View original document

The full text on this page is automatically extracted from the file linked above and may contain errors and inconsistencies.

January 1, 1994

eOONOMIC
GOMM6NTCIRY
Federal Reserve Bank of Cleveland

Monetary Policy and Inflation:
1993 in Perspective
by Gregory A. Bauer and John B. Carlson

An 1993, monetary policy was most
unusual because of what did not happen:
The federal funds rate objective remained
unchanged. The fed funds rate is the interest rate banks pay when they borrow
deposits at the Federal Reserve from
other banks, usually overnight. It is
closely watched in financial markets because its level can be immediately and
purposefully affected by open market
operations of the Federal Reserve's New
York Trading Desk. Market analysts understand that "permanent" changes in this
rate generally occur only after deliberative
action by the Federal Open Market Committee (FOMC), the policymaking arm of
the Federal Reserve System.
Federal Reserve policy actions can lead
to substantial changes in the level of the
fed funds rate. For example, the strong
steps initiated in late 1979 to slow inflation were associated with a rise in the
fed funds rate from around 11 percent
to about 17 percent in April 1980, and
ultimately to around 20 percent in early
1981 (see figure 1). Although the rate
trended downward over the balance of
the 1980s, it also rose and fell by as
much as 2 percentage points within a
given year. From fall 1992 until the
close of 1993, however, the fed funds
rate traded on a daily average basis
within one-eighth percentage point of
3 percent for the most part.
Some economists worry that this pattern
of stability might make it more difficult
to increase the fed funds rate in the face
of a need to head off inflationary pressures. Such concerns are based on the

ISSN 0428-1276

experience of the mid- to late 1970s,
when monetary policy appeared to react too little, too late and inflation accelerated to new highs. Compounding
this sentiment is the recent deemphasis
on monetary targeting. To some analysts, the monetary targeting procedure
has traditionally served not only to
identify the FOMC's intentions regarding the thrust of policy, but also to provide discipline useful for anchoring the
price level.
Although the fed funds rate remained
in a trading range around 3 percent
from early September 1992 through the
end of last year, the period was characterized by substantial swings in the outlook for economic activity and inflation. This Economic Commentary
reviews these events in the context of the
longer-term objective of continuing progress toward price stability. We discuss
how the Fed's credible commitment to
pursuing this goal may have contributed
to the net decline in long-term interest
rates, even without any hard evidence of
deliberative action in the face of financialmarket inflation concerns.
• Humphrey-Hawkins:
February 19,1993
The Full Employment and Balanced
Growth Act of 1978—also known as
the Humphrey-Hawkins Act—requires
that the Federal Reserve's Board of
Governors transmit to Congress semiannually (once before February 20 and
once before July 20) both an analysis
of current economic conditions and its
policy objectives for the calendar year.

Although the Federal Reserve did not
change its objective for the federal
funds rate over the course of the past
year, long-term interest rates declined from their 1992 levels. The
events of 1993 also point to confidence in the financial markets that
the central bank will respond appropriately to any significant acceleration in the price level. This article
provides an overview of these issues
in the context of the Federal Reserve's
continued emphasis on price stability,
which may have contributed to the
outcome for interest rates in 1993.

The first report must specify growth
ranges for the monetary and credit aggregates and also presents the range
and the central tendency of FOMC
member projections for inflation and
output in the current year.
In the July report, the FOMC reassesses
its objectives and projections, as well
as specifies preliminary targets for the
next calendar year. Although nothing in
the act requires the Board to fulfill its
plans for money and credit, it is required to explain the conditions under
which such plans could not or should
not be achieved. The Board is also obligated to supply an explanation for
changes in the targets.

FIGURE 1

FEDERAL FUNDS RATE

Percent
25

1974

1976

1978

1980

1982

1984

1986

1988

1990

1992

1994

SOURCE: Board of Governors of ihe Federal Reserve Syslem.

FIGURE 2

M2 VELOCITY AND OPPORTUNITY COST 2

In the February 1993 report to Congress, the Fed set its ranges for M2 and
M3 growth at 2 to 6 percent and '/i to
4'/> percent, respectively. Both were
one-half percentage point lower than
the corresponding ranges in the prei
vious year. ~
The 1993 report emphasized that the reduction of the monetary ranges was to
be viewed neither as a change in the
stance of policy nor as a hindrance to
continued economic expansion. Rather,
Chairman Alan Greenspan described
the change as wholly technical in nature. The relatively dependable relationship between M2 growth, interest rates,
and economic activity had come into
question in the past few years as low
bank interest rates had caused credit
flows to be rechanneled away from depositories to alternative sources.
This breakdown is illustrated in figure
2, which shows the divergence between
M2 velocity—the ratio of M2 to nominal
GDP—and its opportunity cost—the
difference between market interest rates
and the average interest rate paid on
M2 balances. Prior to 1990, M2 velocity moved directly with changes in opportunity cost; since then, however, the
two series have generally moved apart.
Thus, despite the weakness in M2, the
FOMC projected last winter that the
economy would grow at a healthy pace
in 1993. The central tendency for GDP

1.55
1959

1964

1969

1974

1979

1984

1989

a. M2 velocity is the ratio of GDP to M2. M2 opportunity cost is defined as the spread between the market rate
and the average interest paid on M2 balances. The market rate is defined here as the Ihree-monlh Treasury bill rate.
SOURCE: Board of Governors of the Federal Reserve System.

was expected to be in the range of 3 to
3v4 percent, building on the momentum generated in the fourth quarter of
1992. Coupled with a moderate acceleration in output growth, the FOMC's
projections for inflation were consistent with a continued downward trend.
The central tendency for the annual
change in the Consumer Price Index
(CPI) ranged between 2'/2 and 2V4 percent for 1993, significantly lower than
the 3.1 percent rate in 1992. The report
emphasized that the FOMC still
viewed the containment of inflation as
an important element in its long-run
strategy for stable economic growth.

• Spring Jitters
By early in the second quarter, however, data on business activity and prices
suggested a less sanguine outlook. The
revised estimate of real GDP rose less
than 1 percent in the first three months
of 1993. In addition, weaker-thanexpected employment growth in March
raised concerns about the durability of
the expansion. At the same time, inflation was accelerating: The CPI increased
at an annual rate of more than 5 percent
in April, elevating the year-to-date CPI
inflation rate to around 4 74 percent (see
figure 3). Even the core measure of inflation, which is designed to minimize
transitory noise, seemed to confirm an

1994

CPI INFLATION, 1991-933

FIGURE 3
12-month percent change

6
\
5

\

4-

\
\

3

^ —

\

• v

/

> • • • • ! •

2—
1n

IQ

, | . . 1 • • 1 • . 1 . , 1 • , 1 •
IIIQ
IVQ
IIQ
IIIQ
IIQ
IQ
1991
1992

•

1

IVQ

i

• 1 .
IQ

i

|

IIQ

. . I . . 1 . .
IIIQ
IVQ
1993

a. Dotted lines represent 1993 central tendency projection.
SOURCE: U.S. Department of Labor, Bureau of Labor Statistics.

The FOMC's posture, which market
commentators later described as preparation for a "preemptive strike against
inflation/' seemed to be sufficient to
prevent inflationary expectations from
gaining any upward momentum. The
10-year bond rate resumed its downward trajectory in June after reports of
the tightening bias surfaced in The Wall
Street Journal and The New York Times.
News on inflation began to improve, although little progress was evident in
the relatively stubborn expectations revealed by survey data.

•

Taking Stock at Midyear

By the time the July report was issued,
the accumulation of new information
had substantially altered the 1993 out-

FIGURE 4

10-YEAR U.S. TREASURY RATE, CONSTANT MATURITY

Percent
8.0

look for inflation and the economy.
The Committee members modified
their projections accordingly; the central tendency of real GDP growth for
the year was 2'/t to 2% percent, almost
a full percentage point lower.
The range of projections for the CPI,
on the other hand, was revised upward,
with a central tendency of 3 to 3 '/4 percent for the year, up one-half percentage
point from the February report. The overall news on inflation was termed "disappointing," although the May and June
numbers had helped to ease fears some-

IQ

IIQ

IIIQ

IVQ

IQ

1992

IIQ

IIIQ
1993

Although the continued deceleration in
M2 — which had been evident since
1988 — would have indicated a further
decline in the inflation trend based on historic relationships, markets appeared to
discount the significance of sluggish M2
growth. Indeed, some observers were
more worried about the rapid growth of
the narrower monetary aggregates. M l
and the monetary base were increasing at
double-digit rates—a signal more consistent with rising inflation.

role of expectations in the battle against
inflation.

SOURCE: Board of Governors of the Federal Reserve System.

impending rise in the price level with a
sharp uptick in April.

what. The July testimony stressed the

cline of long-term interest rates (see figure 4). On a monthly average basis, the
10-year bond leveled in April and rose
in May (when the April inflation number was released) despite the signs of
economic weakness and M2 growth
well below its target range (see figure
5). Short-term rates also started to
climb during the beginning of the second quarter (see figure 6).

Higher inflation expectations can compound an upward inflation trend, much
like a self-fulfilling prophecy, when
people negotiate future prices and
wages based on their predictions of a
steeper price level. In contrast, price
stability is achieved when the changes
in the general price level are small
enough to have an insignificant effect
on economic and financial planning."
Faced with below-target growth in the

In light of these inflation concerns, the

aggregates, the Federal Reserve low-

FOMC adopted a tightening bias in the

ered the 1993 ranges at midyear, again

form of an asymmetric directive at its

as a wholly technical move and not as

May 18 meeting. Such a directive al-

an indication of a policy change. The

lows the Chairman certain flexibilities

M2 growth range was reduced a full

Inflation concerns appeared to be cor-

during the period between Committee

percentage point to 1 to 5 percent,

roborated by a suspension in the de-

meetings to move in the direction of a

while the M3 range was lowered by

tightening stance.

one-half percent. The FOMC also

chose a tentative 1994 range for M2 of
1 to 5 percent.
Given the uncertainties surrounding inflation expectations, the Committee reassessed the importance of below target growth, stating that "at least for
the time being, M2 has been downgraded as a reliable indicator of financial conditions in the economy, and no
single variable has yet been identified
to take its place." 4 The long-run relationship between M2 and prices had
clearly broken down and would be set
aside unless a more consistent pattern
reemerged. The markets, apparently understanding the M2 difficulties, were
unmoved by the diminished role for the
aggregate.

FIGURE 5 THE M2 AGGREGATE"
Billions of dollars
3,750

3,650

3,550 -

3,450 -

,

3,350
IVQ

, I . . I .

IIQ

IIIQ

, .
IIQ

IIIQ

IVQ

1993

a. Doited lines represent target ranges.
SOURCE: Board of Governors of the Federal Reserve System.

FIGURE 6 THREE-MONTH U.S. TREASURY BILL RATE

IIQ

IIIQ

IVQ

IQ

IIQ

IIIQ
1993

1992

Although some may argue that the inflation outcome was a transitory response to weak oil prices in the second
half, the core inflation measure reported
in a 1993 Federal Reserve Bank of
Cleveland study was also 2.7 percent/

IQ

1992

In regard to more immediate policy
matters, the Committee continued its
vigilance over inflation. Not wishing to
give in to the inflationary psychology
that could be developing, the Fed maintained its tightening bias despite criticisms from some quarters that if the
bias materialized into an action, it could
eventually hinder the perceived fragile
state of the economy. Nevertheless, the
asymmetric directive remained in place
until the August meeting of the FOMC.
The stage had been set to allow for a
turnaround in confidence of both
households and businesses without an
accompanying surge in inflation.
• The View in Retrospect
In retrospect, the relatively gloomy outlook for inflation and economic activity at midyear seems to have been overstated. Indeed, the year apparently
turned out to be more like original expectations had conceived. The inflation
threat receded, as CPI inflation came in
at 2.7 percent for the year, within the
central tendency ranges reported in
February. Long-term interest rates resumed a downward trajectory as news
on inflation improved (see figure 4).

i I

IVQ

SOURCE: Board of Governors of the Federal Reserve System.

Figure 7 reveals that this core measure
was essentially unaffected by the sustained oil price weakness in 1986 and
suggests that the recent slowdown in inflation is not transitory.
Real GDP, while growing only around
1 '/2 percent in the first half of 1993, accelerated sharply over the course of the
year. Preliminary data suggest that
second-half GDP growth will come in
at a rate at least double that of the first
half. Moreover, output growth is subject to further potentially substantial revisions, so that the final number could
be closer to the original projection than
the level at midyear.

With evidence of a stronger economy,
interest rates tended to firm late in the
year. Nevertheless, long-term rates remained below their midyear levels. By
the end of December, the M2 aggregate
had increased slightly above 1 '/S percent, within target ranges set in July,
but below its original range.
• Trend Inflation
Market reaction to the perceived inflation threat in early 1993 may now
seem to have been exaggerated. After
all. one would need to go back to 1966
to find a calendar year in which inflation was as low as it was in 1993 (see

IVQ

IQ
1994

FIGURE 7
Percent, 12-month moving average
16

Assessing the direction of trend inflation is difficult, particularly since the
breakdown in M2 velocity in 1990. Before then, it was widely held that over
sufficiently long periods, trend inflation could be reduced by following a
policy that lowered the trend growth of
M2. By achieving money growth within the decelerated ranges, the FOMC
could demonstrate a commitment to
further reducing inflation.

INFLATION MEASURES, 1968-93

CPI

I
1968

1973

. . . .

1983

1978

I
1988

1993

a. As computed by the Federal Reserve Bank of Cleveland.
SOURCES: U.S. Department of Labor, Bureau of Labor Statistics; and the Federal Reserve Bank of Cleveland.

FIGURE 8

LONG-TERM INTEREST RATES AND INFLATION

Percent
16

CPI inflation
over previous
two years
.

1960

1965

1970

1975

1980

1985

. I .

1990

SOURCES: Board of Governors of the Federal Reserve System: and U.S. Department of Labor, Bureau of
Labor Statistics.

figure 8). Moreover, since the last business cycle trough, CPI inflation has
averaged just under 3 percent, more
than half a percentage point lower than
in the first three years of the previous
cyclical upturn.
Thus, one perhaps should not be surprised that bond rates continued to fall
in 1993, reaching levels not seen in 20
years. The long-term decline in inflation has been central to the continuing
drop in bond rates because the inflation
experience since 1982 demonstrates a
credible commitment to preventing a
repeat of the 1970s. But why, then,
aren't long-term interest rates closer to
1966 levels?

Although any number of factors may
account for the relatively higher rates—
including the magnitude of the federal
deficit and the worldwide return on
capital, among other things — one possible explanation is that bond holders
do not believe that inflation will persist
at the recent lower levels. Survey data
reveal that price-level expectations
have remained above recent rates of actual inflation. Indeed, according to the
University of Michigan survey, households expect 1994 inflation to be closer
to 4 percent.

Although monetary policy reports to
Congress typically express the Committee's intent to continue its progress toward price stability, explicit targets are
not set. Some policymakers have noted
that this gives the public no clear standard by which to gauge the success of
monetary policy.7 In response, many
analysts have advocated an explicit
nominal anchor by which the FOMC's
longer-term intentions could be identified. In the absence of such an objective, they contend, markets lack a clear
basis on which to make judgments concerning the trend in inflation.
• Lessons from 1993
Despite a year in which the Federal Reserve took no deliberative action to affect the federal funds rate, long-term interest rates ended up declining from
1992 levels. Notwithstanding the diminished role of monetary targeting, financial markets appear to exhibit a degree of confidence that the Fed will not
repeat the mistakes of the 1970s. The
mere hint of a policy tightening bias
last May appeared sufficient to reassure
market participants of a monetary policy response in the event of a persistent
inflation flare-up. Although the FOMC
may have established credibility that it
will prevent a significant acceleration
in the price level, long-term interest
rates do not provide a clear signal that
markets expect inflation to continue to
recede to levels experienced in the late
1950s and early 1960s.
Advocates of price-level targeting argue that without a commitment to an
explicit multiyear price-level objective,

markets lack a concrete basis for expecting further progress toward price
stability. They believe that commitment
to a target path for the price level could
limit the range of expectations about future inflation, as well as ensure that the
outcome will be consistent with those
expectations.

As in decades past, peo-

ple might then become more inclined
to view increases in inflation as temporary. Moreover, they might have a basis
for expecting long-term interest rates
to fall within a range of 2'/2 to 5 percent, characteristic of the earlier period.

• Footnotes
1. The central tendency is essentially a modal range that excludes outliers of the Committee members' forecasts.
2. Over the past seven calendar years, the
M2 range has been lowered by one-half percentage point five times, while it has been
left unchanged in the other two years.

4. See 1993 Monetary Policy Objectives:
Summary Report of the Federal Resen'e
Board, July 20, 1993, p. 8.
5. See Michael F. Bryan and Stephen G.
Cecchetti, "Measuring Core Inflation," Federal Reserve Bank of Cleveland, Working Paper 9304, June 1993. The commonly reported core measure of inflation is the CPI
less food and energy components, which rose
3.2 percent in 1993.
6. Inflation expectations as measured by the
University of Michigan's Survey of Consumers became more favorable, continuing to
ease through the end of the year after peaking
in August at nearly 5 percent. For the first
time in 1993, expected inflation fell below 4
percent in November, to 3.6 percent for the
next 12 months. December expectations
edged upward slightly to 3.8 percent.

Gregory A. Bauer is a research assistant
and John B. Carlson is an economist at the
Federal Reserve Bank of Cleveland. The
authors would like to thank William Gavin
and E.J. Stevens for helpful comments.
The views stated herein are those of the
authors and not necessarily those of the Federal Reserve Bank of Cleveland or of the
Board of Governors of the Federal Reserve
System.

7. See Jerry L. Jordan, "Credibility Begins
with a Clear Commitment to Price Stability,"
Federal Reserve Bank of Cleveland, Economic Commentary, October 1, 1993.
8. Ibid.

3. See 1993 Monetary Policy Objectives:
Summary Report of the Federal Resen'e
Board, February 19, 1993, p. 17.

Federal Reserve Bank of Cleveland
Research Department
P.O. Box 6387
Cleveland, OH 44101

Address Correction Requested:
Please send corrected mailing label to
the above address.
Material may be reprinted provided that
the source is credited. Please send copies
of reprinted materials to the editor.

BULK RATE
U.S. Postage Paid
Cleveland, OH
Permit No. 385