balance sheets and has clear channels through
which financial distress manifests itself. In terms
of balance sheets, households are allowed to
accumulate credit card debt, save in the kinds
of liquid and safe financial assets they can likely
access in reality (e.g., savings accounts), and
own houses that are financed with mortgages.
In terms of financial distress, our simulationbased approach is one in which households can
become delinquent (i.e., delay) in credit card
payments, file for bankruptcy (which erases all
financial debts), or default on their mortgages
(i.e., enter into foreclosure). Moreover, because
income is uncertain, the model captures the
decisions of households that are aware of the risk
they face and that then make spending and savings choices while taking that uncertainty into
account.

Page 1

To use the model to derive predictions for spending, we generate five artificial economies within our
framework, each meant to model one of the “regions”
or quintiles of financial distress explained in our
previous posts. Recall that the group that we call Q5
is composed of individuals who live in the 20 percent
of zip codes that exhibit the highest levels household
financial distress. Similarly, the group that we call Q1
represents individuals who live in the 20 percent of
zip codes that exhibit the lowest levels household
financial distress.
Our findings from previous posts and other empirical work provide a guide for determining the size
of unexpected income losses across sectors and
quintiles of financial distress.1 At an aggregate level,
we assume final demand falls by 75 percent in the
Accommodation and Food Services sector and in
related sectors like Leisure and Hospitality Services.
Using input-output tables provided by the Bureau of
Labor Statistics, we can trace back how this decline
in demand translates into employment or earnings losses across sectors. The input-output tables
imply this aggregate shock translates into employment losses ranging from roughly 59 percent in the
Accommodation and Food Services sector (which
accounts for roughly 8 percent of total employment
and is the hardest hit) to virtually zero in sectors that
aren’t affected by social distancing (which account
for 40 percent of total employment). Sectors somewhere in the middle that are moderately affected by
social distancing (accounting for 52 percent of total
employment) experience 5 percent employment
losses.2 Finally, because each quintile of financial
distress differs in its composition of employment, we
can convert these sector-specific losses into losses for
each quintile.3 Figure 1 shows the average earnings
loss for each quintile implied by these assumptions.

Figure 1: COVID-19-related earnings losses by quintile of
financial distress

Figure 2 plots the change in spending and makes
clear that financial distress is an important preexisting condition (all numbers are in annual
terms and are calculated as percentage changes
relative to a baseline scenario where the shocks
never occur). Comparing the two extremes, consumption falls by roughly 5 percent in Q5 (highest financial distress), which is more than double
the fall measured in Q1 (lowest financial distress).
Figure 2: The response of consumption to COVID-19related earnings losses by quintile of financial distress

Page 2

Importantly, the declines in consumer spending that
we note above combine two effects. First, regions
with greater financial distress experience larger
earnings losses because they have higher employment shares in Accommodation and Food Services.
Second, higher financial distress regions are more
vulnerable (through pre-existing conditions) to any
shock. Using the machinery of our model, we can
separate these two effects to see which is quantitatively more important.
To gauge the “pure” effect of financial distress as a
pre-existing condition, Figure 3 shows the spending
responses across the financial distress spectrum under an alternative scenario wherein regions experience earnings losses that are identical, and equal to,
those in Q1. By construction, the Q1 bars in Figures 2
and 3 are the same. However, all other bars are different, with the differences reflecting the direct effects
of pre-existing conditions in generating differential
drops in spending. The Q5 bar in Figure 3 shows that
when this region faces an earnings shock similar to
Q1, their consumption still declines by over an extra
percentage point relative to Q1 (3.3 percent versus
2.1 percent). This suggests that roughly 40 percent
of the difference (which was 2.8 percentage points)
in consumers’ spending response between Q1 and
Q5—observed in Figure 2—comes solely from
pre-existing conditions, while the other 60 percent
comes because those with highest financial distress
(Q5) experience larger earnings losses related to
COVID-19.

Our results carry a more general lesson: The
pre-existing condition of financial distress that
we emphasize will matter in a broad array of
circumstances for income losses. To see this,
consider the two lines of Table 1, which show the
ratio of the change in consumption compared to
the change in income under both the baseline
(Figure 2) and alternative (Figure 3) scenarios we
study. Two points emerge: First, in both scenarios, those initially most distressed (Q5) are very
vulnerable. Their spending drops roughly half
a percentage point for each percentage point
decline in income.
Interestingly, both rows have the same numbers, indicating that the elasticity in each FD
group does not depend on the size of the shock.
For instance, Q5 has a reduction of income of
nine percent in the benchmark exercise and six
percent in the uniform shock, and in both cases
the elasticity is 0.52. This in part reflects the way
we have imposed the shocks to income on the
different groups, but is strongly suggestive that
overall sensitivities (i.e., the proportional response of consumer spending to the change in
their income) may not hinge on the size of the
shock. Second, and again in both scenarios, the
response of spending is sizeable, reflecting the
fact that the earnings shocks are hard to cope
with.
Table 1: The ratio of the change in consumption to the
change in earnings, by quintile of financial distress

Figure 3: The response of consumption to COVID-19related earnings losses by quintile of financial distress
(same loss across quintiles)

Overall, our calculations strongly suggest that in
response to the earnings losses that will plausibly
accompany the social distancing response to COVID-19, consumer spending is likely to contract
much more in areas that entered this episode
with higher financial distress. Indeed, our numbers suggest that the decline in consumption will

Page 3

be over twice as large between the lowest and highest quintiles of financial distress. Part of this is related
to the magnitude of the shock each region receives,
but an equally large part is related to the pre-existing
conditions of each region.
What do these results imply for policy? In our view,
the findings here mean that special consideration
should be given to assessing the nature of financial
distress when deciding on policies designed to mitigate or offset these earnings losses. This is especially
true for any policies that are already tailored toward
helping more financially distressed communities,
as they are likely to be most at risk and least able to
maintain their living standards.

This article may be photocopied or reprinted in its
entirety. Please credit the authors, source, and the
Federal Reserve Bank of Richmond and include the
italicized statement below.
Views expressed in this article are those of the authors
and not necessarily those of the Federal Reserve Bank
of Richmond or the Federal Reserve System.

In our next series of posts, we will use our model to
examine the effects of some policy initiatives that
take into explicit account differences in initial consumer financial distress.
Katrik Athreya is executive vice president and director of research at the Richmond Fed. Ryan Mather is
a research associate and Juan M. Sanchez is an assistant vice president at the St. Louis Fed. Jose Mustredel-Rio is a senior economist at the Kansas City Fed.
Endnotes
1

O
 ur methodology is similar to Garriga, Mather, and Sánchez
(2020).

2

T his employment breakdown resembles Leibovici, Santacreu,
and Famiglietti (2020), who categorize occupations by how
contact intensive they are and hence how likely they are to
be affected by social distancing measures. Our numbers are
larger because we account for spillovers across industries and
occupations.

3

F or example, our previous posts show that the employment
share in “Accommodation and Food” ranges from roughly 7
percent in the lowest quintile of financial distress to nearly
11 percent in the highest quintile of financial distress. This
suggests that a larger share of the population in high-distress
areas are likely to receive larger earnings losses.

Page 4