View original document

The full text on this page is automatically extracted from the file linked above and may contain errors and inconsistencies.

September 1, 2001

Federal Reserve Bank of Cleveland

Productivity Gains, How Permanent?
by Paul W. Bauer, Jeffrey L. Jensen, and Mark E. Schweitzer

R

ecent measures of economic output
show the economy has slowed dramatically, suggesting the current expansion
may be coming to an end. While many
are now awakening to the possibility
that even the “New Economy” may
experience negative output growth, it is
impossible to ignore productivity’s
exceptional performance over the last
five years. The accelerated growth we
have seen was largely unanticipated outside of ardent proponents of the “New
Economy.” Regardless of the fate of this
expansion, productivity growth is a key
factor in all long-term economic forecasts, and policymakers responsible for
planning various spending may now
need to reevaluate their assumptions
about long-run productivity growth.

Accurate forecasts of future productivity
growth are important because even small
changes have big effects over time. For
example, a half-percent increase in productivity growth may sound small, yet it
could add $1.2 trillion to the 10-year
forecast of the federal budget surplus.1
Social Security solvency estimates are
also dramatically altered by assumed
rates of productivity growth. That same
half-percent increase would cut the cost
of a 50-year fix to Social Security in
half.2 Indeed, any estimates of gross
domestic product more than a few quarters into the future critically depend on
what one assumes productivity will be.
By contrasting patterns of productivity
growth over postwar expansions, this
Economic Commentary shows the varied views policymakers may draw about
the likely future pattern of productivity
growth. In doing so, we update and
expand the analysis of a prior Economic
Commentary, “Productivity Gains During Business Cycles: What’s Normal,”
ISSN 0428-1276

written in July 1998. At that point in the
current expansion, productivity had only
just begun to show signs of unusually
large late-cycle growth. Using similar
statistical techniques, we show that this
acceleration has continued over the last
few years. We also examine some of the
factors that contribute to productivity
growth in order to understand better
what might have led to the current surge
and what is likely to occur in the future.

■

Postwar Productivity Growth

Two things obscure the pattern of productivity growth over the business cycle.
First, productivity data are inherently
noisy—more technically, the series’s variance is large relative to its level compared
to other major economic data series.
Second, the length of past expansions
varies greatly. To reveal the underlying
productivity trend over the business
cycle, a smoothing procedure must be
used. Figure 1 shows the results of this
procedure, which allows us to contrast
the pattern of the current expansion with
a statistical synopsis of the previous
seven postwar expansions.
In a typical expansion, productivity
growth starts quite rapidly, only to slow
for the remainder of the expansion. This
pattern has, of course, not been exactly
repeated in every expansion. A way to
envision the variability of the smoothed
estimates is to plot the 95 percent confidence band (see figure 1). The band
widens sharply toward the end of expansions because few expansions last that
long. Because only one other expansion
lasted longer than 37 quarters, we stop
plotting the band at that point. There is
no question that this expansion has been
unusually long-lived.

This Economic Commentary confirms unusually robust productivity
growth of the last few years and
explores reasonable assumptions
about the likely future pattern of
productivity growth. These assumptions can generate substantially
different productivity growth paths.
Government forecasts, which guide
the major tax and benefit programs,
have been increased in recent years
yet remain cautious.

Contrasting the current expansion with
the smoothed statistical synopsis of previous expansions reveals the extraordinary
nature of the last few years. Until the
twenty-third quarter, this expansion
appears to have been fairly typical, but in
1996, productivity growth surged at an
unexpectedly rapid rate. Consequently,
the attention devoted to productivity
growth over the last few years has been
well justified.
What remains unknown is whether this
surge reflects conditions unique to this
expansion or more permanent factors.
In other words, how likely are future
expansions to be like this one? Yet this
information is key for predicting longrun outcomes accurately. Unfortunately,
no amount of past data can completely
relieve the policymaker from this fundamental uncertainty. In light of this,
we try to constrain the uncertainty by
showing how different the predictions
for productivity growth over the business cycle can be, depending on how
they’re calculated.

■ Looking to the Future
Predictions for the path of productivity
growth depend on which parts of our history we assume are more relevant or
likely to repeat. We consider three alternative assumptions we could reasonably
make when forecasting future productivity growth. Conservative policymakers
(option 1) might assume that the current
expansion is an anomaly and base their
forecasts on postwar data through 1991.
Note that this is the same as the typical
expansion in figure 1, as neither uses
information from the current expansion.
Averaged over the full business cycle
(including the recession quarters), the
conservative option predicts annual labor
productivity growth of 1.8 percent. Even
this option is somewhat more optimistic
than prevailing views prior to this expansion, because most forecasts would have
included a productivity slowdown term
of about –0.6 percentage point, to
account for the marked slowing in productivity growth in post-1973 expansions. The productivity slowdown no
longer appears to be a permanent feature
of the U.S. economy, and including an ad
hoc adjustment only makes the current
expansion more difficult to reconcile
with the past data.

FIGURE 1 CURRENT AND TYPICAL EXPANSIONS

SOURCE: Authors’ calculations.

FIGURE 2 THREE SCENARIOS

Another alternative would be for policymakers to employ all the available productivity data, and thus treat the current
expansion as simply one of nine available business cycles (option 2, neutral).
Under this option, labor productivity
growth is expected to average 2.5 percent over the business cycle, in part
because longer periods of productivity
growth are expected.
Lastly, policymakers might adopt a view,
in the spirit of New Economy proponents, that information from the 1973–91
slowdown should be fully discounted,
because, some would argue, the economy is now on a permanently faster
growth path. Constructing a forecast
without this period yields our third
alternative (option 3, aggressive). This
assumption again raises the productivity
growth forecasts in the later quarters.
Nonetheless, this much more optimistic
option only increases estimated long-run
productivity growth over the business
cycle to 2.8 percent, because longer
cycles are already included and the estimates for early quarters are not substantially altered.
It is clear that the way we treat the data
from the 1973–91 productivity slow-

SOURCE: Authors’ calculations.

down and the current expansion makes a
significant difference to the forecasts in
the three options. Of course, more
aggressive forecasts are possible by further emphasizing the last expansion, but
historical evidence is still a reasonable
constraint for something as hard to predict as productivity growth.

■ Sources of Labor
Productivity Growth
Which of these three assumptions is
most reasonable? Understanding the

sources of productivity growth might
suggest an answer.
Overall labor productivity growth is the
sum of the gains from capital deepening
(an increase in the capital-to-labor ratio),
from changes in input quality (the result
of better trained or more experienced
workers), and from multifactor productivity (an estimate of technological
change often referred to as the Solow
residual).3 The Bureau of Labor Statistics calculates the most widely reported
measure of multifactor productivity

TABLE 1 PRIVATE NONFARM BUSINESS PRODUCTIVITY
1948
–99

1948
–73

1973
–79

1979
–90

1990
–95

1995
–99

Labor productivity

2.2

2.9

1.2

1.4

1.6

2.4

Contribution of capital
deepening

0.8

0.8

0.7

0.8

0.5

1.0

Contribution of labor
quality

0.2

0.2

0.0

0.3

0.4

0.3

Multifactor productivity

1.2

1.9

0.4

0.3

0.6

1.1

SOURCE: U.S. Department of Labor, Bureau of Labor Statistics, Multifactor Productivity Trends, 1999.

TABLE 2 ESTIMATES OF LONG-RUN PRODUCTIVITY GROWTH
Organization

1991

1999

2000

2001

Congressional Budget Office

1.3

1.7

2.3

2.7

Council of Economic Advisors

1.8

1.3

2.0

2.3

N/A

1.9

2.2

2.5

1.0

1.0

1.0

1.0

OECD
Social Security Administration
Conservative

1.8

Neutral

2.5

Aggressive

2.8

SOURCES: Congressional Budget Office, The Budget and Economic Outlook, various issues; Council of
Economic Advisors, Economic Report of the President, various issues; Organisation for Economic Co-operation and Development, OECD Economic Outlook, various issues; Social Security Administration, OASDI
Trustees Report, various issues; and authors’ calculations.

(MFP). MFP is less widely known and
reported than labor productivity because
it is only available annually and, until
recently, has been released only biennially. The reason for the delay and the
relative infrequency of reporting is that
MFP requires more data to calculate
than labor productivity, which requires
only estimates of output and labor input,
both of which are available quarterly. In
addition to output and labor, MFP also
requires an estimate of capital, which is
available only annually.
Table 1 presents the latest available figures for the decomposition of labor productivity into its various components.
From the table, it is clear that the main
cause of the 1973–91 slowdown was a
sharp decline in MFP. This is unfortunate because, being the residual, it is the
least predictable component. A much
smaller share of the slowdown came
from stagnant growth in labor quality, as
baby boomers first entered the job market and a surge of women returning to
work after caring for children increased
female labor force participation.

The contribution of capital deepening
was relatively stable over these periods.
In the long run, it seems likely that capital deepening will continue to contribute around 0.8 percentage point to
overall productivity. Also, with no
bulge in the demographic distribution
and a strong emphasis on education and
job training, the contribution of labor
quality should continue at about 0.3
percentage point. The big question is
what will happen with MFP, but unfortunately, these numbers cannot tell us.
Recent papers have sought to address
this deficiency by reconsidering the
strength of capital deepening in the
economy, particularly in information
and communication technologies.4 This
research has generally focused on identifying assumptions used to calculate
the national income and product
accounts that may be inappropriate for
computers and related technologies.
Correcting these deficiencies in the
national accounts lowers the MFP
estimates by boosting the share of
productivity explained by capital

deepening. This research has greatly
clarified the importance of investments in
information and communications technologies in the latest expansion. The research
has lowered MFP growth in later years to
a more typical rate, attributing about half
of the extra MFP growth over the last
five years to capital deepening. Even so,
this still leaves policymakers to ponder
not only whether this information-andcommunications-technology-led capital
deepening is sustainable but also whether
the other half of the unaccounted-for extra
gains in MFP growth will persist as well.
These uncertainties keep this approach
from dramatically narrowing the range of
forecasts proposed earlier.

■ Comparison with Other
Forecasts
We now compare our three options for
estimating future labor productivity growth
with some other prominent forecasts
(see table 2). Note that most of the organizations considered have boosted their
forecasts for productivity growth since the
early 1990s. The exception is the Social
Security Administration, which has held to
its 1.0 percent long-run forecast throughout
this period. At 2.7 percent, the Congressional Budget Office is the most optimistic
at about the same rate as our aggressive
forecast. The Council of Economic Advisors’ forecast is a little more cautious,
projecting only 2.3 percent growth, in line
with our neutral option. The Organisation
for Economic Co-operation and Development is the second most optimistic at
2.5 percent, the same as our neutral option.
How should policymakers proceed? We
have shown that most of the recent increase
in labor productivity comes from MFP
growth, which cannot be traced to a specific, identifiable cause. The Social Security Administration’s 1.0 percent estimate
appears to be too low. It is not only below
all three of our options, but also capital
deepening and labor quality alone should
be able to deliver at least this rate of
growth. How much higher an estimate
one chooses depends on how permanent
the recent MFP growth gains are assumed
to be. Of course, policymakers will have
to periodically revise their forecasts as
new information becomes available.

■ Conclusion
Despite the recent revision of previous estimates, the current expansion clearly has
generated abnormally large late-cycle gains
in labor productivity, which may indicate a
shift to a higher trend rate of productivity
growth. Alternatively, the recent surge could

be a one-time event. In making forecasts
of future productivity growth, it is prudent to be cautious. Few forecasted the
1973 slowdown, and few predicted productivity’s current resurgence. In any
forecast, one would be well advised to
consider the net cost of forecast error. For
example, when planning for your retirement, assuming a high rate of return for
your investments enables you to save less
and spend more now, but the cost comes
in the future when you may not have the
resources that you planned to have. Of
course, there is also a cost to assuming
too low a rate. You end up saving too
much, needlessly cutting your consumption now.

■ Footnotes
1. See David Wessel, “The Magic
Elixir,” Wall Street Journal, February 15,
2001.
2. See David Wessel, footnote 1.

3. For a more complete discussion of
multifactor productivity growth and this
decomposition, see Paul W. Bauer, “
Are We in a Productivity Boom? Evidence from Multifactor Productivity
Growth,” Federal Reserve Bank of
Cleveland, Economic Commentary,
October 15, 1999.
4. Key research in this area includes
Dale W. Jorgenson, “Information
Technology and the U.S. Economy,”
American Economic Review, vol. 91,
no. 1 (March 2001), pp. 1–32; Robert J.
Gordon, “Does the ‘New Economy’
Measure up to the Great Inventions of
the Past?” Journal of Economic
Perspectives, vol. 14, no. 4 (Fall 2000),
pp. 49–74; and Kevin J. Stiroh,
“Investing in Information Technology:
Productivity Payoffs for U.S. Industries,” Federal Reserve Bank of New
York, Current Issues in Economics
and Finance, vol. 7, no 6 (June 2001).

Paul Bauer is an economic advisor at the
Federal Reserve Bank of Cleveland.
Jeffrey Jensen is a former research assistant
at the Bank, and Mark Schweitzer is an
economist at the Bank.
The views expressed here are those of the
authors and not necessarily those of the Federal Reserve Bank of Cleveland, the Board of
Governors of the Federal Reserve System, or
its staff.
Economic Commentary is published by the
Research Department of the Federal Reserve
Bank of Cleveland. To receive copies or to be
placed on the mailing list, e-mail your request
to 4d.subscriptions@clev.frb.org or fax it to
216-579-3050. Economic Commentary is also
available at the Cleveland Fed’s site on the
World Wide Web: www.clev.frb.org/research,
where glossaries of terms are provided.
We invite comments, questions, and suggestions. E-mail us at editor@clev.frb.org.

.

Federal Reserve Bank of Cleveland
Research Department
P.O. Box 6387
Cleveland, OH 44101
Return Service Requested:
Please send corrected mailing label to
the above address.
Material may be reprinted if the source is
credited. Please send copies of reprinted
material to the editor.

PRSRT STD
U.S. Postage Paid
Cleveland, OH
Permit No. 385