View original document

The full text on this page is automatically extracted from the file linked above and may contain errors and inconsistencies.

October 15, 2000

Federal Reserve Bank of Cleveland

Two Deposit Insurance Funds Are Not
Necessarily Better than One
by James B. Thomson

T

he Great Depression opened an era of
increased federal government intervention into private markets. It brought
striking changes to the financial sector,
where legislation like the Glass–Steagall
Act of 1933 sought to compartmentalize
financial firms and markets into distinct
sets of activities (commercial banking,
housing finance, investment banking,
and insurance). This fragmentation was
mirrored in government agencies, where
a separate regulatory infrastructure was
established for each segment of the
financial system. The change also meant
setting up two different insurance funds
for depository institutions: one for those
engaged primarily in housing finance
(savings and loans) and another for
commercial banks.1
Three eventful decades have now blurred
the distinctions between financial markets and financial firms. Rising inflation
in the 1970s and rapid advances in information and computing technology contributed to a rapid pace of market innovations that effectively dismantled the
Glass–Steagall barriers, many of which
were formally lifted by the Financial
Modernization Act of 1999. For depository institutions, the 1980s thrift debacle
and U.S. regional banking problems
brought on the Financial Institutions
Reform, Recovery, and Enforcement Act
of 1989, which reduced or eliminated
differences in federal regulatory structures for commercial banks and savings
associations but still retained a separate
chartering agency for each.
With the passage of the Financial Modernization Act, the FDIC began reforming our system of federal deposit guarantees. Recently, the FDIC posted a
ISSN 0428-1276

“Deposit Insurance Options” paper on its
Web site for public comment.2 Among
the possible reforms described there is a
merger of its Bank Insurance Fund and its
Savings Association Insurance Fund (BIF
and SAIF). This Economic Commentary
explores that possibility with an examination of the primary arguments for maintaining separate bank and thrift deposit
insurance funds. While each of these
arguments may have seemed valid in the
past, none is defensible today. Moreover,
evidence that merging the two funds
would reduce taxpayers’ exposure to loss
indicates that this deposit insurance
reform is long overdue.3

■ Promoting Home Finance
The idea of separate deposit insurance
funds for banks and savings associations
took root in the regulatory and legislative
environment of the 1930s. Commercial
banking and home finance, traditionally
viewed as distinct financial activities,
were treated as such when the regulatory
infrastructure for depository institutions
was revamped. Commercial banks and
savings banks were to be insured by the
Federal Deposit Insurance Corporation, a
federal government agency newly created by the Glass–Steagall Act. The
FDIC would be independent from the
U.S. Treasury (and its chartering agency,
the Office of the Comptroller of the Currency) as well as from the Federal
Reserve System, adding yet another
player to the already fragmented federal
regulatory system for banks. In contrast,
the Federal Savings and Loan Insurance
Corporation, created by the National
Housing Act of 1934 to insure deposits in
thrifts, would be a subsidiary of the
Federal Home Loan Bank System.4 The
System had been established in 1932 as

Does the United States need to
maintain two separate insurance
funds for banks and thrifts? This
Economic Commentary examines
the arguments in support of a recent
reform proposal for merging them.

a regulatory infrastructure for savings
and loan associations under the Federal
Home Loan Bank Board.
Congress created a parallel regulatory
infrastructure for housing finance lenders
to promote home building and ownership.
Unlike the agencies for regulating banks,
the Federal Home Loan Bank Board had
a mandate to promote the industry it regulated.5 Promoting the housing finance
industry, however, might conflict with the
Bank Board’s regulatory safety and
soundness mandate and would certainly
conflict with a deposit guarantor’s duty to
protect the depositor and the taxpayer
from loss. By creating a separate deposit
insurance fund for thrifts that is subservient to the Federal Home Loan Bank
Board, Congress strengthened the thrift
regulator’s ability to pursue its industrypromotion objective.
By passing the Financial Institutions
Reform, Recovery, and Enforcement Act
(FIRREA) in 1989 and the Federal
Deposit Insurance Corporation Improvement Act (FDICIA) in 1991, Congress
rejected the idea that a federal regulatory
agency should be charged with promoting the industry it regulates.6 FIRREA
dismantled the single regulatory
structure for housing finance. While it
stopped short of merging thrift and

banking industry regulators, it placed the
federal thrift chartering and supervisory
agency under the U.S. Treasury Department (where the equivalent banking
agency is housed) and created a new
deposit insurance fund for thrifts within
the FDIC. Moreover, Congress’ intention
that the FDICIA would “align the incentives of institutions’ owners, managers,
and regulators more closely with the
interests of the deposit insurance funds”
is further evidence that it no longer
viewed the federal thrift regulatory structure as an appropriate tool for promoting
the housing finance industry.7 Hence,
maintaining a separate Savings Association Insurance Fund cannot be justified
on these grounds. Finally, recent research
questions the need for a separate agency
to promote housing finance.8

■ Regulatory Competition
Economists generally consider competition an effective discipline for both
private firms and public agencies. In the
area of bank regulation, competition
between the three federal regulatory
agencies and between federal and state
regulators has been said to confer two
important benefits: Regulatory competition checks overzealous regulators by
mitigating their tendency to stifle innovation and restrict new entrants. Moreover,
competition encourages regulatory agencies to innovate, thus increasing their
effectiveness and lightening the burden of
regulation costs borne by their clients.9
Of course, the benefits of regulatory competition must be weighed against the
higher administrative costs of maintaining multiple agencies and the potential
for competition in laxity.10
In the area of deposit insurance, regulatory competition would help align
insurers’ incentives with those of
uninsured depositors and taxpayers.
The funds would have incentives to
intervene in the affairs of troubled
depository institutions more quickly and
to handle receiverships in the most efficient, cost-effective manner. An insurance fund’s weakness—in the form of
unbooked losses—would be exposed as
its solvent members sought the safety of
the rival fund. For regulatory competition to yield benefits for deposit insurance, certain conditions must be met:
First, the funds must be housed in
separate, independent agencies. Second,
insured depository institutions must have
the right to switch funds when it is in

their interest to do so.11 Neither of these
conditions is met in the current configuration of BIF and SAIF; so it is unlikely
that any competitive benefits now offset
the costs of maintaining two separate
FDIC deposit insurance funds.

■ Cross-Industry Subsidies
Unlike most private insurance arrangements, federal deposit insurance does not
use actuarial principles to determine the
size of its reserve. Instead, the BIF and
the SAIF attempt to maintain a ratio of
fund reserves to insured deposits of 125
basis points, a target established by the
FIRREA. The level of premiums
assessed, therefore, depends on the fund’s
level in relation to the target reserve ratio.
All else being equal, institutions pay
higher deposit insurance premiums when
their FDIC fund’s reserve-to-insureddeposit ratio is below 125 basis points
than when the target is met or exceeded.
Hence, operating both the BIF and the
SAIF results in a form of limited crossguarantee of fund members’ losses
associated with closing failed banks and
thrifts.12 In other words, losses resulting
from institutions that close today are
covered by higher future premiums paid
by a fund’s surviving members.
Initially, concern about merging the
BIF and the SAIF may have arisen
because future premium assessments
were used to underwrite current losses to
the reserve. This created the possibility
that BIF institutions could be taxed
through higher premiums to help clean
up the massive red-ink spill that once
affected much of the thrift industry.
When the SAIF was created, upward of
$200 billion in losses were associated
with resolving closed thrifts, so keeping
the funds separate may have served to
assuage banks’ legitimate concerns
about using their deposit insurance fund
to underwrite some of the Federal Savings and Loan Insurance Corporation’s
losses. Furthermore, the rapid expansion
of insured liabilities that resulted from
admitting even the remaining solvent
thrifts into the banks’ insurance fund
would have further lowered an already
inadequate reserve-to-insured-deposit
ratio and so required higher BIF depositguarantee assessments in the future.
Now that the resolution of the thrift
debacle is complete, no reason remains
to keep operating separate FDIC funds to
protect banks from past losses in the

housing finance industry. Moreover, as
figure 1 shows, both the BIF and the
SAIF have exceeded the target ratio of
125 basis points since 1996. Hence,
merging the funds would not dilute the
BIF’s reserve or raise its members’ premiums. In fact, the SAIF’s reserve-toinsured-deposit ratio currently exceeds
that of the BIF.
A more relevant concern today is the
possibility that, through the two funds’
cross-guarantee, a merger could expose
banks and housing finance lenders to
risks they would not normally bear. This
might be because these two types of
depository institutions operate in distinct
markets. It may also reflect a conscious
choice to avoid certain types of exposure,
either because of risk-management
concerns or because an activity brings
returns that are too low to warrant the
degree of exposure it entails.
Several reasons invalidate this rationale
for maintaining separate funds. First,
financial market integration has effectively removed economic distinctions
between depository institutions and the
risks they face, making it difficult to
argue that banks and savings associations
operate in distinct markets with widely
different types of risk exposure. For
instance, roughly 48 percent of bank
loans are related to real estate (24 percent
to home mortgages alone), and more than
12 percent of loans made by thrifts are
commercial and industrial loans or consumer loans. In fact, the banking industry
currently has, in absolute terms, nearly
1.6 times more dollars invested in home
mortgages than thrifts have.13 Consequently, it is hard to see how merging the
BIF with the SAIF would expose banks
and thrifts to new risks or to risks they
purposely seek to avoid.
Probably the most damning evidence
against the cross-industry subsidy
argument for maintaining separate
funds is the composition of the funds
themselves. Nearly 40 percent of
deposits insured by the SAIF are made
in commercial banks. Savings association deposits account for 9 percent of
BIF accounts. In addition, restrictions
on moving deposits between the BIF
and the SAIF and the ongoing consolidation of the depository institution
sector have caused some banks and
thrifts to have deposits insured by both
funds. BIF members currently own

TABLE 1: INSURANCE FUND RESERVES

Cleveland, Economic Commentary,
June 1995; and “Making the SAIF
Safe for Taxpayers,” Federal Reserve
Bank of Cleveland, Economic
Commentary, November 1, 1993.

Percent of insured deposits
1.60
BIF
SAIF

1.40

Target

4. When federal deposit insurance
was created, most savings banks and
all federal savings and loans were
organized as mutual institutions.
Therefore, deposit accounts at these
institutions were technically “equity
shares,” much as they are in credit
unions today.

1.20

1.00

0.80

0.60

0.40

0.20
0
12/93

12/94

12/95

12/96

12/97

12/98

12/99

03/00

SOURCE: Federal Deposit Insurance Corporation, FDIC Quarterly Banking
Profile, 2000 quarter 1.

nearly 39 percent of deposits insured by
the SAIF.14 In practice, therefore, distinctions as to whose deposits each fund
guarantees are no longer meaningful.

■ Taxpayer Exposure
One compelling argument for merging
the BIF and the SAIF is that doing so
could reduce taxpayers’ exposure to loss.
A recent study shows that a single fund
created from the merger would have a
lower probability of insolvency than
either the BIF or the SAIF.15 The most
conservative estimate shows insolvency
probabilities of 7.0 percent for the BIF
and 10.3 percent for the SAIF, but only
6.5 percent for the merged fund. Similar
results could be achieved by simply
increasing each fund’s target ratio of
reserves to insured deposits; this would
mean increasing deposit insurance premiums for members of the BIF and the
SAIF until the new target is achieved.

■ Conclusion
As with any proposed reform, both the
costs and the benefits of merging the
BIF and the SAIF must be considered.
A fund merger would lower the FDIC’s
administrative costs by eliminating inefficiencies associated with operating two
funds, such as keeping duplicate sets of
books. It would also reduce the paperwork costs of deposit insurance for
banks and thrifts that have deposits
insured by both funds. However, these

administrative cost savings might not
suffice to offset potential benefits from
retaining separate industry funds.
A careful review of the arguments for
keeping separate deposit insurance
funds for banks and thrifts rather than
a single fund suggests that the benefits
of separation are at best elusive and
most likely nonexistent, given the
structure of today’s financial markets.
Finally, recent evidence shows that a
fund merger would lower taxpayer risk
associated with federal deposit guarantees. So merging the BIF and the SAIF
is a deposit insurance reform that
merits consideration.

■ Footnotes
1. Credit unions also have access to
federal guarantees through the National
Credit Union Share Insurance Fund.
However, unlike banks and savings
institutions, state-chartered credit
unions have the option of private
deposit insurance through American
Share Insurance.
2. The paper can be found at
<www.fdic.gov>.
3. For previous analyses of the merger
of the FDIC’s twin insurance funds, see
two articles by William P. Osterberg and
James B. Thomson, “SAIF Policy
Options,” Federal Reserve Bank of

5. At that time, the Federal Home
Loan Bank System consisted of 12
Banks (similar in charter and organization to the 12 Federal Reserve
Banks), the Federal Savings and
Loan Insurance Corporation (similar
to the FDIC), the Home Owners
Loan Corporation, the Federal
Home Loan Bank Board (analogous
to the Federal Reserve Board) to
oversee the System, and charter federal savings and loans (equivalent to
the Office of the Comptroller of the
Currency). The Federal Home Loan
Bank Board and its successor, the
Federal Housing Finance Board,
include all Federal Home Loan
Bank member institutions in their
definition of the Federal Home Loan
Bank System. For a contemporary
discussion of the System and its
mandate to promote housing, see
J.E. McDonough, “The Federal
Home Loan Bank System,” American Economic Review, vol. 24, no. 4
(December 1934), pp. 668–85.
6. One exception is governmentsponsored enterprises, where the
Federal Housing Finance Board is
charged with regulating and promoting Federal Home Loan Banks.
7. See Richard Scott Carnell, “A
Partial Antidote to Perverse Incentives: The FDIC Improvement Act
of 1991,” Annual Review of Banking
Law, vol. 12 (1993), pp. 317–21.
8. A recent study finds no evidence
that savings associations’ commitment to housing is any different than
that of commercial banks. See
Elizabeth Laderman and Wayne
Passmore, “Do Savings Associations Have a Special Commitment
to Housing?” Journal of Financial
Services Research, vol. 17, no. 1
(February 2000), pp. 41–64.

9. See George J. Benston, Robert A.
Eisenbeis, Paul M. Horvitz, Edward J.
Kane, and George G. Kaufman, eds., Perspectives on Safe and Sound Banking:
Past, Present, and Future, Cambridge,
Mass: MIT Press, 1986, chapter 11; and
James B. Thomson, “A Market-Based
Approach to Reforming Bank Regulation
and Federal Deposit Insurance,” in
Research in Financial Services: Private
and Public Policy, vol. 4, Greenwich,
Conn.: JAI Press Inc., 1992, pp. 93–109.
10. The bank regulatory agencies’ performance relative to the single federal
thrift regulatory agency during the 1980s
suggests that competition in laxity was
not a problem and that the competitive
environment may have improved
regulators’ performance.
11. This does not rule out the possibility
of charging entry and exit fees to discourage active switching and remove
depository institutions’ incentives to run
on their insurance fund.

Federal Reserve Bank of Cleveland
Research Department
P.O. Box 6387
Cleveland, OH 44101
Return Service Requested:
Please send corrected mailing label to
the above address.
Material may be reprinted if the source is
credited. Please send copies of reprinted
material to the editor.

12. These cross-guarantees are limited
because BIF and SAIF members do not
pledge their full capital and credit to
cover closed institutions’ losses in
excess of a fund’s insurance reserve.
When the Federal Savings and Loan
Insurance Corporation collapsed, its
losses of $125 billion or more became
the liability of the U.S. taxpayer.
13. See Federal Deposit Insurance
Corporation, FDIC Quarterly Banking
Profile, 2000 quarter 1.
14. Members of the smaller SAIF fund
hold more than 2 percent of all deposits
insured by the BIF.
15. See Robert Oshinsky, “Merging the
BIF and the SAIF: Would a Merger
Improve the Funds’ Viability?” Federal
Deposit Insurance Corporation, Division of Research and Statistics Staff
Paper, 1999.

James B. Thomson is a vice president and
economist at the Federal Reserve Bank of
Cleveland. The author wishes to thank (but
not to implicate) Alex Pollock, Wayne Passmore,
and Walker Todd for helpful comments.
The views stated here are those of the author
and not necessarily those of the Federal Reserve
Bank of Cleveland or of the Board of Governors
of the Federal Reserve System.
Economic Commentary is published by the
Research Department of the Federal Reserve
Bank of Cleveland. To receive copies or to be
placed on the mailing list, e-mail your request
to 4d.subscriptions@clev.frb.org or fax it to
216-579-3050. Economic Commentary is also
available at the Cleveland Fed’s site on the
World Wide Web: www.clev.frb.org/research,
where glossaries of terms are provided.
We invite comments, questions, and suggestions.
E-mail us at editor@clev.frb.org.

PRSRT STD
U.S. Postage Paid
Cleveland, OH
Permit No. 385