View original document

The full text on this page is automatically extracted from the file linked above and may contain errors and inconsistencies.

Table 3 Factors Affecting

Market Share Changes
Gainers
1969

Competition
Financial institutions in market
Banks in market
Savingsand loans in market
Credit unions in market
Financial institutions in mainoffice community
Other banks in main-office
community
Savingsand loans in main-office
community
Credit unions in main-office
community

1977

11.0
4.5
2.2
4.3

11.4
4.2
2.6
4.6

5.0

5.2

1.4

1.4

1.2

Losers
Change

1969

1977

14.5
4.3
2.2
7.8

15.9
4.4

8.9

9.3

-0.2

o

1.3

1.6

-0.3d

1.3

0.1

1.5

1.9

-0.3b

2.3

2.4

0.1

6.1

5.8

-0.3

0.4

1.98
1.82

2.89
2.67

0.91c
0.85d
0.43
0.44
3.1

3.36
2.48

4.16
3.02

0.80
0.54
0.25
0.15
-2.8

0.11
0.31b
0.18
0.29d
5.9d

O.4b
-0.3d
O.4c
0.3c

3.2
8.3

Change

Gainer
change
minus
loser
change

l.4d
0.1
1.0d
0.5

-1.0d
-0.4c
-0.6c
-0.2

Branching
Number of branches
Excluding four largest banks"
Branches in new locations
Excluding four largest bankse
Percent of market offices

Interest

28.5

31.6

32.6

29.8

rate on deposits

Interest on deposits/average
time and savingsdeposits

Lending activities
Loans/assets
Commercial loans/loans
Consumer installment loans/
loans

4.00

5.71

.492
.119

.384

5.52

0.20

.470
.144

.545
.153

.354

4.01

.030

.517
.159

.047d
.015

.006
.019

.316

.339

.022

.008

a. Unless otherwise indicated, data are as of year-end 1969 and 1977. All office data for banks and savings
and loan institutions are as of June 30, 1970, and June 30,1977. Credit union data are as of year-end
1972 and 1977.
b. The difference is significant at the .10 level.
c. The difference is significant at the .05 level.
d. The difference is significant at the .01 level.
e. The four largest banks were two to six times larger than any other bank in the sample.
NOTE: A paired t test was used to determine statistical significance.
SOURCES: Federal Deposit Insurance Corporation, Credit Union Directory Buyers Guide, Directory of
American Savings and Loan Associations, and Federal Reserve Bank of Cleveland.

was limited, many banks opened branches
in new communities.
The losers presumably
suffered from a significant amount of branch
entry into their main-office communities
by
competing banks (0.3) as well as savings and
loans (004). While this entry was offset to
some degree by a reduction in the number of
credit
unions
(0.3), more net entry
by
financial
institutions
took
place in the
main-office
cornmunrnes
of the
losers
than the gainers.

Branching and Location
Consumers choose a bank on the basis
of many factors, including convenience
of

branch location to their work, residence, or
shopping areas. Banks, in turn, respond to
consumer
demand
by
increasing
their
branch ing activities.
Gainers were more aggressive in their
efforts
to expand,
which
was indicated
by the
increased
investment
in branch
offices.5
Despite being smaller banks, the
gainers established
more branches
in the
1970s than the losers. As a result, the gainers
increased
the proportion
of total offices
5. Although branching is prohibited in West
Virginia, banks are permitted to operate a
walk-in or drive-up facility within 2,000 feet
of their offices. Such facil ities are considered
as branches in th is study.

within their markets
from 28.5 to 31.6
percent,
while the percentage
of offices
operated
by losers fell from 32.6 to 29.8
percent.
Branch location also affects the volume
of business generated
by banks. A branch
established
in a different community
should
attract
more deposits
than an additional
office opened in the same cornrnunitv.f
A
bank that opens a branch in another community tends to increase the probability
of
generating
new deposits
as opposed
to
drawing
existing
deposits
from its other
offices. Gainers established
nearly one-half
of their
new branches
in communities
where they previously did not operate any
offices. In contrast,
less than one-third of
the losers' new offices were opened in new
locations.

Interest Rates on Deposits
The

Federal Reserve System's
Regulation Q restricts the ability of financial
institutions
to compete for time and savings
deposits
on the basis of interest
rates.
Financial institutions,
however, have some
flexibility in determining the mix of deposits
and their effective rates. Generally,
banks
that
pay the highest
effective
interest
rates attract the greatest volume of deposits .
Since specific rate information
on various
types of time and savings deposits was not
available, the average interest rate paid on
these deposits was calculated. While the two
groups of banks paid approximately
the
same average
rate in 1969, the gainers
increased their average rate more than the
losers in the 1970s. In 1977, the average rate
paid on time and savings deposits was 5.71
percent for the losers, compared
with 5.52
percent for the gainers.

Lending Policies
Lending
policies often
indicate
the
aggressiveness of management.
Given similar
demand
conditions,
differences
in loan-toasset ratios and composition
of loans should
reflect the lending pol icies and the aggressiveness of bank management.
Liberal lending
policies tend to encourage deposit growth.
Loan customers
are likely to deposit their
funds at the same financial institution
that
previously extended them credit. When banks
6. The term community includes the area within
the corporate limits of a city, village, or other
municipality .

turn down loan applications,
they run the
risk of applicants
withdrawing
their funds
and opening their accounts
at otherjnstitutions.
Loans made to businesses usually
generate
additional
deposits
immediately,
because
banks often
require
commercial
borrowers
to maintain
a deposit
balance.
Gainers allocated
a larger proportion
of their assets to loans and increased their
lending more than losers between 1969 and
1977. In addition,
gainers increased commercial
lending relatively
more than the
losers. Although
these
differences
were
small, they were consistent with expectations.

Summary

and Conclusion

Many banks in Ohio, Kentucky,
and
West Virginia gained or lost 4 percent or
more of their market share between 1969
and 1977. These banks were located in less
populated
markets
that experienced
more
entry
by thrift
institutions.
The deposit
size of the gainers was significantly
smaller
than that of the losers, and a greater percentage of gainers were not members of the
Federal
Reserve System
or a multi-bank
holding company.
While many factors contributed
to the
success of the gainer, the two most important
factors appeared to be a lower level of competition
from thrift institutions
and more
aggressive
management
policies.
Gainers
competed with fewer credit unions, and the
market areas and main-office
communities
of gainers also experienced
significantly
less
entry by other banks and savings and loans.
Gainers
established
a greater
number
of
branches,
with a greater portion
in new
communities.
In addition, gainers tended to
have higher average interest rates on deposits
and more liberal lending policies than the
losers.
The results of this analysis suggest that
small and independent
banks can compete
effectively with larger banks and subsidiaries
of mu Iti-bank holding companies for a share
of deposits in a local area by establishing
additional
offices and by aggressively providing better services. However, the competitive position of banks in local market
areas seems to be affected by direct competition and entry of thrift institutions.
The views stated herein are those of the author and
not necessarily those of the Federal Reserve Bank
of Cleveland or of the Board of Governors of the
Federal ReserveSystem.

May 19, 1980

ECONOMIC
COMMENTARY
In this issue:

Market Share
Gainers and Losers

Federal Reserve Bank of Cleveland
Research Department
P.O. Box 6387
Cleveland,OH
44101

BULK RATE
U.S. Postage Paid
Cleveland,OH
Permit No. 385

Table 1 Market Characteristics

Market Share Gainers and Losers
Markets
with a
gainer
or loser

Paul Watro is an economic analyst, Federal
Reserve Bank of Cleveland.

market. However, if deposits of
bank have increased more than
of competing banks, then that
may be attributed
to aggressive

Growth

1969

by Paul R. Watro

Regulatory changes and financial innovations
in recent
years have fostered
increased
competition
within
the banking
industry
and, indeed, among all financial institutions.
New payments
powers extended
to some
thrift institutions permit third-party
payment
services, which formerly were the exclusive
domain of commercial
banks. Savings and
loans, mutual
savings banks,
and credit
unions compete
directly or indirectly with
commercial
banks for transaction
accounts
through
new services, such as negotiable
order of withdrawal
(NOW) accounts, share
drafts, and remote service units. This more
competitive
environment
has altered
the
rate at which deposits grow at individual
financial institutions.
This Economic Commentary identifies
and explains some factors that contributed
to market deposit growth of individual banks
during the 1970s. A group of banks whose
share of total deposits in their market rose
by 4 percent or more (termed gainers) are
compared
with a group of banks whose
share of total deposits
in their markets
declined
by 4 percent
or more (termed
losers). 1 Differences in behavior presumably
would explain why some banks gained or
lost a portion of their market share.
Although
local economic
conditions
largely determine
deposit growth for the
market as a whole, bankers still can alter
the share of deposits that their banks maintain. Whether
banks gain or lose deposits
relative to their competitors
is likely to
depend on many factors, including mariagerial decisions
regarding
the number
of
branches,
office locations,
rates paid on
deposits, and lending policies. Suppose that
total deposits of all banks in a given market
area have increased
by 10 percent,
and
deposits of a particular bank have experienced
a similar gain. Bank growth may be viewed
as only average, since the particular bank is
merely keeping pace with other banks in the

Table 2 Characteristics

a

the particular
the deposits
extra growth
management.

Market and Bank Characteristics
of the Sample
A group of 120 Fourth District banks
that gained or lost 4 percent or more of the
total deposits
in their local market areas
between
1969 and 1977 were included in
the sample for this analysis. Sixty-one of the
banks were located in Ohio, 48 in Kentucky,
and 11 in West Virginia; the total number
included 56 gainers and 64 losers.2 None of
the banks selected was involved in a merger,
and three out of every four gainers operated
in the same market area as a loser.
While some banks compete for funds
in regional,
national,
and international
markets, most banks draw the vast majority
of their deposits from their local, or immediately surrounding,
area. Therefore,
banking
markets were defined along county lines to
simplify the analysis and to permit utilization
of county data. The banks in the sample
were prohibited
by branching
laws from
operating
offices
outside
of their home
county during the period examined.
The gainers and losers operated in 75
banking markets, or counties. These counties
were generally less populated than counties
without
a gainer or loser (see table 1). In
1969, the markets
served by gainers and
losers had an average of 37,467
fewer
residents;
11,820
fewer
households;
7.5
fewer
financial
institutions;
and $181.7
million less in deposits. Although the population, number of households,
and financial
deposits
grew at similar rates in markets
both with and without
gainers and losers,
per-capita income increased at a significantly
1. The 4·percent criterion was selected because it
reflected a trend in market-share changes and at
the same time provided a large enough sample
for reasonable statistical testing.
2. No Pennsylvania banks were included in the
sample because of data limitations attributed
to Pennsylvania's multi-county branching law.

Population

18,960
income

30,780

$2,914

Difference

-37,467

100,105

62,638

Households
Per-capita

Markets
without
a gainer
or loser

·11,820

$2,803

$111

between 1969 and 1977,
percent change

Markets
with a
gainer
or loser
8.0%

Markets
without
a gainer
or loser

Difference

8.3%

22.4

22.0

104.2

114.1

percent

Charter, percent
banks

3.7

Banks

4.6

4.7

-0.1

-0.3

3.3

-3.6

Savings and loans

2.3

3.8

-1.5

24.1

15.6

8.5

Credit unions

7.3

13.2

-5.9

10.1

2.1

8.0

135.0

132.6

2.4

$344.9

-$181.7

a. Data are as of year-end 1969 and 1977, with the following exceptions: population figures are as of
April 1970 and July 1977; savings and loans data are as of September 1968 and September 1977;
credit union data are as of year-end 1972.
b. The difference is significant at the .10 level.
NOTES: The t test was used to determine statistical significance.
There were 75 markets with a gainer or loser and 75 markets without a gainer or loser.
SOURCES:

Gainers
42.9

71.0

-28.1

37.1

41.9

-4.8

40.7

11.8

21.5

-25.9b
-9.7c
0.6c

Losers

Difference

2.3

1.7

1.8

2.0

-0.2

29.2

39.3

-10.1 c

35.9

32.9

3.0

48.4

21.2b

69.6

48.4

21.2b

41.1

68.8

-28.7c

41.1

67.2

-28.2c

3.2

7.4

29.2

67.6

-38.4c

company

_4.2c

a. The four largest banks (one gainer and three losers) were two to six times larger than any other bank
in the sample.
b. The difference is significant at the .05 level.
c. The difference is significant at the .01 level.
d. Percentage refers to gainers and losers in Ohio only. Kentucky and West Virginia currently do not
permit the formation of multi-bank holding companies.
NOTE: The t test was used to determine statistical significance.
SOURCE: Federal Reserve Bank of Cleveland.

Survey of Buying Power, Federal Home Loan Bank Board, Credit Union Directory and

Buyers Guide, Federal Reserve Bank of Cleveland, and U.S. Bureau of the Census.

slower rate in the markets served by gainers
and losers. In addition,
the gainers' and
losers' markets experienced
more entry by
thrift institutions,
but these markets had a
net reduction
in the number of banks as a
result of mergers and consolidations.
The institutional
characteristics
of the
gainers differed from the losers in several
important
ways (see table 2). Gainers were
significantly
smaller than the losers, and a
larger percentage of the gainers were statechartered
banks that were not members of
the Federal Reserve System or a multi-bank
holding
cornpanv.J In 1969, the average
gainer had deposits of $14.8 million, while
the average loser had deposits
of $40.7
million.4
The average gainer also held a
smaller share of market deposits in 1969. By
year-end 1977, however, the market positions
of the gainers and losers were reversed. The
3. Kentucky

Federal Reserve member
banks, percent
Multi-bank holdinJ
banks, percent

Difference

14.8

of state

7.8

Losers

69.6

0.4
-9.9b

Market deposits,

11.5

$163.2

four largest banks"

Market rank of banks

-7.5

Financial deposits,
millions of dollars

Deposit size,
millions of dollars

-0.3%

21.7

institutions

1977

1969
Gainers

Excluding

14.2

Financial

of Gainers and Losers

and West Virginia currently do not
permit the formation of multi-bank holding
companies.
4. All the banks in the sample had total deposits
under $71 million in 1969, except for four
Ohio banks with total deposits ranging from
$160 million to $472 million. By eliminating
these four banks, the average deposit size of the
gainers and losers is greatly reduced (see table 2).

average gainer increased
its market share
from 29.2 percent to 35.9 percent. In contrast, the average loser's market share fell
from 39.3 percent to 32.9 percent.

Competition
Competition
among
financial
institutions is a complex, dynamic phenomenon.
The number
of institutions
in a market
affects the behavior
and performance
of
market
participants;
a larger number
of
competitors
can
indicate
more
intense
competition.
Entry and exit also affect the
competitiveness
of institutions
in an area
over a period of time. New competitors
are
thought
to lead sellers to provide both a
higher level and a greater variety of services
at lower prices in order to maintain their
market
positions.
When another
financial
institution
enters a market, the probability
increases that an existing bank would lose a
portion of its market share.
To estimate the degree of competition
that gainers and losers encountered
during
the 1970s, the number of financial institutions (banks, savings and loans, and credit
unions) was examined in 1970 and again in
1977 (see table 3). Changes in the number of

competitors
should reflect the competitive
climate in the counties over the eight-year
period. In addition, the number of financial
institutions
operating
in the main-office
communities
of the gainers
and losers
should
approximate
the degree of direct
competition
that they faced. Banks typically
transact
the largest percentage
of their
business in the communities
in which they
are headquartered.
Losers faced a larger number of competitors
than the gainers throughout
the
1970s. In 1970, an average of 14.5 financial
institutions
operated
in the market areas
served by the losers, while an average of 11.0
financial institutions
operated in the gainers'
markets. Losers also had 3.9 more financial
institutions
operating
in their main-office
communities
than the gainers. This structural
differential
was attributed
to a disparity in
the number
of credit
unions.
Although
credit unions
are generally
much smaller
than banks and savings and loans, they have
been a significant source of competition
for
many banks in product Iines such as savings
deposits and consumer loans.
Other things being equal, banks that
do not provide quality services at competitive
prices inadvertently
encourage
other institutions
to enter their market
areas. An

average of 1.4 new competitors
entered the
markets served by losers, compared with an
average net increase of 0.4 in the gainers'
markets.
Thrift
institutions
accounted
for
nearly all of the entry. The average number
of savings and loans increased significantly
from 2.2 to 3.2 in the losers' markets,
compared with an average increase from 2.2
to 2.6 in the gainers' markets.
Over 80
percent of the savings and loan entry occurred
in Ohio, where the option exists to establish
branches
in more than
one county.
In
contrast, banks in Ohio, Kentucky, and West
Virginia (and savings and loans in the latter
two states) were prohibited
from opening
branches
outside
of
their
home-office
county.
Since the formation
of new banks
required large outlays of capital, very few
new banks were established.
In fact, the
market areas served by gainers experienced a
significant
net reduction
in the number of
banks as a result of mergers and consolidations. While nominal capital requirements
make it quite easy to start a credit union,
relatively few were established
in both the
gainers' and losers' markets. As a result, the
losers continued
to compete
with several
more credit unions than the gainers throughout the 1970s.
While bank entry into new markets

Table 1 Market Characteristics

Market Share Gainers and Losers
Markets
with a
gainer
or loser

Paul Watro is an economic analyst, Federal
Reserve Bank of Cleveland.

market. However, if deposits of
bank have increased more than
of competing banks, then that
may be attributed
to aggressive

Growth

1969

by Paul R. Watro

Regulatory changes and financial innovations
in recent
years have fostered
increased
competition
within
the banking
industry
and, indeed, among all financial institutions.
New payments
powers extended
to some
thrift institutions permit third-party
payment
services, which formerly were the exclusive
domain of commercial
banks. Savings and
loans, mutual
savings banks,
and credit
unions compete
directly or indirectly with
commercial
banks for transaction
accounts
through
new services, such as negotiable
order of withdrawal
(NOW) accounts, share
drafts, and remote service units. This more
competitive
environment
has altered
the
rate at which deposits grow at individual
financial institutions.
This Economic Commentary identifies
and explains some factors that contributed
to market deposit growth of individual banks
during the 1970s. A group of banks whose
share of total deposits in their market rose
by 4 percent or more (termed gainers) are
compared
with a group of banks whose
share of total deposits
in their markets
declined
by 4 percent
or more (termed
losers). 1 Differences in behavior presumably
would explain why some banks gained or
lost a portion of their market share.
Although
local economic
conditions
largely determine
deposit growth for the
market as a whole, bankers still can alter
the share of deposits that their banks maintain. Whether
banks gain or lose deposits
relative to their competitors
is likely to
depend on many factors, including mariagerial decisions
regarding
the number
of
branches,
office locations,
rates paid on
deposits, and lending policies. Suppose that
total deposits of all banks in a given market
area have increased
by 10 percent,
and
deposits of a particular bank have experienced
a similar gain. Bank growth may be viewed
as only average, since the particular bank is
merely keeping pace with other banks in the

Table 2 Characteristics

a

the particular
the deposits
extra growth
management.

Market and Bank Characteristics
of the Sample
A group of 120 Fourth District banks
that gained or lost 4 percent or more of the
total deposits
in their local market areas
between
1969 and 1977 were included in
the sample for this analysis. Sixty-one of the
banks were located in Ohio, 48 in Kentucky,
and 11 in West Virginia; the total number
included 56 gainers and 64 losers.2 None of
the banks selected was involved in a merger,
and three out of every four gainers operated
in the same market area as a loser.
While some banks compete for funds
in regional,
national,
and international
markets, most banks draw the vast majority
of their deposits from their local, or immediately surrounding,
area. Therefore,
banking
markets were defined along county lines to
simplify the analysis and to permit utilization
of county data. The banks in the sample
were prohibited
by branching
laws from
operating
offices
outside
of their home
county during the period examined.
The gainers and losers operated in 75
banking markets, or counties. These counties
were generally less populated than counties
without
a gainer or loser (see table 1). In
1969, the markets
served by gainers and
losers had an average of 37,467
fewer
residents;
11,820
fewer
households;
7.5
fewer
financial
institutions;
and $181.7
million less in deposits. Although the population, number of households,
and financial
deposits
grew at similar rates in markets
both with and without
gainers and losers,
per-capita income increased at a significantly
1. The 4·percent criterion was selected because it
reflected a trend in market-share changes and at
the same time provided a large enough sample
for reasonable statistical testing.
2. No Pennsylvania banks were included in the
sample because of data limitations attributed
to Pennsylvania's multi-county branching law.

Population

18,960
income

30,780

$2,914

Difference

-37,467

100,105

62,638

Households
Per-capita

Markets
without
a gainer
or loser

·11,820

$2,803

$111

between 1969 and 1977,
percent change

Markets
with a
gainer
or loser
8.0%

Markets
without
a gainer
or loser

Difference

8.3%

22.4

22.0

104.2

114.1

percent

Charter, percent
banks

3.7

Banks

4.6

4.7

-0.1

-0.3

3.3

-3.6

Savings and loans

2.3

3.8

-1.5

24.1

15.6

8.5

Credit unions

7.3

13.2

-5.9

10.1

2.1

8.0

135.0

132.6

2.4

$344.9

-$181.7

a. Data are as of year-end 1969 and 1977, with the following exceptions: population figures are as of
April 1970 and July 1977; savings and loans data are as of September 1968 and September 1977;
credit union data are as of year-end 1972.
b. The difference is significant at the .10 level.
NOTES: The t test was used to determine statistical significance.
There were 75 markets with a gainer or loser and 75 markets without a gainer or loser.
SOURCES:

Gainers
42.9

71.0

-28.1

37.1

41.9

-4.8

40.7

11.8

21.5

-25.9b
-9.7c
0.6c

Losers

Difference

2.3

1.7

1.8

2.0

-0.2

29.2

39.3

-10.1 c

35.9

32.9

3.0

48.4

21.2b

69.6

48.4

21.2b

41.1

68.8

-28.7c

41.1

67.2

-28.2c

3.2

7.4

29.2

67.6

-38.4c

company

_4.2c

a. The four largest banks (one gainer and three losers) were two to six times larger than any other bank
in the sample.
b. The difference is significant at the .05 level.
c. The difference is significant at the .01 level.
d. Percentage refers to gainers and losers in Ohio only. Kentucky and West Virginia currently do not
permit the formation of multi-bank holding companies.
NOTE: The t test was used to determine statistical significance.
SOURCE: Federal Reserve Bank of Cleveland.

Survey of Buying Power, Federal Home Loan Bank Board, Credit Union Directory and

Buyers Guide, Federal Reserve Bank of Cleveland, and U.S. Bureau of the Census.

slower rate in the markets served by gainers
and losers. In addition,
the gainers' and
losers' markets experienced
more entry by
thrift institutions,
but these markets had a
net reduction
in the number of banks as a
result of mergers and consolidations.
The institutional
characteristics
of the
gainers differed from the losers in several
important
ways (see table 2). Gainers were
significantly
smaller than the losers, and a
larger percentage of the gainers were statechartered
banks that were not members of
the Federal Reserve System or a multi-bank
holding
cornpanv.J In 1969, the average
gainer had deposits of $14.8 million, while
the average loser had deposits
of $40.7
million.4
The average gainer also held a
smaller share of market deposits in 1969. By
year-end 1977, however, the market positions
of the gainers and losers were reversed. The
3. Kentucky

Federal Reserve member
banks, percent
Multi-bank holdinJ
banks, percent

Difference

14.8

of state

7.8

Losers

69.6

0.4
-9.9b

Market deposits,

11.5

$163.2

four largest banks"

Market rank of banks

-7.5

Financial deposits,
millions of dollars

Deposit size,
millions of dollars

-0.3%

21.7

institutions

1977

1969
Gainers

Excluding

14.2

Financial

of Gainers and Losers

and West Virginia currently do not
permit the formation of multi-bank holding
companies.
4. All the banks in the sample had total deposits
under $71 million in 1969, except for four
Ohio banks with total deposits ranging from
$160 million to $472 million. By eliminating
these four banks, the average deposit size of the
gainers and losers is greatly reduced (see table 2).

average gainer increased
its market share
from 29.2 percent to 35.9 percent. In contrast, the average loser's market share fell
from 39.3 percent to 32.9 percent.

Competition
Competition
among
financial
institutions is a complex, dynamic phenomenon.
The number
of institutions
in a market
affects the behavior
and performance
of
market
participants;
a larger number
of
competitors
can
indicate
more
intense
competition.
Entry and exit also affect the
competitiveness
of institutions
in an area
over a period of time. New competitors
are
thought
to lead sellers to provide both a
higher level and a greater variety of services
at lower prices in order to maintain their
market
positions.
When another
financial
institution
enters a market, the probability
increases that an existing bank would lose a
portion of its market share.
To estimate the degree of competition
that gainers and losers encountered
during
the 1970s, the number of financial institutions (banks, savings and loans, and credit
unions) was examined in 1970 and again in
1977 (see table 3). Changes in the number of

competitors
should reflect the competitive
climate in the counties over the eight-year
period. In addition, the number of financial
institutions
operating
in the main-office
communities
of the gainers
and losers
should
approximate
the degree of direct
competition
that they faced. Banks typically
transact
the largest percentage
of their
business in the communities
in which they
are headquartered.
Losers faced a larger number of competitors
than the gainers throughout
the
1970s. In 1970, an average of 14.5 financial
institutions
operated
in the market areas
served by the losers, while an average of 11.0
financial institutions
operated in the gainers'
markets. Losers also had 3.9 more financial
institutions
operating
in their main-office
communities
than the gainers. This structural
differential
was attributed
to a disparity in
the number
of credit
unions.
Although
credit unions
are generally
much smaller
than banks and savings and loans, they have
been a significant source of competition
for
many banks in product Iines such as savings
deposits and consumer loans.
Other things being equal, banks that
do not provide quality services at competitive
prices inadvertently
encourage
other institutions
to enter their market
areas. An

average of 1.4 new competitors
entered the
markets served by losers, compared with an
average net increase of 0.4 in the gainers'
markets.
Thrift
institutions
accounted
for
nearly all of the entry. The average number
of savings and loans increased significantly
from 2.2 to 3.2 in the losers' markets,
compared with an average increase from 2.2
to 2.6 in the gainers' markets.
Over 80
percent of the savings and loan entry occurred
in Ohio, where the option exists to establish
branches
in more than
one county.
In
contrast, banks in Ohio, Kentucky, and West
Virginia (and savings and loans in the latter
two states) were prohibited
from opening
branches
outside
of
their
home-office
county.
Since the formation
of new banks
required large outlays of capital, very few
new banks were established.
In fact, the
market areas served by gainers experienced a
significant
net reduction
in the number of
banks as a result of mergers and consolidations. While nominal capital requirements
make it quite easy to start a credit union,
relatively few were established
in both the
gainers' and losers' markets. As a result, the
losers continued
to compete
with several
more credit unions than the gainers throughout the 1970s.
While bank entry into new markets

Table 1 Market Characteristics

Market Share Gainers and Losers
Markets
with a
gainer
or loser

Paul Watro is an economic analyst, Federal
Reserve Bank of Cleveland.

market. However, if deposits of
bank have increased more than
of competing banks, then that
may be attributed
to aggressive

Growth

1969

by Paul R. Watro

Regulatory changes and financial innovations
in recent
years have fostered
increased
competition
within
the banking
industry
and, indeed, among all financial institutions.
New payments
powers extended
to some
thrift institutions permit third-party
payment
services, which formerly were the exclusive
domain of commercial
banks. Savings and
loans, mutual
savings banks,
and credit
unions compete
directly or indirectly with
commercial
banks for transaction
accounts
through
new services, such as negotiable
order of withdrawal
(NOW) accounts, share
drafts, and remote service units. This more
competitive
environment
has altered
the
rate at which deposits grow at individual
financial institutions.
This Economic Commentary identifies
and explains some factors that contributed
to market deposit growth of individual banks
during the 1970s. A group of banks whose
share of total deposits in their market rose
by 4 percent or more (termed gainers) are
compared
with a group of banks whose
share of total deposits
in their markets
declined
by 4 percent
or more (termed
losers). 1 Differences in behavior presumably
would explain why some banks gained or
lost a portion of their market share.
Although
local economic
conditions
largely determine
deposit growth for the
market as a whole, bankers still can alter
the share of deposits that their banks maintain. Whether
banks gain or lose deposits
relative to their competitors
is likely to
depend on many factors, including mariagerial decisions
regarding
the number
of
branches,
office locations,
rates paid on
deposits, and lending policies. Suppose that
total deposits of all banks in a given market
area have increased
by 10 percent,
and
deposits of a particular bank have experienced
a similar gain. Bank growth may be viewed
as only average, since the particular bank is
merely keeping pace with other banks in the

Table 2 Characteristics

a

the particular
the deposits
extra growth
management.

Market and Bank Characteristics
of the Sample
A group of 120 Fourth District banks
that gained or lost 4 percent or more of the
total deposits
in their local market areas
between
1969 and 1977 were included in
the sample for this analysis. Sixty-one of the
banks were located in Ohio, 48 in Kentucky,
and 11 in West Virginia; the total number
included 56 gainers and 64 losers.2 None of
the banks selected was involved in a merger,
and three out of every four gainers operated
in the same market area as a loser.
While some banks compete for funds
in regional,
national,
and international
markets, most banks draw the vast majority
of their deposits from their local, or immediately surrounding,
area. Therefore,
banking
markets were defined along county lines to
simplify the analysis and to permit utilization
of county data. The banks in the sample
were prohibited
by branching
laws from
operating
offices
outside
of their home
county during the period examined.
The gainers and losers operated in 75
banking markets, or counties. These counties
were generally less populated than counties
without
a gainer or loser (see table 1). In
1969, the markets
served by gainers and
losers had an average of 37,467
fewer
residents;
11,820
fewer
households;
7.5
fewer
financial
institutions;
and $181.7
million less in deposits. Although the population, number of households,
and financial
deposits
grew at similar rates in markets
both with and without
gainers and losers,
per-capita income increased at a significantly
1. The 4·percent criterion was selected because it
reflected a trend in market-share changes and at
the same time provided a large enough sample
for reasonable statistical testing.
2. No Pennsylvania banks were included in the
sample because of data limitations attributed
to Pennsylvania's multi-county branching law.

Population

18,960
income

30,780

$2,914

Difference

-37,467

100,105

62,638

Households
Per-capita

Markets
without
a gainer
or loser

·11,820

$2,803

$111

between 1969 and 1977,
percent change

Markets
with a
gainer
or loser
8.0%

Markets
without
a gainer
or loser

Difference

8.3%

22.4

22.0

104.2

114.1

percent

Charter, percent
banks

3.7

Banks

4.6

4.7

-0.1

-0.3

3.3

-3.6

Savings and loans

2.3

3.8

-1.5

24.1

15.6

8.5

Credit unions

7.3

13.2

-5.9

10.1

2.1

8.0

135.0

132.6

2.4

$344.9

-$181.7

a. Data are as of year-end 1969 and 1977, with the following exceptions: population figures are as of
April 1970 and July 1977; savings and loans data are as of September 1968 and September 1977;
credit union data are as of year-end 1972.
b. The difference is significant at the .10 level.
NOTES: The t test was used to determine statistical significance.
There were 75 markets with a gainer or loser and 75 markets without a gainer or loser.
SOURCES:

Gainers
42.9

71.0

-28.1

37.1

41.9

-4.8

40.7

11.8

21.5

-25.9b
-9.7c
0.6c

Losers

Difference

2.3

1.7

1.8

2.0

-0.2

29.2

39.3

-10.1 c

35.9

32.9

3.0

48.4

21.2b

69.6

48.4

21.2b

41.1

68.8

-28.7c

41.1

67.2

-28.2c

3.2

7.4

29.2

67.6

-38.4c

company

_4.2c

a. The four largest banks (one gainer and three losers) were two to six times larger than any other bank
in the sample.
b. The difference is significant at the .05 level.
c. The difference is significant at the .01 level.
d. Percentage refers to gainers and losers in Ohio only. Kentucky and West Virginia currently do not
permit the formation of multi-bank holding companies.
NOTE: The t test was used to determine statistical significance.
SOURCE: Federal Reserve Bank of Cleveland.

Survey of Buying Power, Federal Home Loan Bank Board, Credit Union Directory and

Buyers Guide, Federal Reserve Bank of Cleveland, and U.S. Bureau of the Census.

slower rate in the markets served by gainers
and losers. In addition,
the gainers' and
losers' markets experienced
more entry by
thrift institutions,
but these markets had a
net reduction
in the number of banks as a
result of mergers and consolidations.
The institutional
characteristics
of the
gainers differed from the losers in several
important
ways (see table 2). Gainers were
significantly
smaller than the losers, and a
larger percentage of the gainers were statechartered
banks that were not members of
the Federal Reserve System or a multi-bank
holding
cornpanv.J In 1969, the average
gainer had deposits of $14.8 million, while
the average loser had deposits
of $40.7
million.4
The average gainer also held a
smaller share of market deposits in 1969. By
year-end 1977, however, the market positions
of the gainers and losers were reversed. The
3. Kentucky

Federal Reserve member
banks, percent
Multi-bank holdinJ
banks, percent

Difference

14.8

of state

7.8

Losers

69.6

0.4
-9.9b

Market deposits,

11.5

$163.2

four largest banks"

Market rank of banks

-7.5

Financial deposits,
millions of dollars

Deposit size,
millions of dollars

-0.3%

21.7

institutions

1977

1969
Gainers

Excluding

14.2

Financial

of Gainers and Losers

and West Virginia currently do not
permit the formation of multi-bank holding
companies.
4. All the banks in the sample had total deposits
under $71 million in 1969, except for four
Ohio banks with total deposits ranging from
$160 million to $472 million. By eliminating
these four banks, the average deposit size of the
gainers and losers is greatly reduced (see table 2).

average gainer increased
its market share
from 29.2 percent to 35.9 percent. In contrast, the average loser's market share fell
from 39.3 percent to 32.9 percent.

Competition
Competition
among
financial
institutions is a complex, dynamic phenomenon.
The number
of institutions
in a market
affects the behavior
and performance
of
market
participants;
a larger number
of
competitors
can
indicate
more
intense
competition.
Entry and exit also affect the
competitiveness
of institutions
in an area
over a period of time. New competitors
are
thought
to lead sellers to provide both a
higher level and a greater variety of services
at lower prices in order to maintain their
market
positions.
When another
financial
institution
enters a market, the probability
increases that an existing bank would lose a
portion of its market share.
To estimate the degree of competition
that gainers and losers encountered
during
the 1970s, the number of financial institutions (banks, savings and loans, and credit
unions) was examined in 1970 and again in
1977 (see table 3). Changes in the number of

competitors
should reflect the competitive
climate in the counties over the eight-year
period. In addition, the number of financial
institutions
operating
in the main-office
communities
of the gainers
and losers
should
approximate
the degree of direct
competition
that they faced. Banks typically
transact
the largest percentage
of their
business in the communities
in which they
are headquartered.
Losers faced a larger number of competitors
than the gainers throughout
the
1970s. In 1970, an average of 14.5 financial
institutions
operated
in the market areas
served by the losers, while an average of 11.0
financial institutions
operated in the gainers'
markets. Losers also had 3.9 more financial
institutions
operating
in their main-office
communities
than the gainers. This structural
differential
was attributed
to a disparity in
the number
of credit
unions.
Although
credit unions
are generally
much smaller
than banks and savings and loans, they have
been a significant source of competition
for
many banks in product Iines such as savings
deposits and consumer loans.
Other things being equal, banks that
do not provide quality services at competitive
prices inadvertently
encourage
other institutions
to enter their market
areas. An

average of 1.4 new competitors
entered the
markets served by losers, compared with an
average net increase of 0.4 in the gainers'
markets.
Thrift
institutions
accounted
for
nearly all of the entry. The average number
of savings and loans increased significantly
from 2.2 to 3.2 in the losers' markets,
compared with an average increase from 2.2
to 2.6 in the gainers' markets.
Over 80
percent of the savings and loan entry occurred
in Ohio, where the option exists to establish
branches
in more than
one county.
In
contrast, banks in Ohio, Kentucky, and West
Virginia (and savings and loans in the latter
two states) were prohibited
from opening
branches
outside
of
their
home-office
county.
Since the formation
of new banks
required large outlays of capital, very few
new banks were established.
In fact, the
market areas served by gainers experienced a
significant
net reduction
in the number of
banks as a result of mergers and consolidations. While nominal capital requirements
make it quite easy to start a credit union,
relatively few were established
in both the
gainers' and losers' markets. As a result, the
losers continued
to compete
with several
more credit unions than the gainers throughout the 1970s.
While bank entry into new markets

Table 3 Factors Affecting

Market Share Changes
Gainers
1969

Competition
Financial institutions in market
Banks in market
Savingsand loans in market
Credit unions in market
Financial institutions in mainoffice community
Other banks in main-office
community
Savingsand loans in main-office
community
Credit unions in main-office
community

1977

11.0
4.5
2.2
4.3

11.4
4.2
2.6
4.6

5.0

5.2

1.4

1.4

1.2

Losers
Change

1969

1977

14.5
4.3
2.2
7.8

15.9
4.4

8.9

9.3

-0.2

o

1.3

1.6

-0.3d

1.3

0.1

1.5

1.9

-0.3b

2.3

2.4

0.1

6.1

5.8

-0.3

0.4

1.98
1.82

2.89
2.67

0.91c
0.85d
0.43
0.44
3.1

3.36
2.48

4.16
3.02

0.80
0.54
0.25
0.15
-2.8

0.11
0.31b
0.18
0.29d
5.9d

O.4b
-0.3d
O.4c
0.3c

3.2
8.3

Change

Gainer
change
minus
loser
change

l.4d
0.1
1.0d
0.5

-1.0d
-0.4c
-0.6c
-0.2

Branching
Number of branches
Excluding four largest banks"
Branches in new locations
Excluding four largest bankse
Percent of market offices

Interest

28.5

31.6

32.6

29.8

rate on deposits

Interest on deposits/average
time and savingsdeposits

Lending activities
Loans/assets
Commercial loans/loans
Consumer installment loans/
loans

4.00

5.71

.492
.119

.384

5.52

0.20

.470
.144

.545
.153

.354

4.01

.030

.517
.159

.047d
.015

.006
.019

.316

.339

.022

.008

a. Unless otherwise indicated, data are as of year-end 1969 and 1977. All office data for banks and savings
and loan institutions are as of June 30, 1970, and June 30,1977. Credit union data are as of year-end
1972 and 1977.
b. The difference is significant at the .10 level.
c. The difference is significant at the .05 level.
d. The difference is significant at the .01 level.
e. The four largest banks were two to six times larger than any other bank in the sample.
NOTE: A paired t test was used to determine statistical significance.
SOURCES: Federal Deposit Insurance Corporation, Credit Union Directory Buyers Guide, Directory of
American Savings and Loan Associations, and Federal Reserve Bank of Cleveland.

was limited, many banks opened branches
in new communities.
The losers presumably
suffered from a significant amount of branch
entry into their main-office communities
by
competing banks (0.3) as well as savings and
loans (004). While this entry was offset to
some degree by a reduction in the number of
credit
unions
(0.3), more net entry
by
financial
institutions
took
place in the
main-office
cornmunrnes
of the
losers
than the gainers.

Branching and Location
Consumers choose a bank on the basis
of many factors, including convenience
of

branch location to their work, residence, or
shopping areas. Banks, in turn, respond to
consumer
demand
by
increasing
their
branch ing activities.
Gainers were more aggressive in their
efforts
to expand,
which
was indicated
by the
increased
investment
in branch
offices.5
Despite being smaller banks, the
gainers established
more branches
in the
1970s than the losers. As a result, the gainers
increased
the proportion
of total offices
5. Although branching is prohibited in West
Virginia, banks are permitted to operate a
walk-in or drive-up facility within 2,000 feet
of their offices. Such facil ities are considered
as branches in th is study.

within their markets
from 28.5 to 31.6
percent,
while the percentage
of offices
operated
by losers fell from 32.6 to 29.8
percent.
Branch location also affects the volume
of business generated
by banks. A branch
established
in a different community
should
attract
more deposits
than an additional
office opened in the same cornrnunitv.f
A
bank that opens a branch in another community tends to increase the probability
of
generating
new deposits
as opposed
to
drawing
existing
deposits
from its other
offices. Gainers established
nearly one-half
of their
new branches
in communities
where they previously did not operate any
offices. In contrast,
less than one-third of
the losers' new offices were opened in new
locations.

Interest Rates on Deposits
The

Federal Reserve System's
Regulation Q restricts the ability of financial
institutions
to compete for time and savings
deposits
on the basis of interest
rates.
Financial institutions,
however, have some
flexibility in determining the mix of deposits
and their effective rates. Generally,
banks
that
pay the highest
effective
interest
rates attract the greatest volume of deposits .
Since specific rate information
on various
types of time and savings deposits was not
available, the average interest rate paid on
these deposits was calculated. While the two
groups of banks paid approximately
the
same average
rate in 1969, the gainers
increased their average rate more than the
losers in the 1970s. In 1977, the average rate
paid on time and savings deposits was 5.71
percent for the losers, compared
with 5.52
percent for the gainers.

Lending Policies
Lending
policies often
indicate
the
aggressiveness of management.
Given similar
demand
conditions,
differences
in loan-toasset ratios and composition
of loans should
reflect the lending pol icies and the aggressiveness of bank management.
Liberal lending
policies tend to encourage deposit growth.
Loan customers
are likely to deposit their
funds at the same financial institution
that
previously extended them credit. When banks
6. The term community includes the area within
the corporate limits of a city, village, or other
municipality .

turn down loan applications,
they run the
risk of applicants
withdrawing
their funds
and opening their accounts
at otherjnstitutions.
Loans made to businesses usually
generate
additional
deposits
immediately,
because
banks often
require
commercial
borrowers
to maintain
a deposit
balance.
Gainers allocated
a larger proportion
of their assets to loans and increased their
lending more than losers between 1969 and
1977. In addition,
gainers increased commercial
lending relatively
more than the
losers. Although
these
differences
were
small, they were consistent with expectations.

Summary

and Conclusion

Many banks in Ohio, Kentucky,
and
West Virginia gained or lost 4 percent or
more of their market share between 1969
and 1977. These banks were located in less
populated
markets
that experienced
more
entry
by thrift
institutions.
The deposit
size of the gainers was significantly
smaller
than that of the losers, and a greater percentage of gainers were not members of the
Federal
Reserve System
or a multi-bank
holding company.
While many factors contributed
to the
success of the gainer, the two most important
factors appeared to be a lower level of competition
from thrift institutions
and more
aggressive
management
policies.
Gainers
competed with fewer credit unions, and the
market areas and main-office
communities
of gainers also experienced
significantly
less
entry by other banks and savings and loans.
Gainers
established
a greater
number
of
branches,
with a greater portion
in new
communities.
In addition, gainers tended to
have higher average interest rates on deposits
and more liberal lending policies than the
losers.
The results of this analysis suggest that
small and independent
banks can compete
effectively with larger banks and subsidiaries
of mu Iti-bank holding companies for a share
of deposits in a local area by establishing
additional
offices and by aggressively providing better services. However, the competitive position of banks in local market
areas seems to be affected by direct competition and entry of thrift institutions.
The views stated herein are those of the author and
not necessarily those of the Federal Reserve Bank
of Cleveland or of the Board of Governors of the
Federal ReserveSystem.

May 19, 1980

ECONOMIC
COMMENTARY
In this issue:

Market Share
Gainers and Losers

Federal Reserve Bank of Cleveland
Research Department
P.O. Box 6387
Cleveland,OH
44101

BULK RATE
U.S. Postage Paid
Cleveland,OH
Permit No. 385

Table 3 Factors Affecting

Market Share Changes
Gainers
1969

Competition
Financial institutions in market
Banks in market
Savingsand loans in market
Credit unions in market
Financial institutions in mainoffice community
Other banks in main-office
community
Savingsand loans in main-office
community
Credit unions in main-office
community

1977

11.0
4.5
2.2
4.3

11.4
4.2
2.6
4.6

5.0

5.2

1.4

1.4

1.2

Losers
Change

1969

1977

14.5
4.3
2.2
7.8

15.9
4.4

8.9

9.3

-0.2

o

1.3

1.6

-0.3d

1.3

0.1

1.5

1.9

-0.3b

2.3

2.4

0.1

6.1

5.8

-0.3

0.4

1.98
1.82

2.89
2.67

0.91c
0.85d
0.43
0.44
3.1

3.36
2.48

4.16
3.02

0.80
0.54
0.25
0.15
-2.8

0.11
0.31b
0.18
0.29d
5.9d

O.4b
-0.3d
O.4c
0.3c

3.2
8.3

Change

Gainer
change
minus
loser
change

l.4d
0.1
1.0d
0.5

-1.0d
-0.4c
-0.6c
-0.2

Branching
Number of branches
Excluding four largest banks"
Branches in new locations
Excluding four largest bankse
Percent of market offices

Interest

28.5

31.6

32.6

29.8

rate on deposits

Interest on deposits/average
time and savingsdeposits

Lending activities
Loans/assets
Commercial loans/loans
Consumer installment loans/
loans

4.00

5.71

.492
.119

.384

5.52

0.20

.470
.144

.545
.153

.354

4.01

.030

.517
.159

.047d
.015

.006
.019

.316

.339

.022

.008

a. Unless otherwise indicated, data are as of year-end 1969 and 1977. All office data for banks and savings
and loan institutions are as of June 30, 1970, and June 30,1977. Credit union data are as of year-end
1972 and 1977.
b. The difference is significant at the .10 level.
c. The difference is significant at the .05 level.
d. The difference is significant at the .01 level.
e. The four largest banks were two to six times larger than any other bank in the sample.
NOTE: A paired t test was used to determine statistical significance.
SOURCES: Federal Deposit Insurance Corporation, Credit Union Directory Buyers Guide, Directory of
American Savings and Loan Associations, and Federal Reserve Bank of Cleveland.

was limited, many banks opened branches
in new communities.
The losers presumably
suffered from a significant amount of branch
entry into their main-office communities
by
competing banks (0.3) as well as savings and
loans (004). While this entry was offset to
some degree by a reduction in the number of
credit
unions
(0.3), more net entry
by
financial
institutions
took
place in the
main-office
cornmunrnes
of the
losers
than the gainers.

Branching and Location
Consumers choose a bank on the basis
of many factors, including convenience
of

branch location to their work, residence, or
shopping areas. Banks, in turn, respond to
consumer
demand
by
increasing
their
branch ing activities.
Gainers were more aggressive in their
efforts
to expand,
which
was indicated
by the
increased
investment
in branch
offices.5
Despite being smaller banks, the
gainers established
more branches
in the
1970s than the losers. As a result, the gainers
increased
the proportion
of total offices
5. Although branching is prohibited in West
Virginia, banks are permitted to operate a
walk-in or drive-up facility within 2,000 feet
of their offices. Such facil ities are considered
as branches in th is study.

within their markets
from 28.5 to 31.6
percent,
while the percentage
of offices
operated
by losers fell from 32.6 to 29.8
percent.
Branch location also affects the volume
of business generated
by banks. A branch
established
in a different community
should
attract
more deposits
than an additional
office opened in the same cornrnunitv.f
A
bank that opens a branch in another community tends to increase the probability
of
generating
new deposits
as opposed
to
drawing
existing
deposits
from its other
offices. Gainers established
nearly one-half
of their
new branches
in communities
where they previously did not operate any
offices. In contrast,
less than one-third of
the losers' new offices were opened in new
locations.

Interest Rates on Deposits
The

Federal Reserve System's
Regulation Q restricts the ability of financial
institutions
to compete for time and savings
deposits
on the basis of interest
rates.
Financial institutions,
however, have some
flexibility in determining the mix of deposits
and their effective rates. Generally,
banks
that
pay the highest
effective
interest
rates attract the greatest volume of deposits .
Since specific rate information
on various
types of time and savings deposits was not
available, the average interest rate paid on
these deposits was calculated. While the two
groups of banks paid approximately
the
same average
rate in 1969, the gainers
increased their average rate more than the
losers in the 1970s. In 1977, the average rate
paid on time and savings deposits was 5.71
percent for the losers, compared
with 5.52
percent for the gainers.

Lending Policies
Lending
policies often
indicate
the
aggressiveness of management.
Given similar
demand
conditions,
differences
in loan-toasset ratios and composition
of loans should
reflect the lending pol icies and the aggressiveness of bank management.
Liberal lending
policies tend to encourage deposit growth.
Loan customers
are likely to deposit their
funds at the same financial institution
that
previously extended them credit. When banks
6. The term community includes the area within
the corporate limits of a city, village, or other
municipality .

turn down loan applications,
they run the
risk of applicants
withdrawing
their funds
and opening their accounts
at otherjnstitutions.
Loans made to businesses usually
generate
additional
deposits
immediately,
because
banks often
require
commercial
borrowers
to maintain
a deposit
balance.
Gainers allocated
a larger proportion
of their assets to loans and increased their
lending more than losers between 1969 and
1977. In addition,
gainers increased commercial
lending relatively
more than the
losers. Although
these
differences
were
small, they were consistent with expectations.

Summary

and Conclusion

Many banks in Ohio, Kentucky,
and
West Virginia gained or lost 4 percent or
more of their market share between 1969
and 1977. These banks were located in less
populated
markets
that experienced
more
entry
by thrift
institutions.
The deposit
size of the gainers was significantly
smaller
than that of the losers, and a greater percentage of gainers were not members of the
Federal
Reserve System
or a multi-bank
holding company.
While many factors contributed
to the
success of the gainer, the two most important
factors appeared to be a lower level of competition
from thrift institutions
and more
aggressive
management
policies.
Gainers
competed with fewer credit unions, and the
market areas and main-office
communities
of gainers also experienced
significantly
less
entry by other banks and savings and loans.
Gainers
established
a greater
number
of
branches,
with a greater portion
in new
communities.
In addition, gainers tended to
have higher average interest rates on deposits
and more liberal lending policies than the
losers.
The results of this analysis suggest that
small and independent
banks can compete
effectively with larger banks and subsidiaries
of mu Iti-bank holding companies for a share
of deposits in a local area by establishing
additional
offices and by aggressively providing better services. However, the competitive position of banks in local market
areas seems to be affected by direct competition and entry of thrift institutions.
The views stated herein are those of the author and
not necessarily those of the Federal Reserve Bank
of Cleveland or of the Board of Governors of the
Federal ReserveSystem.

May 19, 1980

ECONOMIC
COMMENTARY
In this issue:

Market Share
Gainers and Losers

Federal Reserve Bank of Cleveland
Research Department
P.O. Box 6387
Cleveland,OH
44101

BULK RATE
U.S. Postage Paid
Cleveland,OH
Permit No. 385