View original document

The full text on this page is automatically extracted from the file linked above and may contain errors and inconsistencies.

May 1, 2001

Federal Reserve Bank of Cleveland

Monetary Policy with Humility
by Sandra Pianalto

“On eight Tuesdays each year, Federal
Reserve Chairman Greenspan convenes a
small committee to set the short-term
interest rate ... [T]he committee’s actions
determine the economic well-being of
every American. The availability of
money for business or consumer loans,
mortgages, job creation and overall
national economic growth all flows from
those decisions.”
—Bob Woodward, in his best-seller,
Maestro

T

his is an intoxicating description of
the Federal Reserve when the economy
is making record economic gains, but it
hangs like a yoke around our necks
when the economic clouds darken. And
indeed, the economic skies have clouded
over since last October.
How should the central bank conduct
monetary policy when faced with what
potentially is a difficult year ahead? This
Economic Commentary argues that we
should resist the temptation to fine-tune
economic performance and keep our
focus on that which we know to be in the
best interest of our longer-run prosperity.
In other words, smoothing out the business cycle, as it is conventionally conceived and measured, is not an appropriate goal of monetary policy. Monetary
policy has been successful in recent
years because the Federal Reserve has
contained inflation and inflation expectations as it has responded to variations
in real economic activity. Instead of trying to manage the business cycle, we
have increasingly focused on managing

ISSN 0428-1276

the inflationary psychology of households and businesses. With inflation
expectations under control, we have created an environment in which this
exceptional expansion in U.S. prosperity
has taken root.

■ A Refresher on Activist
Economic Policy
When monetary policy is used as a
stabilization tool—sometimes called the
“activist” approach to economic policy—
the presumption is that the way markets
allocate our national resources is fundamentally flawed. Adam Smith’s invisible
hand is a bit arthritic. Prices don’t, in general, respond very quickly to changing
market conditions, and entrepreneurs
instead make their adjustments through
the workforce—hiring new employees
during periods of strong demand, laying
off employees when demand is waning.
And so what we see in the ups and downs
of business activity is the market oscillating around its desired level, sometimes a
little too strong, sometimes a little too
weak, but rarely at a level that maximizes
the economy’s long-run potential.
In the “activist” world view, the object
of a sensible economic policy is one that
helps the market along, propping up its
sags during downturns and knocking the
edges off the seemingly excessive good
times. This is the macroeconomics of my
youth, the economics of the Keynesian
revolution. We were instructed that the
focal point of economic policy was the
management of the short-run swings in
the “business cycle.” This idea is best
summarized by John Maynard Keynes’
classic quote: “Economists set themselves too easy, too useless a task if in
the tempestuous seasons they can only

When the economy slows, monetary
policymakers face pressure to deviate
from their longer-term goals to
address short-term problems. This
Commentary argues that the Fed
must stay focused on the long term—
maintaining the stable purchasing
power of the dollar. The Commentary
is adapted from a speech delivered by
Sandra Pianalto, first vice president
of the Federal Reserve Bank of Cleveland, to the Association for Corporate
Growth in March 2001.

tell us that when the storm is long past
the ocean will be flat.… In the long-run,
we are all dead.”
Much of the policy advice offered by
economists today takes this approach.
They track the economic indicators that
are supposed to help us decide when to
push on the business cycle gas pedal, and
when to brake. The activist philosophy
would have economic policy strike a balance between growth on the one hand and
inflation on the other. The 1960s and
1970s, when policymakers tried to exploit
the presumed trade-off between growth
and inflation, taught us that this approach
can go terribly awry. Initially, economic
policy undershot, then soon overshot the
estimates of our economy’s potential, and
all the while we watched our inflation rate
ratchet higher until in the end, we were
left with an economy that suffered from
both high inflation and high unemployment. Dismal science indeed!

The ultimate cost of pursuing short-run
economic gains, it turns out, was not
merely a little bit more inflation, but a
falloff in long-term national prosperity.
It now appears that the initial decline in
output that set the policymakers off on
their corrective course represented the
economy’s natural response to changing
economic events. The economy was
doing what economies try to do, and that
is allocate the nation’s resources in a
manner determined by the marketplace.
Failing to appreciate the dynamic nature
of markets created a confusing confluence of pricing signals—some real,
some policy-generated—that led people
to err more often when making economic decisions and then to divert some
of their resources to measures that protected them from the ill effects of bad
decisions. Poor resource reallocation
ultimately caused the efficiency of the
markets to diminish.

■ Can We Fix the Activist
Model?
What did we learn from this national
ordeal? Some say that what went wrong
was purely a matter of inaccurate measurement. Identifying where our economy’s potential is exactly is very difficult.
The problem with the activist policy,
some lament, is that we haven’t done a
better job of measuring that potential.
Others, I among them, say that the concept of economic potential cannot be
made into a useful policy tool. The reason this is so lies in the fact that when
we presumed that business cycles occur
because markets fail, we were wrong.
Can we fix the activist model? I don’t
think so.
Activist economic policies generally
failed to appreciate the dynamic environment of the marketplace, and more
specifically, the dynamic way in which
the market forms its expectations. We
now understand that as inflation rose,
people altered their behavior to accommodate it, altering what had previously
appeared to be a stable relationship in
the data. The harder economic policy
tried to push the unemployment rate
lower, the greater and more disruptive
the inflation price tag became. By continually working against the operations
of the market, we were disrupting the
beneficial, and ultimately necessary,
adjustments that the economy was working through.

■ The Real Business Cycle View:
A Brief Primer
What do we call two consecutive periods
when national output falls by 60 percent
or more? Answer: The weekend. Why
don’t we ask economic policymakers to
do something about this extreme decline
in output? Because the weekend dropoff is a natural response to a decline in
effort as the nation consumes leisure—
we take time off. On Monday, the economy picks up on its own, and economic
policymakers have no role to play. Yes,
we could easily, as some nations do, put
in place national workweek rules such
that we can “create jobs” by limiting the
number of hours individuals are allowed
to work per week, or alternatively, we
can raise unemployment by making
work on Saturdays mandatory. But we
don’t. We presume that what we see in
the data is an efficient economy’s
response to the impulses of the economic agents, and therefore, the economic policymaker need not intervene.
Likewise, you might be surprised to
know that national output typically falls
about 7 percent between the fourth and
first quarters. That puts these fluctuations on a par with the most extreme
recessions the economy faces. And yet
again, economic policymakers do nothing. In fact, this bit of information may
surprise you because virtually all of the
data reported on national economic performance is “seasonally adjusted,”
which means that it only reports those
fluctuations that are not part of the typical within-year gyrations in business
activity. You are not alarmed by this
omission in the data because, quite simply, it doesn’t matter to you. Because the
economy is responding naturally to seasonal forces that you understand, and
moreover, you can do nothing useful
about it, you care not to examine the
data at this frequency.
These seemingly ridiculous examples
underscore that we expect economic policymakers to identify aspects of economic performance where inefficiencies
exist and then put policies and programs
into place that reduce, if not eliminate
those inefficiencies. This insight leads us
to consider more carefully what we do
and do not understand about the phenomenon known as the industrial “business cycle.” To what extent do output
fluctuations at these frequencies reflect
the failure of the marketplace, and how
are our economic policies expected to

reduce the inefficiencies? Economists
who continue to proscribe economic
policies from the activist perspective fail
to provide a satisfactory answer to either
of these questions.
What if economic fluctuations that we
call the business cycle can be characterized as the economy’s optimal response
to external forces—some fortunate,
some not so fortunate—and are therefore
not the appropriate objects of a policy
response? What if, by interfering with
that response, we lay the groundwork for
greater, more disruptive economic
problems somewhere a little farther
down the road?

■ A Long-Run Perspective for
Economic Policy
Despite the rhetoric of activist economic
theory, which still pervades the policy
debate inside and outside of government,
I think economic policymakers, monetary and otherwise, are replacing their
business cycle focus with a longer-term
perspective. And this perspective has
made all the difference.
In the case of fiscal policy, we have
moved away from the idea that budgetary surpluses and deficits can be used
to manage the course of the business
cycle. Instead, we think more seriously
about the incentives and investment
properties of alternative government tax
and spending proposals. We think not
just in terms of this year’s fiscal surplus
or deficit, but also consider the generational inequities that various policies
imply. In trade policy, we think less in
terms of the number of jobs we create,
but more about how trade redirects our
existing jobs in the most effective way.
So, too, this perspective appears to have
permeated the conduct of monetary policy. By striking a balance between
money supply and its demand, that is, by
providing a relatively stable purchasing
power for the dollar, the central bank has
done a remarkable job in building its
credibility and keeping the inflationary
psychology subdued. By abandoning the
impulse to control fluctuations in
national output and movements in the
rate of national unemployment, policy
has provided the environment that
allows the marketplace the greatest
clarity to do what the marketplace is best
positioned to do.

The Federal Reserve is not alone among
central banks in this realization. A large
and growing number of nations now
require as a matter of law that their central bank commit to multiyear targets for
their retail price indexes. While the Federal Reserve does not have such a clearly
proscribed Congressional mandate, the
central bank has nevertheless produced
an inflation path that is observationally
equivalent to one.

■ Monetary Policy in the
Current Economic
Environment
Today we are faced with a set of economic indicators that have soured since
the fall. National production, which set
records for both duration and magnitude
in the 1990s, slowed by more than half
in the final quarter of 2000, and economic growth has been somewhat sluggish during the first half of 2001. Economic performance in our own backyard
has seen a more precipitous drop. Heavy
manufacturing, like steel, automobiles
and heavy trucks, chemicals, and rubber
and plastics, has seen its economic fortunes collapse over the past five months,
and these industries make up a disproportionate share of our jobs and
incomes.
Some sort of an economic slowdown
was not entirely unexpected. Our economic expansion had entered into Lake
Wobegon territory—where all of our
years were above average. But at some
point during this unprecedented period
of economic growth, we need to either
rethink what an “average” economic
growth rate is, or we need to be prepared
for a sharp realignment between our economic performance and underlying economic realities. For economists who
have consistently underpredicted the
growth rate in national income for seven
consecutive years—and that list is both
long and prominent—the current set of
economic data probably comes as a
belated “I told you so.”
But before we lay this incredible period
of economic expansion to rest, and heap
all of that “New Economy” literature in
the wastebasket, let’s consider what we
know, or more accurately, don’t know
about our current state of economic affairs.
As we currently conceive of national
economic policy, it is the job of the
policymaker to regulate the amount of

aggregate national spending by raising
or lowering money market interest
rates. The presumption is that economic
slowdowns, such as that which we are
seeing today, reflect a hesitancy on the
part of consumers and businesses to
adequately consume all of the nation’s
product. This seems a dubious strategy
for at least two reasons. First, it is
unclear that reductions in money market interest rates translate directly into
lower capital market interest rates and,
if they do, how sensitive aggregate
spending is to the interest rate. More
importantly, we never know with any
certainty whether the decline in aggregate economic performance originates
from a lack of adequate national
demand, or a change in national supply.
And in retrospect, there is growing evidence that much of what policymakers
believed to be demand-side weaknesses
in economic performance are more
likely to have been supply disturbances,
many of which appear to have been initiated by an energy shortage.
This is an important distinction. It may
be, as many have suggested, that a sudden drop in consumer and business confidence created an unexpected shortfall
in spending, which in turn caused an
undesired rise in inventories and a cutback in industrial production. Certainly,
recent readings showing an upturn in
business inventory-to-sales ratios and
the frightening drop in consumer optimism are consistent with this view. One
elixir for this economic condition might
be to help restore confidence by lowering money market interest rates.
But it may also be that the economy is
working to digest some of the past
year’s rather hard-to-swallow energycost increases, and our measures of
business performance are merely
reflecting this economic reality. Here, a
tonic that encourages the public to
spend more may actually be counterproductive. If we attempt to boost economic demands on an economy that is
having difficulty maintaining its ability
to supply, we risk turning a period of
modest economic adjustment into a
protracted period of economic chaos.
One need only look to data on national
energy costs, the recent sharp step-up in
the Producer and Consumer Price
Indexes, and the troubling high rate of
domestic money growth to support this
view of our economic condition.

■ A New Economic
Revolution?
I am convinced that we are part of
an economic revolution on an order
of magnitude rarely seen in a lifetime, but this New Economy is not
likely to always emerge smoothly.
We will be continually challenged,
by business cycle forces and from
other quarters, to deviate from our
longer-term goals to try to achieve
some shorter-term economic gains.
I believe that the New Economy
has yet to deliver its greatest gains.
Consider that it has been about 25
years since the development of the
microprocessor—halfway through
the innovation process as suggested
by historical experience—and
almost on schedule, the U.S. capital
stock has expanded explosively. In
the past two and a half years, nonfarm business productivity has
grown at a pace of about 3 percent
per year—its best showing in about
thirty years. If past technological
revolutions are a good indication,
this may be only the beginning.
Moreover, the new technologies
capable of rapidly propelling our
economy forward over the next few
decades may have the added benefit of helping us cope with the economic adjustments that we
inevitably face from time to time—
our business cycle fluctuations. If
business fluctuations are propagated by large swings in business
inventories, the time it takes for
information to flow between consumers and business and from business to business may dramatically
shorten from earlier episodes.
I wish I could tell you whether or
not there is a recession in our path.
I think not, and I believe that by
year’s end, we will once again be
impressed by the speed of our economic progress. But while I suspect
that this will be the road our economy takes, I remain convinced that
the only appropriate role for the
monetary authority in addressing
the business cycle is to endeavor to
keep liquidity in the marketplace
consistent with the economic
demands of the marketplace. We
need to resist the great temptation
to alter the economy’s path by presuming too much knowledge and

too much power over the course of economic events. We must be humbled by
the knowledge that growth, in the end,
comes from entrepreneurial energy, not
monetary policy. We facilitate, rather
than manage. We nurture, rather than
instigate. And in pursuing such a course,
the monetary authority contributes to our
economic prosperity in the most productive way it can, by laying the stable
financial foundation on which economic
prosperity can be built.

Sandra Pianalto is first vice president of the
Federal Reserve Bank of Cleveland. This
Commentary was printed on July 20, 2001.
The views expressed here are those of the
author and not necessarily those of the
Federal Reserve Bank of Cleveland, the
Board of Governors of the Federal Reserve
System, or its staff.
Economic Commentary is published by the
Research Department of the Federal Reserve Bank of Cleveland. To receive copies or
to be placed on the mailing list, e-mail your
request to 4d.subscriptions@clev.frb.org or fax
it to 216-579-3050. Economic Commentary is
also available at the Cleveland Fed’s site on the
World Wide Web: www.clev.frb.org/research,
where glossaries of terms are provided.
We invite comments, questions, and suggestions. E-mail us at editor@clev.frb.org.

Federal Reserve Bank of Cleveland
Research Department
P.O. Box 6387
Cleveland, OH 44101
Return Service Requested:
Please send corrected mailing label to
the above address.
Material may be reprinted if the source is
credited. Please send copies of reprinted
material to the editor.

PRSRT STD
U.S. Postage Paid
Cleveland, OH
Permit No. 385