View original document

The full text on this page is automatically extracted from the file linked above and may contain errors and inconsistencies.

The February-April 1987 Episode
When the dollar started to decline
again late in March 1987, officials
apparently feared that it was falling too
far. Excessive decline risked recession
abroad and additional inflationary pressures in the United States. Officials of
the major nations had " ...agreed to cooperate closely to foster stability of ex·
change rates around current levels."!'
Consequently, major nations' central
banks began intervening in foreignexchange markets, buying dollars to
resist the depreciation.
Central- bank-in terven tion purchases
of dollars typically result in an official
capital inflow to the United States-a
form of foreign saving. Because total
foreign saving-private
and officialcan change no more rapidly than the
typically slow change in the trade
deficit, a sharp increase in official foreign saving must be accompanied by an
equally sharp decrease in private foreign saving. The volume of the intervention in this episode was extremely
large and, when measured relative to
the size of the U.S. economy, is among
the largest for any three-month period.
The possibility that there had been a
sudden, large decline in private foreign
saving raised concerns about the continued willingness of private portfolio
holders to acquire dollar assets. Of
course, if central banks had not intervened, exchange rates and interest
rates would have changed enough to
14. Ibid.
15. See Alan Murray, "Debtor's Dilemma: U.S.
Efforts to Deter Foreign Investors Vie with Need
for Capital," The Wall Street Journal, Midwest
Edition, August 5, 1987, p. 1.

Federal Reserve Bank of Cleveland
Research Department
P.O. Box 6387
Cleveland, OR 44101

Material may be reprinted provided that the
source is credited. Please send copies of reprinted
materials to the editor.

attract the amount of foreign private
saving necessary to finance the trade
deficit. The real question is whether
that saving would have come on terms
compatible with domestic investment
of an amount sufficient for continued
growth of the U.S. economy.
We don't know what caused private
portfolio holders to seek more favorable
terms. A reasonable conjecture is that
rising prices of U.S. imports increased
investors' fears that inflation in the
United States would accelerate. Another
possibility is that actions and proposals
by the administration and Congress
that would be adverse to foreign
investment in the United States may
have frightened foreign investors."
Whatever the cause for private portfolio holders' reluctance to invest in the
United States in the February-April
period, the terms of investment ultimately adjusted enough to induce private capital inflow to recover. Interest
rates rose in the United States and fell
abroad, changing interest rate differentials in directions that made dollar
assets more attractive. The dollar
depreciated somewhat despite the intervention, reducing the potential for
future depreciation and making purchases of dollar assets more attractive.
Moreover, then-Federal Reserve Chairman Paul Volcker announced at the
end of April that the Federal Reserve
had tightened monetary policy slightly
"in view of the weakness of the dollar
on foreign-exchange markets.':"
16. See Charles W. Stevens, "Dollar Gains, But
Traders Call Its Move Weak," The Wall Street
Journal, Midwest Edition, May 1, 1987, p. 24.

Federal Reserve Bank of Cleveland
Conclusions
When viewed from the perspective of
the framework we have presented, foreign private funds did not "dry up"
during the February-April 1987 episode.
Instead, the willingness of foreign private portfolio holders to invest in the
United States diminished. When central banks prevented investment terms
from changing sufficiently to maintain
the inflow of private funds, private
portfolio holders, given their diminished willingness to invest, sharply
slowed their acquisition of dollar
assets. When the investment terms
subsequently changed enough, the
inflow of private funds recovered.
Thus, the important issue in this
regard is not the possibility of foreign
funds suddenly becoming unavailable,
but rather the possibility that they may
become available only at interest rates
so high that private domestic investment will be crowded out.
The danger of crowding out domestic
investment could be reduced in at least
three ways. First, the United States
could reduce the federal budget deficit
and thereby reduce its need for foreign
saving. Second, the United States could
continue to pursue policies that will
prevent the reigniting of inflation or
expectations of inflation. Third, the
United States could avoid taking actions
that discourage foreign investment
here. These would be constructive
actions, in contrast to protectionism,
which would be a destructive response
to symptoms caused by excess U.S.
spending and resulting dependence on
foreign saving.

BULK RATE
U.S. Postage Paid
Cleveland, OR
Permit No. 385

Address Correction Requested: Please send
corrected mailing label to the Federal Reserve
Bank of Cleveland, Research Department,
P.O. Box 6387, Cleveland, OH 44101.

Se tember 1, 1987
ISSN 0428-1276

ECONOMIC
COMMENTARY
Earlier this year, foreign central banks
made very substantial purchases of
U.S. securities. They did so with some
of the proceeds of their massive intervention in the foreign-exchange market,
involving purchases of the dollar
intended to prevent its depreciation. In
the same period, private international
investors sharply reduced their net new
investment in U.S. financial markets.
Foreign private investors had been
investing large amounts in the United
States since mid-1982.1 Through the
end of last year, they had placed an
average of $22.6 billion per quarter in
this country. But an estimate suggests
that amount dropped by nearly half in
February-April 1987.2
The recent shift in foreign investment
behavior raises important questions concerning the durability of inflows of foreign private saving. Could these inflows
of foreign private saving dry up? Why
did central banks intervene in foreignexchange markets? What would have
happened if they had not intervened?
Answers to these questions have important implications for the cost and
availability of credit and, in turn, for
the well-being of the U.S. economy.
This Economic Commentary explains
how the flow of foreign saving into the
United States is determined and how international portfolio holders, private
and official, determine the terms at

Gerald H. Anderson is an economic advisor and
John B. Carlson is an economist at the Federal
Reserve Bank of Cleveland. The authors would like
to thank E.]. Stevens for his participation in an
earlier draft, and John Martin for research
assistance.
The views stated herein are those of the authors
and not necessarily those of the Federal Reserve
Bank of Cleveland or of the Board of Governors of
the Federal Reserve System.

which saving is obtained. We also identify factors that made private international portfolio holders willing to acquire
dollar assets at terms consistent with
vigorous U.S. economic growth in the
early part of the current expansion.
Finally, we examine the basis of concerns about the continued willingness
of private portfolio holders to purchase
dollar assets at terms consistent with
the well-being of the U.S. economy.
The Determination of Foreign
Saving Inflow and Its Terms
Foreign saving-a net capital inflowarises when a country spends more
than its income." More precisely, it
arises to finance the excess of aggregate domestic spending (E), including
government expenditures, over
national income (Y). The national
income accounting (NIA) framework
shows that the excess spending (E-Y),
in turn, must equal an excess of
imports over exports (M-X), that is, a
trade deficit of the same amount. In
other words, the excess of goods and
services purchased by domestic spenders over goods and services produced
domestically must be acquired through
foreign trade and must be financed by
an equal amount of foreign saving.
In this sense, foreign saving is the
sine qua non of a trade deficit. Factors
that generate an excess of imports over
exports generate an equal inflow of foreign saving. In fact, both are determined

1. The net inflow of private capital to the United
States is the result of investment decisions' by
U.S. as well as foreign investors, and is the
inflow of foreign private capital, less the outflow
of U.S. private capital. The term "foreign private
investors" is used for convenience of exposition
and because the inflows have been much larger
than the outflows. The net inflow of private capital is calculated here as the U.S. current-account
deficit, minus the increase in foreign official
assets in the United States, plus the increase in
U.S. official reserve and government assets

u.s. Dependence

on Foreign Saving
by Gerald H. Anderson
and John B. Carlson

within the general equilibrium process
of price and income determination by
the fundamental forces that lead a
country to spend more than it earns.
Defining foreign saving as a net capital inflow implies an increase in the
difference between foreign claims on
the United States and U.S. claims on
the rest of the world. Though we normally think of foreign saving as an
increase in foreign ownership of dollar
assets, it need not be. Foreign saving
may result from a reduction in U.S.
ownership of foreign assets. Regardless, international portfolio holders
finance a country's excess spending by
adjusting their portfolios to hold the
change in net external claims.
The coordination between the need for
external financing and the means of
such financing involves a simultaneous
interaction between goods markets,
where trade flows are determined, and
asset markets, where changes in private
portfolio holdings are determined. An
important empirical characteristic of
the coordination process is that trade
flows adjust rather slowly to international economic conditions. Thus, the flow
of foreign saving itself adjusts slowly to
international economic conditions.
Because the willingness of private
international portfolio holders to
finance a nation's trade deficit may
change substantially in the short run,
such changes will be largely reflected
in the terms that are important to

abroad. This method counts the statistical discrepancy in the balance-of-payments accounts as
a private capital flow.
2. Our estimate was made as follows: The
current-account deficit was $37.12 billion in the
first quarter of 1987. Because the current
account changes rather slowly, we assume the
deficit was the same in February-April 1987. We
estimate official capital inflow in February-April
1987 to be $24.63 billion, from tables 3.12 and

these holders-relative
interest rates
and exchange rates-rather
than in the
size of the saving flow. For example, if
international portfolio holders sought
to shift substantial amounts of their
holdings away from dollar assets
toward claims on the rest of the world,
there would be two potential effects.
First, reduced demand for dollar assets
would imply a reduced demand for dollars in foreign-exchange markets.
Other things being equal, this would
put downward pressure on the dollar's
exchange rate. While dollar depreciation would also tend to reduce the trade
deficit, as we have noted, such an effect
occurs rather slowly.'
Second, reduced demand for dollar
assets would tend to reduce the price of
assets and raise the level of interest
rates in the United States relative to interest rates abroad. The key implication is that factors that affect domestic
and foreign investors' willingness to
finance the trade deficit have a much
greater effect on the terms of financing
than on the size of foreign saving in the
short run,>
Increasing Dependence on
Foreign Saving
Since about 1981, the United States has
become increasingly dependent on foreign saving (chart 1, bottom panel)."
Increased dependence on foreign capital
is largely attributable to two factors:
the recent decline in the U.S. domestic
saving rate and the recent increase in,
and persistence of, U.S. budget deficits.
To understand the roles of these factors, it is useful to recognize some additional constraints imposed by the NIA
framework. The definition of saving
allows us to break down excess spending (E-Y) into two components: the difference between private investment
and domestic saving (I-S), plus the difference between federal government
expenditures and taxes (G-T).? Given
that excess spending must be the same
as foreign saving (FS), then FS =
(I-S) + (G-T).

Thus, foreign saving must be equal
to the difference between investment
and domestic saving, plus the federal
budget deficit. This relationship
imposes requirements on the various
components. For example, when the
domestic saving rate declines, as it has
since 1982, increases in budget deficits
relative to output must be met by a
decline in the share of output devoted
to private domestic investment or by an
increase in the foreign saving rate.
Other than the consistency they
impose, accounting identities imply
nothing about underlying behavior.
Thus, one cannot determine from the
identities alone whether one sectoral
imbalance (e.g., governmental) implies
another (e.g., foreign trade). The channels of influence are identifiable only
when auxiliary assumptions are made.
For example, a common view around
1982 was that persistently large U.S.
budget deficits would lead to higher
interest rates as the U.S. economy
approached full employment growth,
and would ultimately crowd out private
domestic investment. In this view,
neither domestic nor foreign saving
was presumed to be sufficiently
responsive to world financial market
conditions to avoid a substantial reduction in domestic investment.
An alternative view, first advanced
by economist Robert Mundell, essentially is that foreign capital is sufficiently mobile to compensate for any
shortfall in domestic saving. A net
inflow of capital would be induced by
the upward pressures on U.S. interest
rates and, hence, on perceived real
returns on dollar assets relative to
assets denominated in other currencies.
The willingness of portfolio holders to
respond strongly to changes in perceived
real interest rate differentials would
dampen the rise in U.S. interest rates
and would thereby moderate' the effects
on domestic investment. In the process
of switching to dollar assets, portfolio
holders would bid up the dollar's
exchange rate. Dollar appreciation
would, in turn, raise the price of goods
produced in the United States relative
to goods produced in other countries and

3.15 in the Federal Reserve Bulletin, vol. 73, no. 8
(August 1987). We subtracted official capital
inflow from the current-account deficit to obtain
our $12.49 billion estimate of private capital
inflow in February-April 1987.

4. See, for example, Gerald H. Anderson and John
B. Carlson, "Does Dollar Depreciation Matter:
The Case of Auto Imports from Japan," Economic
Commentary,
Federal Reserve Bank of Cleveland,
May 1, 1987.

3. The term "foreign saving" is used in this Economic Commentary
to mean the net inflow of foreign capital to the United States.

5. More precisely, the current-account deficit,
rather than the trade deficit, is financed by foreign investors. The difference between the two is
of no consequence in the analysis presented here,
so for ease of exposition we continue to refer to
the trade defici t.

Chart 1 Investment Less
Domestic Saving, Federal
Deficit, and Foreign Saving

6~------~~~--------,

Percent of GNP

Note: Foreign saving is measured as the
current-account balance with the sign
reversed.
SOURCE: U.S. Department of Commerce.

would generate the trade deficit consistent with the foreign saving inflow.
Before the 1980s, the evidence appeared to favor the first view, that
budget deficits would crowd out
investment. Throughout most of the
postwar period, federal budget deficits
tended to be the mirror image of the
difference between private domestic
investment and domestic saving (chart
1, top panel)," In cyclical contractions,
budget deficits increased, reflecting
declining tax revenues and increasing
expenditures on income maintenance
programs. Both investment and consumption declined relative to income,
so that the difference between domestic
investment and saving widened as the
deficit increased. In economic expansions, deficits shrank while investment
and consumption increased relative to
income, so that the difference between
investment and saving narrowed.

6. Foreign saving is measured here as the
current-account balance with the sign reversed.
Thus, it includes measured net capital inflow
plus the statistical discrepancy in the balance-ofpayments accounts. This measure differs only
slightly from net foreign investment in the
National Income and Product Accounts, which is
another name for foreign saving. This slight difference does not affect our analysis.

The cyclical patterns appeared to
support the first view because investment tended to decrease when budget
deficits increased, while foreign saving
seemed to be unaffected. The budget
deficits during this period, however,
might not have been persistently large
enough to provide a basis for discriminating between the two views of the
effects of budget deficits.
After 1982, budget deficits averaged
about 5 percent of GNP, compared with
2.4 percent in the 1970s and less than 1
percent in the 1960s. Moreover, the
domestic saving rate decreased from
18.0 percent in 1981 to 16.2 percent in
1986. Nonetheless, private investment
increased, supported by an enlarged
inflow of foreign saving. The strength
of investment-particularly
in the earlier stages of the recovery-and the
appreciating dollar suggest that the
Mundell view was correct.
On the other hand, estimates of real
U.S. interest rates suggest that rates
rose sharply and stayed high through
1984. Moreover, real interest rate differentials also increased in favor of dollar assets." To many analysts, real
interest rates in the United States
seemed too high to be consistent with
the strong economic recovery, particularly the strong investment boom in
1983-1984. The administration reasoned, however, that the Economic
Recovery and Tax Act of 1981, together
with disinflation, significantly raised
the after-tax real rate of return on new
business investment. This increase in
the real rate of return on new capital
assets spilled over into markets competing for dollar assets and, in the context of unchanged monetary policy,
raised their yields.
Because these interest rate increases
were caused by an increase in demand
for U.S. real capital assets, rather than
just an increased supply of Treasury
debt, the interest rate increase was not
associated with a decline in investment. Thus, it is not clear which of the

two views-investment
crowding out,
or compensating foreign capital-would
have prevailed in the absence of tax
incentives for investment.
While it seems clear that foreign capital is more responsive to interest rate
differentials than many analysts previously had thought, other factors also
may have accounted for the willingness
of foreign investors to make up the
shortfall in U.S. saving at the terms
they did. One important reason was the
debt crisis in developing countries that
surfaced in 1982, which discouraged
international lenders from lending to
those countries and encouraged capital
flight from those debtor nations to the
United States and other havens.
In addition, the Japanese government
liberalized its own foreign-exchange
laws in December 1980, which enhanced
the marketability of U.S. securities in
Japan. Japanese net purchases of U.S.
securities increased from $0.8 billion in
1982 to $29.9 billion in 1985. Finally, in
1984, the U.S. repealed its 30 percent
withholding tax on interest paid to foreign residents, further enhancing foreign demand for U.S. securities.
To the extent these factors increased
the demand for dollar assets, they
helped to keep U.S. interest rates below
what they would have been and to
drive the dollar's exchange rate higher.
Moreover, to the extent these factors
can change, there is a risk that foreign
investors will begin to demand even
greater returns on their investments
than have recently prevailed.
How long foreign lenders will continue to lend at present terms may be
less important than a pressing problem
that reflects the counterpart to foreign
saving: the trade deficit. While large
budget deficits have not had a discernible adverse effect on domestic investment, they have, through the associated trade deficits, crowded out both
exporters and businesses that compete
against imports. The strain in these
sectors has led to the most serious
threats of protectionism since the
Great Depression.

7. Domestic saving is defined here and in chart 1
as non federal domestic saving, which includes
private saving, gross business saving, and the
budget surplus of state and local governments,

lar in the Eighties," Economic Commentary, Federal Reserve Bank of Cleveland, September 1, 1985.

8. For a more detailed discussion, see Economic
Report 0/ the President, January 1987, U.S.
Government Printing Office, Washington, D,C.,
pp. 109·111.
9. For estimates of real interest rates and their
role in the dollar's appreciation, see Owen F.
Humpage and Nicholas V. Karamouzis, "The Dol-

10. See "Group of Five's Communique on Coordination of Economic Policies and Steps to Be
Taken Leading to Dollar Depreciation, Released
Sept. 22, 1985: Announcement of the Ministers of
Finance and Central Bank Governors of France,
Germany, Japan, the United Kingdom, and the
United States," Daily Report/or Executives, The
Bureau of National Affairs, Washington, D.C.,
September 24,1985, pp. M1-M3.

Reducing Dependence on
Foreign Saving
Senior officials of the Group of Five
nations (France, West Germany, Japan,
the United Kingdom, and the United
States) recognized that the large U.S.
external imbalance could lead to damaging protectionist actions by the United
States. Following its meeting in September 1985, the Group of Five stated
in its Plaza Accord that protectionism
here " ...could lead to mutually destructive retaliation with serious damage to
the world economy ... "IO
Protectionism can damage the world
economy by interfering with the gains
from international trade and by raising
prices. To reduce the U.S. external imbalance, the Group agreed on the need to
reduce the U.S. budget deficit, to encourage orderly depreciation of the dollar,
and to encourage spending growth in
U.S. trading partner countries. I I
Together, these actions would tend to
reduce excess spending in the United
States and excess saving abroad, as
well as reduce trade imbalances.
Following the Plaza Accord, the dollar continued the depreciation that
began in February 1985. By February
1987, the dollar had fallen to a level
that officials of major nations agreed
was low enough. They agreed that
their currencies were then " ...within
ranges broadly consistent with underlying economic fundamentals ... "12
Although the nominal trade deficit had
shrunk only slightly, the real trade
imbalance was beginning to show solid
progress, which was augmenting economic growth in the United States and
tending to diminish growth in West
Germany and Japan. The officials agreed
that "further substantial exchange rate
shifts among their currencies could
damage growth and adjustment prospects in their countries."13

11. A factor contributing to the trade deficit was
that the economies of several other major nations
had been growing more slowly than that of the
United States.
12. See "Text of the Communique Issued by the
Ministers of Finance and Central Bank Governors of Six Major Industrialized Countries Following Their Meeting in Paris on 2/22/87," Bank
for International Settlements, BIS Review, no. 37,
February 23, 1987.
13. Ibid.

these holders-relative
interest rates
and exchange rates-rather
than in the
size of the saving flow. For example, if
international portfolio holders sought
to shift substantial amounts of their
holdings away from dollar assets
toward claims on the rest of the world,
there would be two potential effects.
First, reduced demand for dollar assets
would imply a reduced demand for dollars in foreign-exchange markets.
Other things being equal, this would
put downward pressure on the dollar's
exchange rate. While dollar depreciation would also tend to reduce the trade
deficit, as we have noted, such an effect
occurs rather slowly.'
Second, reduced demand for dollar
assets would tend to reduce the price of
assets and raise the level of interest
rates in the United States relative to interest rates abroad. The key implication is that factors that affect domestic
and foreign investors' willingness to
finance the trade deficit have a much
greater effect on the terms of financing
than on the size of foreign saving in the
short run,>
Increasing Dependence on
Foreign Saving
Since about 1981, the United States has
become increasingly dependent on foreign saving (chart 1, bottom panel)."
Increased dependence on foreign capital
is largely attributable to two factors:
the recent decline in the U.S. domestic
saving rate and the recent increase in,
and persistence of, U.S. budget deficits.
To understand the roles of these factors, it is useful to recognize some additional constraints imposed by the NIA
framework. The definition of saving
allows us to break down excess spending (E-Y) into two components: the difference between private investment
and domestic saving (I-S), plus the difference between federal government
expenditures and taxes (G-T).? Given
that excess spending must be the same
as foreign saving (FS), then FS =
(I-S) + (G-T).

Thus, foreign saving must be equal
to the difference between investment
and domestic saving, plus the federal
budget deficit. This relationship
imposes requirements on the various
components. For example, when the
domestic saving rate declines, as it has
since 1982, increases in budget deficits
relative to output must be met by a
decline in the share of output devoted
to private domestic investment or by an
increase in the foreign saving rate.
Other than the consistency they
impose, accounting identities imply
nothing about underlying behavior.
Thus, one cannot determine from the
identities alone whether one sectoral
imbalance (e.g., governmental) implies
another (e.g., foreign trade). The channels of influence are identifiable only
when auxiliary assumptions are made.
For example, a common view around
1982 was that persistently large U.S.
budget deficits would lead to higher
interest rates as the U.S. economy
approached full employment growth,
and would ultimately crowd out private
domestic investment. In this view,
neither domestic nor foreign saving
was presumed to be sufficiently
responsive to world financial market
conditions to avoid a substantial reduction in domestic investment.
An alternative view, first advanced
by economist Robert Mundell, essentially is that foreign capital is sufficiently mobile to compensate for any
shortfall in domestic saving. A net
inflow of capital would be induced by
the upward pressures on U.S. interest
rates and, hence, on perceived real
returns on dollar assets relative to
assets denominated in other currencies.
The willingness of portfolio holders to
respond strongly to changes in perceived
real interest rate differentials would
dampen the rise in U.S. interest rates
and would thereby moderate' the effects
on domestic investment. In the process
of switching to dollar assets, portfolio
holders would bid up the dollar's
exchange rate. Dollar appreciation
would, in turn, raise the price of goods
produced in the United States relative
to goods produced in other countries and

3.15 in the Federal Reserve Bulletin, vol. 73, no. 8
(August 1987). We subtracted official capital
inflow from the current-account deficit to obtain
our $12.49 billion estimate of private capital
inflow in February-April 1987.

4. See, for example, Gerald H. Anderson and John
B. Carlson, "Does Dollar Depreciation Matter:
The Case of Auto Imports from Japan," Economic
Commentary,
Federal Reserve Bank of Cleveland,
May 1, 1987.

3. The term "foreign saving" is used in this Economic Commentary
to mean the net inflow of foreign capital to the United States.

5. More precisely, the current-account deficit,
rather than the trade deficit, is financed by foreign investors. The difference between the two is
of no consequence in the analysis presented here,
so for ease of exposition we continue to refer to
the trade defici t.

Chart 1 Investment Less
Domestic Saving, Federal
Deficit, and Foreign Saving

6~------~~~--------,

Percent of GNP

Note: Foreign saving is measured as the
current-account balance with the sign
reversed.
SOURCE: U.S. Department of Commerce.

would generate the trade deficit consistent with the foreign saving inflow.
Before the 1980s, the evidence appeared to favor the first view, that
budget deficits would crowd out
investment. Throughout most of the
postwar period, federal budget deficits
tended to be the mirror image of the
difference between private domestic
investment and domestic saving (chart
1, top panel)," In cyclical contractions,
budget deficits increased, reflecting
declining tax revenues and increasing
expenditures on income maintenance
programs. Both investment and consumption declined relative to income,
so that the difference between domestic
investment and saving widened as the
deficit increased. In economic expansions, deficits shrank while investment
and consumption increased relative to
income, so that the difference between
investment and saving narrowed.

6. Foreign saving is measured here as the
current-account balance with the sign reversed.
Thus, it includes measured net capital inflow
plus the statistical discrepancy in the balance-ofpayments accounts. This measure differs only
slightly from net foreign investment in the
National Income and Product Accounts, which is
another name for foreign saving. This slight difference does not affect our analysis.

The cyclical patterns appeared to
support the first view because investment tended to decrease when budget
deficits increased, while foreign saving
seemed to be unaffected. The budget
deficits during this period, however,
might not have been persistently large
enough to provide a basis for discriminating between the two views of the
effects of budget deficits.
After 1982, budget deficits averaged
about 5 percent of GNP, compared with
2.4 percent in the 1970s and less than 1
percent in the 1960s. Moreover, the
domestic saving rate decreased from
18.0 percent in 1981 to 16.2 percent in
1986. Nonetheless, private investment
increased, supported by an enlarged
inflow of foreign saving. The strength
of investment-particularly
in the earlier stages of the recovery-and the
appreciating dollar suggest that the
Mundell view was correct.
On the other hand, estimates of real
U.S. interest rates suggest that rates
rose sharply and stayed high through
1984. Moreover, real interest rate differentials also increased in favor of dollar assets." To many analysts, real
interest rates in the United States
seemed too high to be consistent with
the strong economic recovery, particularly the strong investment boom in
1983-1984. The administration reasoned, however, that the Economic
Recovery and Tax Act of 1981, together
with disinflation, significantly raised
the after-tax real rate of return on new
business investment. This increase in
the real rate of return on new capital
assets spilled over into markets competing for dollar assets and, in the context of unchanged monetary policy,
raised their yields.
Because these interest rate increases
were caused by an increase in demand
for U.S. real capital assets, rather than
just an increased supply of Treasury
debt, the interest rate increase was not
associated with a decline in investment. Thus, it is not clear which of the

two views-investment
crowding out,
or compensating foreign capital-would
have prevailed in the absence of tax
incentives for investment.
While it seems clear that foreign capital is more responsive to interest rate
differentials than many analysts previously had thought, other factors also
may have accounted for the willingness
of foreign investors to make up the
shortfall in U.S. saving at the terms
they did. One important reason was the
debt crisis in developing countries that
surfaced in 1982, which discouraged
international lenders from lending to
those countries and encouraged capital
flight from those debtor nations to the
United States and other havens.
In addition, the Japanese government
liberalized its own foreign-exchange
laws in December 1980, which enhanced
the marketability of U.S. securities in
Japan. Japanese net purchases of U.S.
securities increased from $0.8 billion in
1982 to $29.9 billion in 1985. Finally, in
1984, the U.S. repealed its 30 percent
withholding tax on interest paid to foreign residents, further enhancing foreign demand for U.S. securities.
To the extent these factors increased
the demand for dollar assets, they
helped to keep U.S. interest rates below
what they would have been and to
drive the dollar's exchange rate higher.
Moreover, to the extent these factors
can change, there is a risk that foreign
investors will begin to demand even
greater returns on their investments
than have recently prevailed.
How long foreign lenders will continue to lend at present terms may be
less important than a pressing problem
that reflects the counterpart to foreign
saving: the trade deficit. While large
budget deficits have not had a discernible adverse effect on domestic investment, they have, through the associated trade deficits, crowded out both
exporters and businesses that compete
against imports. The strain in these
sectors has led to the most serious
threats of protectionism since the
Great Depression.

7. Domestic saving is defined here and in chart 1
as non federal domestic saving, which includes
private saving, gross business saving, and the
budget surplus of state and local governments,

lar in the Eighties," Economic Commentary, Federal Reserve Bank of Cleveland, September 1, 1985.

8. For a more detailed discussion, see Economic
Report 0/ the President, January 1987, U.S.
Government Printing Office, Washington, D,C.,
pp. 109·111.
9. For estimates of real interest rates and their
role in the dollar's appreciation, see Owen F.
Humpage and Nicholas V. Karamouzis, "The Dol-

10. See "Group of Five's Communique on Coordination of Economic Policies and Steps to Be
Taken Leading to Dollar Depreciation, Released
Sept. 22, 1985: Announcement of the Ministers of
Finance and Central Bank Governors of France,
Germany, Japan, the United Kingdom, and the
United States," Daily Report/or Executives, The
Bureau of National Affairs, Washington, D.C.,
September 24,1985, pp. M1-M3.

Reducing Dependence on
Foreign Saving
Senior officials of the Group of Five
nations (France, West Germany, Japan,
the United Kingdom, and the United
States) recognized that the large U.S.
external imbalance could lead to damaging protectionist actions by the United
States. Following its meeting in September 1985, the Group of Five stated
in its Plaza Accord that protectionism
here " ...could lead to mutually destructive retaliation with serious damage to
the world economy ... "IO
Protectionism can damage the world
economy by interfering with the gains
from international trade and by raising
prices. To reduce the U.S. external imbalance, the Group agreed on the need to
reduce the U.S. budget deficit, to encourage orderly depreciation of the dollar,
and to encourage spending growth in
U.S. trading partner countries. I I
Together, these actions would tend to
reduce excess spending in the United
States and excess saving abroad, as
well as reduce trade imbalances.
Following the Plaza Accord, the dollar continued the depreciation that
began in February 1985. By February
1987, the dollar had fallen to a level
that officials of major nations agreed
was low enough. They agreed that
their currencies were then " ...within
ranges broadly consistent with underlying economic fundamentals ... "12
Although the nominal trade deficit had
shrunk only slightly, the real trade
imbalance was beginning to show solid
progress, which was augmenting economic growth in the United States and
tending to diminish growth in West
Germany and Japan. The officials agreed
that "further substantial exchange rate
shifts among their currencies could
damage growth and adjustment prospects in their countries."13

11. A factor contributing to the trade deficit was
that the economies of several other major nations
had been growing more slowly than that of the
United States.
12. See "Text of the Communique Issued by the
Ministers of Finance and Central Bank Governors of Six Major Industrialized Countries Following Their Meeting in Paris on 2/22/87," Bank
for International Settlements, BIS Review, no. 37,
February 23, 1987.
13. Ibid.

The February-April 1987 Episode
When the dollar started to decline
again late in March 1987, officials
apparently feared that it was falling too
far. Excessive decline risked recession
abroad and additional inflationary pressures in the United States. Officials of
the major nations had " ...agreed to cooperate closely to foster stability of ex·
change rates around current levels."!'
Consequently, major nations' central
banks began intervening in foreignexchange markets, buying dollars to
resist the depreciation.
Central- bank-in terven tion purchases
of dollars typically result in an official
capital inflow to the United States-a
form of foreign saving. Because total
foreign saving-private
and officialcan change no more rapidly than the
typically slow change in the trade
deficit, a sharp increase in official foreign saving must be accompanied by an
equally sharp decrease in private foreign saving. The volume of the intervention in this episode was extremely
large and, when measured relative to
the size of the U.S. economy, is among
the largest for any three-month period.
The possibility that there had been a
sudden, large decline in private foreign
saving raised concerns about the continued willingness of private portfolio
holders to acquire dollar assets. Of
course, if central banks had not intervened, exchange rates and interest
rates would have changed enough to
14. Ibid.
15. See Alan Murray, "Debtor's Dilemma: U.S.
Efforts to Deter Foreign Investors Vie with Need
for Capital," The Wall Street Journal, Midwest
Edition, August 5, 1987, p. 1.

Federal Reserve Bank of Cleveland
Research Department
P.O. Box 6387
Cleveland, OR 44101

Material may be reprinted provided that the
source is credited. Please send copies of reprinted
materials to the editor.

attract the amount of foreign private
saving necessary to finance the trade
deficit. The real question is whether
that saving would have come on terms
compatible with domestic investment
of an amount sufficient for continued
growth of the U.S. economy.
We don't know what caused private
portfolio holders to seek more favorable
terms. A reasonable conjecture is that
rising prices of U.S. imports increased
investors' fears that inflation in the
United States would accelerate. Another
possibility is that actions and proposals
by the administration and Congress
that would be adverse to foreign
investment in the United States may
have frightened foreign investors."
Whatever the cause for private portfolio holders' reluctance to invest in the
United States in the February-April
period, the terms of investment ultimately adjusted enough to induce private capital inflow to recover. Interest
rates rose in the United States and fell
abroad, changing interest rate differentials in directions that made dollar
assets more attractive. The dollar
depreciated somewhat despite the intervention, reducing the potential for
future depreciation and making purchases of dollar assets more attractive.
Moreover, then-Federal Reserve Chairman Paul Volcker announced at the
end of April that the Federal Reserve
had tightened monetary policy slightly
"in view of the weakness of the dollar
on foreign-exchange markets.':"
16. See Charles W. Stevens, "Dollar Gains, But
Traders Call Its Move Weak," The Wall Street
Journal, Midwest Edition, May 1, 1987, p. 24.

Federal Reserve Bank of Cleveland
Conclusions
When viewed from the perspective of
the framework we have presented, foreign private funds did not "dry up"
during the February-April 1987 episode.
Instead, the willingness of foreign private portfolio holders to invest in the
United States diminished. When central banks prevented investment terms
from changing sufficiently to maintain
the inflow of private funds, private
portfolio holders, given their diminished willingness to invest, sharply
slowed their acquisition of dollar
assets. When the investment terms
subsequently changed enough, the
inflow of private funds recovered.
Thus, the important issue in this
regard is not the possibility of foreign
funds suddenly becoming unavailable,
but rather the possibility that they may
become available only at interest rates
so high that private domestic investment will be crowded out.
The danger of crowding out domestic
investment could be reduced in at least
three ways. First, the United States
could reduce the federal budget deficit
and thereby reduce its need for foreign
saving. Second, the United States could
continue to pursue policies that will
prevent the reigniting of inflation or
expectations of inflation. Third, the
United States could avoid taking actions
that discourage foreign investment
here. These would be constructive
actions, in contrast to protectionism,
which would be a destructive response
to symptoms caused by excess U.S.
spending and resulting dependence on
foreign saving.

BULK RATE
U.S. Postage Paid
Cleveland, OR
Permit No. 385

Address Correction Requested: Please send
corrected mailing label to the Federal Reserve
Bank of Cleveland, Research Department,
P.O. Box 6387, Cleveland, OH 44101.

Se tember 1, 1987
ISSN 0428-1276

ECONOMIC
COMMENTARY
Earlier this year, foreign central banks
made very substantial purchases of
U.S. securities. They did so with some
of the proceeds of their massive intervention in the foreign-exchange market,
involving purchases of the dollar
intended to prevent its depreciation. In
the same period, private international
investors sharply reduced their net new
investment in U.S. financial markets.
Foreign private investors had been
investing large amounts in the United
States since mid-1982.1 Through the
end of last year, they had placed an
average of $22.6 billion per quarter in
this country. But an estimate suggests
that amount dropped by nearly half in
February-April 1987.2
The recent shift in foreign investment
behavior raises important questions concerning the durability of inflows of foreign private saving. Could these inflows
of foreign private saving dry up? Why
did central banks intervene in foreignexchange markets? What would have
happened if they had not intervened?
Answers to these questions have important implications for the cost and
availability of credit and, in turn, for
the well-being of the U.S. economy.
This Economic Commentary explains
how the flow of foreign saving into the
United States is determined and how international portfolio holders, private
and official, determine the terms at

Gerald H. Anderson is an economic advisor and
John B. Carlson is an economist at the Federal
Reserve Bank of Cleveland. The authors would like
to thank E.]. Stevens for his participation in an
earlier draft, and John Martin for research
assistance.
The views stated herein are those of the authors
and not necessarily those of the Federal Reserve
Bank of Cleveland or of the Board of Governors of
the Federal Reserve System.

which saving is obtained. We also identify factors that made private international portfolio holders willing to acquire
dollar assets at terms consistent with
vigorous U.S. economic growth in the
early part of the current expansion.
Finally, we examine the basis of concerns about the continued willingness
of private portfolio holders to purchase
dollar assets at terms consistent with
the well-being of the U.S. economy.
The Determination of Foreign
Saving Inflow and Its Terms
Foreign saving-a net capital inflowarises when a country spends more
than its income." More precisely, it
arises to finance the excess of aggregate domestic spending (E), including
government expenditures, over
national income (Y). The national
income accounting (NIA) framework
shows that the excess spending (E-Y),
in turn, must equal an excess of
imports over exports (M-X), that is, a
trade deficit of the same amount. In
other words, the excess of goods and
services purchased by domestic spenders over goods and services produced
domestically must be acquired through
foreign trade and must be financed by
an equal amount of foreign saving.
In this sense, foreign saving is the
sine qua non of a trade deficit. Factors
that generate an excess of imports over
exports generate an equal inflow of foreign saving. In fact, both are determined

1. The net inflow of private capital to the United
States is the result of investment decisions' by
U.S. as well as foreign investors, and is the
inflow of foreign private capital, less the outflow
of U.S. private capital. The term "foreign private
investors" is used for convenience of exposition
and because the inflows have been much larger
than the outflows. The net inflow of private capital is calculated here as the U.S. current-account
deficit, minus the increase in foreign official
assets in the United States, plus the increase in
U.S. official reserve and government assets

u.s. Dependence

on Foreign Saving
by Gerald H. Anderson
and John B. Carlson

within the general equilibrium process
of price and income determination by
the fundamental forces that lead a
country to spend more than it earns.
Defining foreign saving as a net capital inflow implies an increase in the
difference between foreign claims on
the United States and U.S. claims on
the rest of the world. Though we normally think of foreign saving as an
increase in foreign ownership of dollar
assets, it need not be. Foreign saving
may result from a reduction in U.S.
ownership of foreign assets. Regardless, international portfolio holders
finance a country's excess spending by
adjusting their portfolios to hold the
change in net external claims.
The coordination between the need for
external financing and the means of
such financing involves a simultaneous
interaction between goods markets,
where trade flows are determined, and
asset markets, where changes in private
portfolio holdings are determined. An
important empirical characteristic of
the coordination process is that trade
flows adjust rather slowly to international economic conditions. Thus, the flow
of foreign saving itself adjusts slowly to
international economic conditions.
Because the willingness of private
international portfolio holders to
finance a nation's trade deficit may
change substantially in the short run,
such changes will be largely reflected
in the terms that are important to

abroad. This method counts the statistical discrepancy in the balance-of-payments accounts as
a private capital flow.
2. Our estimate was made as follows: The
current-account deficit was $37.12 billion in the
first quarter of 1987. Because the current
account changes rather slowly, we assume the
deficit was the same in February-April 1987. We
estimate official capital inflow in February-April
1987 to be $24.63 billion, from tables 3.12 and