View original document

The full text on this page is automatically extracted from the file linked above and may contain errors and inconsistencies.

August 15, 2001

Federal Reserve Bank of Cleveland

Does Social Security Worsen Inequality?
by Jagadeesh Gokhale

S

ocial Security s long-term financial
health is weak at best. It is widely appreciated that hiking payroll taxes or cutting
benefits to restore solvency will postpone but not eliminate Social Security s
impending financial shortfall. Neither
will such fixes remedy the system s
structural shortcomings. The current
program treats some groups more favorably than others, and it distorts individuals economic decisions. In particular,
payroll taxes induce people to work
less, and the expectation of retirement
benefits reduces saving, lowering overall
capital formation and output.

Some have proposed establishing
individual Social Security accounts,
which would be privately owned and
controlled, as a solution. Such a reform
may ultimately reduce payroll tax rates
and eliminate the negative influence of
the current Social Security system on
capital formation and output growth.1
Opponents of private accounts counter
that they will increase the already high
wealth inequality among retirees by
exposing savings to greater market risks.
Private accounts may jeopardize retirement security for poorer households,
who typically are less able to manage
retirement portfolios.
Very few seem to appreciate that the
current Social Security arrangement
may, in some ways, be contributing to
rather than limiting wealth inequality
among retirees. Social Security may
induce lower-earning households to
save less for retirement than they would
otherwise, and this may be even more
important in increasing wealth inequality
among retirees than other factors such
as financial skills.

Another rarely discussed issue concerns
the long-term impact of Social Security
on intergenerational wealth mobility.
Greater wealth inequality provokes calls
for redistributive public policies to level
the playing field. However, attitudes are
also molded by perceptions regarding
wealth mobility. If those who are poor
today have (or their children have) a good
chance of becoming rich tomorrow, the
desire for public intervention would be
weaker. This Economic Commentary
suggests that Social Security itself may be
causing greater wealth inequality and
may lower intergenerational wealth
mobility. Establishing individual accounts
may result in greater wealth equality
and mobility.

■ Inequality in Bequeathable
Wealth Why is It Important?
Bequeathable wealth includes cash, bank
accounts, stocks, and life insurance policies assets that can be passed on to the
next generation. Alternatively, wealth
can exist in an annuitized form annual
income flows such as Social Security
benefits or pensions. Some annuities
allow for limited contingent benefits to
survivors. Most, however, cease upon
the owner s death.
Concern over the distribution of
bequeathable wealth at retirement
emerges because access to it expands the
available options in configuring one s
spending when retired. For example,
financing college education for children,
helping them with a down payment on a
home, entering a nursing home, or leaving a bequest, are feasible when a
person owns bequeathable wealth but are
foreclosed when all wealth is annuitized.
Further, in order to examine how Social
Security affects wealth mobility, it is

ISSN 0428-1276

Gaps between the rich and poor grow
once people hit retirement. Some
say privatizing Social Security will
increase wealth inequality among
retirees. This Commentary argues it
won t and suggests that the current
system may be reducing wealth
mobility from one generation to the
next. This Commentary is based on a
presentation given at the CATO Institute s conference on Social Security
Privatization, February 5—7, 2001.

most useful to focus on the distribution
of bequeathable wealth at retirement.
Most inheritances have been received by
this point, and the bequeathable-wealth
distribution at retirement fully reflects
their influence. Likewise, most bequests
to succeeding generations are made out
of retirees bequeathable wealth, and any
public policy influences on its distribution will be propagated forward to successive generations of retirees. Hence,
this distribution reflects the influence of
public policies on intergenerational
wealth mobility.
Many factors potentially affect the
distribution of bequeathable wealth at
retirement. Fertility and mortality are two
obvious ones: Parents with more children
spend more on consumption when working and cannot save as much for retirement as parents with fewer children.
Children whose parents die sooner after
retirement receive larger bequests and
may themselves retire richer as a result.
Other influential factors are the distribution of skills (and, hence, earnings), the
degree to which people sort by wealth or
earnings when marrying, and the extent

to which skills are inherited by children.
Policy-related factors such as progressive
income taxation and Social Security may
also play an important role. Each of these
factors affects the equilibrium level of
inequality in bequeathable wealth at
retirement that which would emerge
absent random shocks to pertinent demographic, economic, and policy factors.
The same factors also influence the
degree of intergenerational mobility
across the distribution of bequeathable
wealth. Mobility across a wealth distribution refers to the likelihood that someone
who is poor today turns up rich tomorrow.
Intergenerational mobility across the
distribution of bequeathable wealth refers
to the likelihood that children of poor (or
rich) retirees will themselves retire poor
(or rich). High intergenerational wealth
mobility means that the offspring of poor
retirees have a good chance of retiring
with more bequeathable wealth than their
parents. In contrast, low intergenerational
wealth mobility implies persistent poverty
among successive generations within the
same family dynasty. Obviously, policies
that allow the children of the poor a
greater chance to escape poverty are
more desirable than those that trap
descendents of poor parents in a state
of poverty: Greater intergenerational
mobility in bequeathable wealth is more
closely aligned to the ideal of equality
of opportunity.

■

Social Security and the
Distribution of Bequeathable
Wealth

In general, households with low education
and earnings save very little and, unlike
the rich, retire with almost no financial
wealth. This renders the distribution of
bequeathable wealth across all retirees
highly unequal. Calculations based on the
Federal Reserve s Survey of Consumer
Finances suggests that of the total
bequeathable wealth owned by retiring
married households, the richest 1 percent
own a third; the top 5 percent own onehalf; and the top 10 percent own nearly
two-thirds. Unfortunately, no reliable data
exist to inform us about the extent of
intergenerational wealth mobility. Anecdotal evidence suggests that children of
rich parents also own or accrue substantial
wealth. However, no one has documented
parent-child bequeathable assets at the
same stage of their respective life
cycles namely, at retirement.
A recent study based on a computer simulation designed to match the features of

the U.S. economy isolates the influence
of several factors in determining wealth
inequality at retirement. It suggests that
the U.S. Social Security system
increases inequality among retirees
because it substitutes public for private
saving to a disproportionately greater
degree for low-earning households than
for high-earning ones. Under the current
system, earnings are subject to payroll
taxes and count toward the determination of future benefits only up to a limit.
As a result, payroll taxes constitute a
much greater fraction of low earners
incomes than for high earners, reducing
low earners ability to save for retirement. Moreover, Social Security provides low earners with annual retirement
benefits almost equal to their postretirement consumption (consistent with
their lifetime earnings and pre-retirement
living standard), thus reducing their
incentive to accumulate significant
personal savings. This forced annuitization of a large fraction of low earners
lifetime resources leaves them with little
bequeathable wealth during retirement.
Hence, low earners leave few, if any,
bequests upon death.
In contrast, high earners pay payroll
taxes on a smaller portion of their earnings, and Social Security benefits constitute a minor fraction of their retirement
consumption. They can and do accumulate considerable personal savings before
retiring. Their stock of bequeathable
assets remains high, and their children
receive large inheritances in spite of
Social Security. Because of its asymmetrical impact on saving by low and high
earners, Social Security reduces or eliminates inheritances of children in poor
households but not those in rich ones.
By making the distribution of bequests
more unequal, Social Security may
increase the persistence of low bequeathable retirement wealth among poorer
households across successive generations. As mentioned earlier, no reliable
data exist to validate this for the U.S.
economy. However, the aforementioned
simulation can be used to estimate Social
Security s influence.2

■

Results

When the simulation is calibrated to
match the features of the U.S. economy including Social Security s payroll tax and benefit benchmarks the
degree of bequeathable-wealth inequality across the simulated retiree population closely matches that observed in

U.S. data.3,4 Furthermore, the simulated
distribution closely approximates the
concentration of wealth at the upper end
of the U.S. distribution.5 Grouping the
simulated distribution of bequeathable
wealth into quintiles shows that the
poorest 20 percent have less than
$99,000 in bequeathable wealth at
retirement, and the richest 20 percent
have more than $455,000. The richest
household has a bequeathable wealth
level of $118 million.6
The results on intergenerational mobility
across the distribution of bequeathable
wealth are quite striking. Table 1(a)
shows probabilities (in percent) that a
child will be in any particular bequeathable-wealth category at retirement,
given its parent s position in the
bequeathable-wealth distribution.7 For
example, children of parents who hold
less than $99,000 of bequeathable assets
at retirement have a 40 percent chance
of themselves retiring with less than
$99,000, but less than a 5 percent chance
of retiring with more than $455,000.
Children of parents among the richest
20 percent of households have close to a
50 percent chance of retiring with more
than $455,000. The likelihood that such
children will retire with less than
$99,000 is less than 4 percent much
lower than the 40 percent likelihood for
children of poor retirees. Thus, under
current Social Security, the simulation
exhibits sizable persistence in bequeathable wealth among successive generations within a household dynasty.

■

Wealth Inequality and
Mobility under an
Alternative Social Security
System

How would creating individual Social
Security accounts change things? To find
out, we carry out the simulation again,
this time eliminating Social Security
from the calibration. While most reform
proposals envision supplementing the
current system or only partially replacing
it with individual accounts, eliminating
Social Security in the simulation is
equivalent to establishing a self-financed
but mandatory individual accounts
system because the households that
populate the computer simulation save
in order to smooth consumption over
their lifetimes. The simulation thus
forces each household to accumulate
assets sufficient to maintain retirement
consumption at pre-retirement level.
Absent Social Security, the simulation

TABLE 1 INTERGENERATIONAL MOBILITY
IN BEQUEATHABLE WEALTH
(a) Under Social Security
Parent wealth
(thousands of dollars)

0—99

0—99
40.0%

Child wealth (thousands of dollars)
99—159 159—245 245—455 455—117,576
27.3%
17.8%
10.2%
4.7%

99—159

24.2

24.4

22.1

18.1

11.3

159—245

15.4

21.0

22.8

22.7

18.1

245—455

8.1

15.2

22.6

27.8

26.3

455—117,576

3.5

7.0

14.4

28.5

46.2

(b) Without Social Security
Parent wealth
0—99

0—99
16.3%

(thousands of dollars)

long-run equilibrium distribution of
bequeathable wealth at retirement for
the U.S. economy suggests that an
individual-accounts-type Social
Security system may slightly reduce
inequality. The case for such a Social
Security reform is strengthened further
by its likely long-run impact in increasing intergenerational wealth mobility
across the distribution of retirees
bequeathable wealth.

■ Footnotes
Child wealth (thousands of dollars)
99—159 159—245 245—455 455—117,576
20.3%
24.2%
28.4%
10.8%

99—159

9.1

14.6

22.3

33.5

20.5

159—245

6.4

11.3

18.4

33.0

31.0

245—455

3.8

7.2

13.4

30.0

45.6

455—117,576

0.9

2.1

5.2

18.3

73.5

NOTE: Numbers in each cell express the probability that a child will retire in the wealth grouping identified by the column heading, given that the child s parent retired in the wealth grouping identified by the row
heading. Bequeathable wealth groupings represent the quintiles of the distribution simulated using Social
Security as part of the calibration.

exhibits lower inequality in bequeathable wealth among retirees.8 This occurs
because low-earning households are
now motivated and able to accumulate
assets in bequeathable form in their
personal accounts.
In contrast to table 1(a), table 1(b)
shows intergenerational wealth transition probabilities when Social Security
is absent. The same dollar limits are
used as in table 1(a) to classify households among bequeathable wealth
categories. Now, children of parents
who are in the poorest category at
retirement have only a 16 percent
likelihood of ending up in the poorest
group themselves at retirement. In
contrast, the chance that they will retire
in the highest bequeathable-wealth
category rises to 10.8 percent more
than twice that of table 1(a). Of course,
children of richer parents enjoy a yet
higher probability of being wealthy
when they retire and a much lower
probability of ending up poor.
One ought to take these simulation results
with a pinch of skepticism. Replacing
Social Security with personal saving for
retirement may not improve intergenera-

tional wealth mobility if households
purchase annuities in the same amounts
upon retirement as Social Security provides today. However, given that retirement consumption is better configured
when one owns some bequeathable
assets, and given that Social Security
disproportionately and forcibly annuitizes a high fraction of poor households
wealth, these households are likely to
prefer a lower degree of wealth annuitization under an individual-accounts-type
Social Security system. An appropriate
conclusion might be that these results
indicate the direction rather than the
amount of improvement in wealth equality and mobility in the U.S. economy
that could be achieved by shifting to a
system with individual accounts.

■ Conclusion
Preserving a portion of total wealth in
bequeathable form during retirement
is desirable because it increases the
configuration of spending options
available for retirees. Inequality in
bequeathable wealth at retirement is
quite high but this may be exacerbated
rather than improved by the existence
of Social Security. Simulating the

1. Of course, benefits to current retirees
would have to be financed by transitional taxes. Several economists have
proposed alternative ways for doing
this. Two examples are Martin Feldstein
and Andrew Samwick, Allocating
Payroll Tax Revenue to Personal
Retirement Accounts to Maintain Social
Security Benefits and the Payroll Tax
Rate, NBER Working Paper no. 7767,
June 2000; and Laurence J. Kotlikoff,
Kent Smetters, and Jan Walliser, Simulating a Way out of America s Demographic Dilemma, NBER Working
Paper no. 8258, April 2001.
2. The model simulates an 88-period,
overlapping-generations economy, with
each generation consisting of 2,000
married households with demographic
and economic characteristics calibrated
to the U.S. economy. Several factors
that can influence wealth inequality are
studied in this model. For more details,
see Jagadeesh Gokhale, Laurence J.
Kotlikoff, James Sefton, and Martin
Weale, Simulating the Transmission
of Inequality via Bequests, Journal of
Public Economics, vol. 79, no. 1
(January 2001), pp. 93—128.
3. The simulated Gini coefficient is
0.674 for the distribution of bequeathable wealth at retirement. This is quite
close to the observed value of 0.73
calculated from the 1995 Survey of
Consumer Finances.
4. The estimates reported here should
be viewed with caution, as they are
based on a stylized life-cycle simulation model. First, life-cycle behavior
may not be an accurate representation
of individual behavior and second, for
tractability, the model abstracts from
a number of features of the real-world

U.S. economy for example, all households are assumed to be married, fertility among all households is positive,
and the observed negative correlation
of mortality with skills and wealth is
ignored.
5. In the simulated upper tail of the
distribution, the top 1 percent of households owned 33 percent of bequeathable wealth, the top 5 percent owned
49 percent, and the top 10 percent
owned 59 percent.

6. The figure for the richest household
seems rather low. However, the wealth
generated by the simulation is based on
the Federal Reserve s Survey of Consumer Finances. Admittedly, the survey
may not adequately sample from among
the Bill Gateses and Warren Buffets of
the U.S. economy.
7. These are the probabilities that
emerge when the simulation s bequeathable wealth distribution has stabilized.
8. The simulated Gini coefficient falls
from 0.674 to 0.6038. (Editor's note:
when this Commentary was first
published, the latter number was
incorrectly reported as 0.666).

Jagadeesh Gokhale is a senior economic
advisor at the Federal Reserve Bank of
Cleveland. He thanks David Altig,
Joe Haubrich, and Larry Kotlikoff for
helpful comments.
The views expressed here are those of the
author and not necessarily those of the Federal
Reserve Bank of Cleveland, the Board of
Governors of the Federal Reserve System, or
its staff.
Economic Commentary is published by the
Research Department of the Federal Reserve
Bank of Cleveland. To receive copies or to be
placed on the mailing list, e-mail your request
to 4d.subscriptions@clev.frb.org or fax it to
216-579-3050. Economic Commentary is also
available at the Cleveland Feds site on the
World Wide Web: www.clev.frb.org/research,
where glossaries of terms are provided.
We invite comments, questions, and suggestions. E-mail us at editor@clev.frb.org.

Federal Reserve Bank of Cleveland
Research Department
P.O. Box 6387
Cleveland, OH 44101
Return Service Requested:
Please send corrected mailing label to
the above address.
Material may be reprinted if the source is
credited. Please send copies of reprinted
material to the editor.

PRSRT STD
U.S. Postage Paid
Cleveland, OH
Permit No. 385