View original document

The full text on this page is automatically extracted from the file linked above and may contain errors and inconsistencies.

For example, the general industrial
machinery and vehicles sectors experienced near-parallel growth of domestic production (for both domestic and
foreign markets) and the domestic
market between 1969 and 1979_Production of specialized industry machinery and information-processing equipment expanded slightly faster than
their domestic market growth over
that period, while production of electrical equipment slightly lagged its
domestic market growth.
These variations are nevertheless
quite small compared to the growth
of the PDE market and the domestic
producers' share of that market. Only
when the dollar-dominated 1980s
are included, does domestic production consistently and substantially
lag domestic market growth. Indeed,
production more nearly paralleled
the growth of domestic producers'
share of the domestic market. In other
words, domestic producers were to
some extent successful in offsetting
losses in their domestic market with
gains in their foreign markets-until
the dollar's appreciation damaged
their world competitiveness in terms
of both imports and exports.
Although exports of domestically
produced capital goods continue to rise,
relative competitiveness of domestic
PDE producers has been declining
as evidenced by their declining share
of the world market? Rather than
capturing a larger share of the world
market, domestic producers have
merely ridden a rising wave of world

demand for capital goods. While the
largest proportion of exports has
gone to western European countries
(32 percent) and newly industrializing
countries (30 percent), only the latter
have been consistently increasing
their share of domestic exports since
1969. Domestic capital-goods producers seem to have been dependent
on strong growth in world demand,
particularly among newly industrializing countries, to offset their loss
of world market share.
While domestic capital-goods producers, for the most part, benefit
from trade, the trade patterns are not
encouraging for the years ahead.
Domestic producers most likely will
continue to lose their competitive
position in the world market. Even if
the dollar declines, market losses in
earlier years are unlikely to be reversed
easily. Regaining domestic market
share may be particularly difficult,
as auto and steel producers have
already discovered. As concerns about
quality of product and reliability of
service are resolved, price competition
intensifies, and many imports still
have the same labor-cost advantages
over domestically produced capital
goods that have troubled domestic steel
and auto producers. Once domestic
capital-goods buyers overcome the
threshold problems of finding reliable
trading partners, trade between the
partners could quickly expand.

u.s. Trade

nomic Discussion Paper II, U.S. Department of
Labor, Bureau of International Labor Affairs,
October 1980.

in Manufactured Goods: An Analysis
and Comparison of Various Indicators of Cornparative Advantage and Competitiveness;'
Eco-

Federal Reserve Bank of Cleveland
Research Department
P.O.Box 6387
Cleveland, OR 44101

Concluding Remarks
While the capital-goods industry is

still rightfully seen as one of the
strongest industries in the United
States, recent trends in capital formation raise concern about its potential for future growth. All three of
the capital-formation trends discussed
above have been detrimental to domestic capital-goods producers.
In some cases, such as the slowdown in capital formation, the trend
should not be considered irreversiblealthough some overbuilding of structures may have occurred in recent
years and may take a few years to
be absorbed. The 1982-84 boom in
information-processing equipment is
an encouraging sign for producers
of equipment. However, part of that
strength was linked to an expansionary phase of the business cycle and
presumably will weaken as the economy itself loses steam, as appears
to be happening in late 1984 and
early 1985.
The overall growth of the equipment market and its changing composition are part of the economic
environment in which capital-goods
producers must operate, but over
which they have little direct control.
The gradual decline in international
competitiveness, on which they might
have some influence, has been a far
more worrisome trend. If the capitalgoods industry is to remain strong
in an increasingly global market,
domestic producers must be aggressive in preserving their technological
leadership and in finding new ways
to expand their share of the world
market.

BULK RATE
U.S. Postage Paid
Cleveland, OR
Permit No. 385

Federal Reserve Bank of Cleveland

ISSN 0428·1276

ECONOMIC
COMMENTARY
Capital formation in the United States
has undergone dramatic changes since
the 1960s, particularly for domestic
capital-goods producers. Two of many
(often related) trends are the overall
slowdown in capital formation and
the shift in the mix of capital goods
being formed. A third major trend,
only recently gaining prominence, is
the expanding penetration of imported
capital goods into domestic capitalgoods markets.
Put in the perspective of domestic
capital-goods producers, capital goods
have not been experiencing the amount
of growth that they had in the early
post-World War II years, primarily
due to less construction of offices and
factories. However, even in some sectors of the equipment market, such
as the "traditional" goods-producing
machinery, demand has been diminishing. And now, to compound these
problems, domestic producers in virtually all sectors of the equipment
market are facing stiff foreign competition.
In this Economic Commentary, we
review the reasons for these three
trends in capital formation in order
to understand the extent to which
they represent long-term threats to
the future of the domestic capitalgoods industry.
Capital Formation Slowdown
Despite some concern that the nation
is deindustrializing, our stock of capital has not actually been shrinking.

Address Correction Requested: Please send
corrected mailing label to the Federal Reserve
Bank of Cleveland, Research Department,
P.O. Box 6387, Cleveland, OH 4410L

June 15, 1985

Robert H. Schnorbus is an economist at the Federal
Reserve Bank of Cleveland. The author would like
to thank Roger H. Hinderliter for his thoughtful
comments.
The views expressed herein are those of the author
and not necessarily those of the Federal Reserve
Bank of Cleveland or of the Board of Governors of
the Federal Reserve System.

Major Trends in
Capital Formation
by Robert H. Schnorbus

However, the overall growth of capital.
stock has slowed during the recessionprone 1970s and early 1980s as economic growth in general slowed.
Growth of capital stock, measured
by the average annual growth rate of
real gross business fixed investment,
declined from 4.8 percent during
the 1960s to 3.8 percent in the 1970s
and early 1980s.1 Much of the weakness until recently was concentrated
in all structures, especially factories
as opposed to office buildings.
Growth of producers' durable
equipment (PDE) spending was much
more stable (falling marginally from
5.5 percent in the 1960s to 5.3 percent in the 1970s), but then also weakened (4.1percent) in the early 1980s.
Although the growth of equipment
capital has outperformed structures,
domestic equipment producers have
not been able to take full advantage of
that better performance because of
rising imports, which will be discussed later.
The slowdown in the growth of capital stock primarily has two sourcesone reflects the sluggishness of the
national economy, rather than the
"deindustrialization" of the economy,
as is often alleged, and the other reflects the changing composition of capital goods? To begin with, durable
goods are particularly sensitive to the
business cycle. There were two backto-back recessions in the early 1970s
and the 1980s, but only one mild recession during the 1960s. Moreover, both
the 1973-75 recession and the 1982-83

recession broke post-Great Depression records for severity. The sluggishness of the economy is also evident in the steadily rising ratio of net
capital stock to gross domestic product from 0.73 in 1962 to 0.82 in 1983.
Net capital stock was expanding nipidly in the 1960s (6.0 percent between
1962 and 1971), but has slowed by
nearly a third in the 1970s and early
1980s, as growth in gross domestic
product slowed from 4.5 percent in
the 1960s to 3.8 percent in the 1970s
and early 1980s. The rising ratio,
could, therefore, imply that the economy has not been growing fast enough
to sustain earlier rates of capital
formation.
The deindustrialization issue is,
therefore, overemphasized.' Although
the manufacturing sector is not growing as fast as other sectors of the economy, its absolute size (including output, capital stock and, until recently,
employment) is expanding. Continuation of the slowing trend in capital
formation during the 1980s will depend, in large part, on how long the
current economic expansion continues.
Until this year, the expansion has displayed record PDE spending, which
has been largely associated with the
so-called computer revolution.
Another important source of the
capital formation slowdown has been
the shift from structures to relatively
short-lived producers' durable equipment. This shift, in effect, decreased
the growth rate of capital formation by
increasing its average depreciation

L To avoid distortions associated with different
phases of the business cycle, growth rates were
calculated between the years just preceding a
peak year. The growth rates representing the
1960s were computed between 1957 and 1969
and for the 1970s, 1969 and 1979. For the final
period, 1979-84, the end year was the latest data
available and was the second year of an exceptionally robust economic expansion. If the current

expansion continues through 1985, the cornparison for the 1979-84 period may understate the
strength of PDE growth. Based on a recent Data
Resources, Inc. forecast for 1985, however, real
PDE growth during this period would still show
a slowing (4.7 percent) from previous periods. See
Review of the U.S. Economy, Data Resources, Inc.,
May 1985.

rate, that is, the rate at which the
existing capital stock was written off
for depreciation purposes,'
Equipment's share of total investment rose from a low of 55 percent
in 1962 to roughly 70 percent in 1978
before flattening out. The Revenue
Act of 1962 began the trend by establishing a tax structure that favored
investment in equipment over structures. Other government regulations
in the 1960s mandated capital expenditures on pollution-abatement equipment and other such protections to
the environment.
During the 1970s, accelerating inflation made short-term investments
with quick pay-offs highly desirable
and long-range investments risky.
Box 1

The Shift in PDE Spending
Demand has not been changing uniformly across all types of PDE, even
during the current expansion. As
recently as 1970, traditional capital
equipment, including vehicles, general industrial machinery, and specialized industry machinery, held about
65 percent of the domestic PDE market (see box).
By 1984, their market share had
fallen to 42 percent. Indeed, by 1984
the "high-tech" capital goods, identified most closely with informationprocessing (including computers) and
electrical equipment, had supplanted
traditional capital goods with nearly
60 percent of the total PDE market.

Composition of Major Sectors of Producers'

The five sectors of the capital-goods market discussed in this article were intended to separate
distinct groups. particularly high technology
products. from more traditional products. A sector may contain an odd mixture of products. such
as service industry machinery in information pro-

Durable Equipment

cessing equipment. however. because of differences in the way data are aggregated by the different data services. The sectors are based on the
components of PDE spending in the National Income Accounts as presented in tables 5.6 and 5.7
of the Survey 0/ Current Business.

tighter control of orders, shipments,
and inventories was made possible
by more efficient storage and organization of information.
More recently, computer technology has substantially increased the
potential for direct managerial control of the production process itself?
Machining centers and factory robots
are prime examples of the rising wave
of programmable manufacturing processes that are under the direct control of managers rather than skilled
laborers. Meanwhile, traditional capital-goods producers must contend
with the fact that much of the increase
in PDE spending will go to the hightech sectors. Traditional producers can
only expect thriving market growth
if they can link their product to new
technologies as, to some extent, has
been the case with machine tools and
robotics.

Imports and Equipment Spending
Traditional capital-goods producers
have bigger worries than losing their
share of PDE spending; they have
been steadily losing larger and larger
shares of their own domestic market
Specialized industry
to foreign producers. Surprisingly,
machinery
high-tech producers have also expeSpecial industry
rienced market-share erosion in
machinery, n.e.c.
Information processing
Agricultural machinery,
equipment
recent years.
except tractors
Office. computing. and
The loss of market shares to foreign
Construction machinery.
accounting machinery
producers
was perhaps unexpected
Service industry machinery
except tractors
Mining and oilfield machinery
Instruments
because the capital-goods industry
historically had been viewed as one
of America's strongest trade performAs a result, during the current ecoSome of the stimuli to the equipment
ers. The long-standing competitive
nomic expansion, capacity has been
market may have faded in the early
advantages of domestic PDE producstrained for many high-tech capital
1980s with the sharp decline in inflaers over foreign producers were shaped
tion. However, falling short-term inter- goods, while most traditional capital
goods have been burdened with exces- by the domestic industry's leadership
est rates relative to long-term rates,
in such areas as research, innovation,
new tax incentives (i.e., accelerated
sive capacity/
and quality of the work force? Net
The shift in the mix of investment
depreciation), and the need to modernize capital stock to compete against within the PDE market reflects a dra- exports of producers' durable equipment reached a peak in 1974,and
matic change in the control of largeforeign competition has contributed
began a sharp decline after 1980, as
scale enterprises and in the producto a rise in PDE's share of total capiimports'
share of the domestic market
tion
process
itself
(i.e.,
a
shift
from
tal spending
during
the
current
eco.
.
rose from 8 percent in 1970 to 26 perhuman labor to robots). The sharp
nOmIC expansion.
cent in 1984. Penetration varied
decline in the real cost of computers
during the 1970s made the technolog- among sectors in 1984, ranging from
14 percent in vehicles to 39 percent in
ical advances that they offer more
commercially accessible. As a result,
General industrial
machinery
General industrial equipment
Metalworking machinery
Engines and turbines

Vehicles
Trucks, buses, and
truck trailers
Autos
Aircraft
Ships and boats
Railroad equipment
Tractors

2. For a detailed discussion of the causes of the
capital formation slowdown, see Dana Johnson,
"Capital Formation in the United States: the
Postwar Perspective;' Public Policy and Capital
Formation. Washington, DC: Board of Governors
of the Federal Reserve System. April 1981.
pp.47-58.

Electronic apparatus
Electrical and communication equipment
Electrical transmission. distribution. and industrial
apparatus
Communication equipment
Electrical equipment, n.e.c.

3. A lucid debunking of the myths of deindustrialization is contained in Robert Z. Lawrence. Can
America Compete? Washington. DC: The Brookings Institution. 1984.
4. Average service life of newly purchased PDE
fell 7 percent between 1962 and 1977 to an average
of 11.9 years. Since then, the rising share of office
machinery. which has an average service life of
eight years, has further reduced the average life
of total PDE.

5. A notable exception to this statement among
high-tech products is the computer industry.
which currently appears to have excess capacity.
The problem might be a temporary difficulty in
keeping up with rapid technological changes and
need for restructuring, however. rather than a
demand-related problem. In 1985, plant closings.
may have reduced much of the excess capacity
in the industry. See Randall Smith, "Computer

electrical equipment, but still represented substantial gains in each sector over 1970 import shares.
The most often-cited explanation for
the recent deterioration in net trade
of capital goods is the sharp appreciation of the dollar since mid-1980which,
relative to foreign currencies, has
made all domestic goods more expensive in the world market and imports
cheaper in the domestic market. During the 1970s, the dollar was generally
depreciating. Many exchange-market
analysts currently believe that the
dollar is overvalued and expect this
depreciation to return in the future.
If the dollar does depreciate, it will
help offset some of the competitive
advantage currently being enjoyed by
foreign producers.
Chart 1 Producers' Durable Equipment
Market with Foreign Trade
Billions of real dollars
140
130
120
110
100

ness of foreign producers is a more
serious threat than the dollar movements to domestic producers. Furthermore, recent research indicates
that the adjustment lag to declining
import prices of capital goods may last
as long as five yearsf Even a sudden
reversal in the dollar could mean several more years of intense foreign
competition.

The difference between domestic
producers' share of the domestic market and their total production represents the size of their foreign markets
(exports), as distinct from their home
market in any given year. The difference between the size of the domestic market and total domestic production represents the trade surplus
generated by these capital-goods pro-

Table 1 Market Growth of PDE with Trade Adjustments
Average annual rates
1969-1979

1979-1984

Domestic
market
(RPDE)

Domestic
production
for the
domestic
market
(RPDE-M)

Domestic
production
(RPDE-M+X)

Domestic
market
(RPDE)

Domestic
production
for the
domestic
market
(RPDE-M)

Total PDE
spending

5.4

4.3

5.5

4.4

1.8

2.0

Specialized
industry
machinery

3.1

2.3

3.4

-4.4

-5.2

-5.6

General
industrial
machinery

2.6

1.0

2.5

-4.0

-6.2

-5.4

Information
processing
equipment

11.4

10.5

12.0

13.7

9.3

10.4

Vehicles

3.9

3.0

4.0

1.3

1.1

0.7

Electrical
equipment

6.0

3.7

5.5

4.0

0.9

0.4

Domestic
production
(RPDE-M+X)

SOURCE:U.S. Department of Commerce. Bureau of EconomicAnalysis. Survey a/Current Business. various July
issues. Tables 5.6 and 5.7. and Table 3; and Bureau of the Census. Highlights 0/ U S. Merchandise Trade. December
issues. Tables 6 and 1·10.

90
80
Domesticproducers'
production for the
domestic market

1975
1980
NOTE: Data used to construct this chart are based
on the combined merchandise trade and PDE spendingdata for the fivesectors describedin the box.Other
definitions of the equipment market or other sources
of trade data may give slightly different levels.but the
trend should be unaffected.
SOURCE:U.S. Department of Commerce. Bureau of
EconomicAnalysis, Survey 0/ Current Business. various July issues. Tables 5.6 and 5.7. and Table 3; and
Bureau of the Census. Highlights 0/ U S. Merchandise
Trade. Decemberissues. Tables 6 and 1·10.

However, as indicated above,
imports were expanding long before
the dollar began its rise, which suggests that the increasing competitiveIndustry Called Ripe for Mergers;'
Journal, June 19. 1985.

Wall Street

6. For examples of extending management control
to daily plant operations, see Robert Harvey. "Computers in Manufacturing;'
Iron Age. March 15.
1985. For a history of the development of computer-controlled machine tools. see David F. Noble,
Forces 0/ Production. New York, NY: Alfred A.
Knopf. 1984.

Relationship of Market Growth
and International Trade
Imports are only part of the story concerning the impact of international
trade on domestic capital-goods producers. As net exporters, at least until
1984, domestic producers consistently
benefited from world trade.
By comparing three relationships,
chart 1 shows how both imports and
exports of capital goods affect domestic PDE producers: 1) the domestic
market (real PDE spending), 2) domestic PDE producers' share of that domestic market (PDE minus imports),
and 3) total domestic production (excluding changes in inventories) for
home and overseas markets (PDE
minus imports plus exports).

ducers. Consequently, as long as
domestic production is larger than
the domestic market, the domestic
industry benefits from trade. Only if
total domestic production drops below
the size of the domestic capital-goods
market could it be said that the domestic capital-goods industry was not
a net beneficiary from world trade.
Domestic production of PDE in total
has kept pace with the growth of the
domestic market between 1969 and
1979,even though imports were taking
a larger share of the domestic PDE
market, because export growth was
strong as well. This pattern has been
more or less true of all sectors, despite
a wide variation in domestic market
growth among sectors (see table 1).

7. For further discussion. see Thomas C. Lowinger,
"The Technology Factor and Export Performance of U.S. Manufacturing Industries;' Economic Inquiry. vol. 13, no. 2 (lune 1975).
pp.221-36.

9. The size of the world PDE market. usually
defined as total PDE exports of the largest (usually 18) capital-goods exporting nations. was not
computed for this study. Other research clearly
indicates. however. that the United States has
been losing its share of the world market because
of declining competitiveness. even though its exports have been growing. See. for example.
C. Michael Aho, Harry P. Bowen. and Joseph
Pelzman, "Assessing the Changing Structure of

8. See Irving B. Kravis, Robert E. Lipsey, and
Dennis M. Bushe, "Prices and Market Shares in
International Machinery Trade;' Working Paper
No. 521. National Bureau of Economic Research.
July 1980.

rate, that is, the rate at which the
existing capital stock was written off
for depreciation purposes,'
Equipment's share of total investment rose from a low of 55 percent
in 1962 to roughly 70 percent in 1978
before flattening out. The Revenue
Act of 1962 began the trend by establishing a tax structure that favored
investment in equipment over structures. Other government regulations
in the 1960s mandated capital expenditures on pollution-abatement equipment and other such protections to
the environment.
During the 1970s, accelerating inflation made short-term investments
with quick pay-offs highly desirable
and long-range investments risky.
Box 1

The Shift in PDE Spending
Demand has not been changing uniformly across all types of PDE, even
during the current expansion. As
recently as 1970, traditional capital
equipment, including vehicles, general industrial machinery, and specialized industry machinery, held about
65 percent of the domestic PDE market (see box).
By 1984, their market share had
fallen to 42 percent. Indeed, by 1984
the "high-tech" capital goods, identified most closely with informationprocessing (including computers) and
electrical equipment, had supplanted
traditional capital goods with nearly
60 percent of the total PDE market.

Composition of Major Sectors of Producers'

The five sectors of the capital-goods market discussed in this article were intended to separate
distinct groups. particularly high technology
products. from more traditional products. A sector may contain an odd mixture of products. such
as service industry machinery in information pro-

Durable Equipment

cessing equipment. however. because of differences in the way data are aggregated by the different data services. The sectors are based on the
components of PDE spending in the National Income Accounts as presented in tables 5.6 and 5.7
of the Survey 0/ Current Business.

tighter control of orders, shipments,
and inventories was made possible
by more efficient storage and organization of information.
More recently, computer technology has substantially increased the
potential for direct managerial control of the production process itself?
Machining centers and factory robots
are prime examples of the rising wave
of programmable manufacturing processes that are under the direct control of managers rather than skilled
laborers. Meanwhile, traditional capital-goods producers must contend
with the fact that much of the increase
in PDE spending will go to the hightech sectors. Traditional producers can
only expect thriving market growth
if they can link their product to new
technologies as, to some extent, has
been the case with machine tools and
robotics.

Imports and Equipment Spending
Traditional capital-goods producers
have bigger worries than losing their
share of PDE spending; they have
been steadily losing larger and larger
shares of their own domestic market
Specialized industry
to foreign producers. Surprisingly,
machinery
high-tech producers have also expeSpecial industry
rienced market-share erosion in
machinery, n.e.c.
Information processing
Agricultural machinery,
equipment
recent years.
except tractors
Office. computing. and
The loss of market shares to foreign
Construction machinery.
accounting machinery
producers
was perhaps unexpected
Service industry machinery
except tractors
Mining and oilfield machinery
Instruments
because the capital-goods industry
historically had been viewed as one
of America's strongest trade performAs a result, during the current ecoSome of the stimuli to the equipment
ers. The long-standing competitive
nomic expansion, capacity has been
market may have faded in the early
advantages of domestic PDE producstrained for many high-tech capital
1980s with the sharp decline in inflaers over foreign producers were shaped
tion. However, falling short-term inter- goods, while most traditional capital
goods have been burdened with exces- by the domestic industry's leadership
est rates relative to long-term rates,
in such areas as research, innovation,
new tax incentives (i.e., accelerated
sive capacity/
and quality of the work force? Net
The shift in the mix of investment
depreciation), and the need to modernize capital stock to compete against within the PDE market reflects a dra- exports of producers' durable equipment reached a peak in 1974,and
matic change in the control of largeforeign competition has contributed
began a sharp decline after 1980, as
scale enterprises and in the producto a rise in PDE's share of total capiimports'
share of the domestic market
tion
process
itself
(i.e.,
a
shift
from
tal spending
during
the
current
eco.
.
rose from 8 percent in 1970 to 26 perhuman labor to robots). The sharp
nOmIC expansion.
cent in 1984. Penetration varied
decline in the real cost of computers
during the 1970s made the technolog- among sectors in 1984, ranging from
14 percent in vehicles to 39 percent in
ical advances that they offer more
commercially accessible. As a result,
General industrial
machinery
General industrial equipment
Metalworking machinery
Engines and turbines

Vehicles
Trucks, buses, and
truck trailers
Autos
Aircraft
Ships and boats
Railroad equipment
Tractors

2. For a detailed discussion of the causes of the
capital formation slowdown, see Dana Johnson,
"Capital Formation in the United States: the
Postwar Perspective;' Public Policy and Capital
Formation. Washington, DC: Board of Governors
of the Federal Reserve System. April 1981.
pp.47-58.

Electronic apparatus
Electrical and communication equipment
Electrical transmission. distribution. and industrial
apparatus
Communication equipment
Electrical equipment, n.e.c.

3. A lucid debunking of the myths of deindustrialization is contained in Robert Z. Lawrence. Can
America Compete? Washington. DC: The Brookings Institution. 1984.
4. Average service life of newly purchased PDE
fell 7 percent between 1962 and 1977 to an average
of 11.9 years. Since then, the rising share of office
machinery. which has an average service life of
eight years, has further reduced the average life
of total PDE.

5. A notable exception to this statement among
high-tech products is the computer industry.
which currently appears to have excess capacity.
The problem might be a temporary difficulty in
keeping up with rapid technological changes and
need for restructuring, however. rather than a
demand-related problem. In 1985, plant closings.
may have reduced much of the excess capacity
in the industry. See Randall Smith, "Computer

electrical equipment, but still represented substantial gains in each sector over 1970 import shares.
The most often-cited explanation for
the recent deterioration in net trade
of capital goods is the sharp appreciation of the dollar since mid-1980which,
relative to foreign currencies, has
made all domestic goods more expensive in the world market and imports
cheaper in the domestic market. During the 1970s, the dollar was generally
depreciating. Many exchange-market
analysts currently believe that the
dollar is overvalued and expect this
depreciation to return in the future.
If the dollar does depreciate, it will
help offset some of the competitive
advantage currently being enjoyed by
foreign producers.
Chart 1 Producers' Durable Equipment
Market with Foreign Trade
Billions of real dollars
140
130
120
110
100

ness of foreign producers is a more
serious threat than the dollar movements to domestic producers. Furthermore, recent research indicates
that the adjustment lag to declining
import prices of capital goods may last
as long as five yearsf Even a sudden
reversal in the dollar could mean several more years of intense foreign
competition.

The difference between domestic
producers' share of the domestic market and their total production represents the size of their foreign markets
(exports), as distinct from their home
market in any given year. The difference between the size of the domestic market and total domestic production represents the trade surplus
generated by these capital-goods pro-

Table 1 Market Growth of PDE with Trade Adjustments
Average annual rates
1969-1979

1979-1984

Domestic
market
(RPDE)

Domestic
production
for the
domestic
market
(RPDE-M)

Domestic
production
(RPDE-M+X)

Domestic
market
(RPDE)

Domestic
production
for the
domestic
market
(RPDE-M)

Total PDE
spending

5.4

4.3

5.5

4.4

1.8

2.0

Specialized
industry
machinery

3.1

2.3

3.4

-4.4

-5.2

-5.6

General
industrial
machinery

2.6

1.0

2.5

-4.0

-6.2

-5.4

Information
processing
equipment

11.4

10.5

12.0

13.7

9.3

10.4

Vehicles

3.9

3.0

4.0

1.3

1.1

0.7

Electrical
equipment

6.0

3.7

5.5

4.0

0.9

0.4

Domestic
production
(RPDE-M+X)

SOURCE:U.S. Department of Commerce. Bureau of EconomicAnalysis. Survey a/Current Business. various July
issues. Tables 5.6 and 5.7. and Table 3; and Bureau of the Census. Highlights 0/ U S. Merchandise Trade. December
issues. Tables 6 and 1·10.

90
80
Domesticproducers'
production for the
domestic market

1975
1980
NOTE: Data used to construct this chart are based
on the combined merchandise trade and PDE spendingdata for the fivesectors describedin the box.Other
definitions of the equipment market or other sources
of trade data may give slightly different levels.but the
trend should be unaffected.
SOURCE:U.S. Department of Commerce. Bureau of
EconomicAnalysis, Survey 0/ Current Business. various July issues. Tables 5.6 and 5.7. and Table 3; and
Bureau of the Census. Highlights 0/ U S. Merchandise
Trade. Decemberissues. Tables 6 and 1·10.

However, as indicated above,
imports were expanding long before
the dollar began its rise, which suggests that the increasing competitiveIndustry Called Ripe for Mergers;'
Journal, June 19. 1985.

Wall Street

6. For examples of extending management control
to daily plant operations, see Robert Harvey. "Computers in Manufacturing;'
Iron Age. March 15.
1985. For a history of the development of computer-controlled machine tools. see David F. Noble,
Forces 0/ Production. New York, NY: Alfred A.
Knopf. 1984.

Relationship of Market Growth
and International Trade
Imports are only part of the story concerning the impact of international
trade on domestic capital-goods producers. As net exporters, at least until
1984, domestic producers consistently
benefited from world trade.
By comparing three relationships,
chart 1 shows how both imports and
exports of capital goods affect domestic PDE producers: 1) the domestic
market (real PDE spending), 2) domestic PDE producers' share of that domestic market (PDE minus imports),
and 3) total domestic production (excluding changes in inventories) for
home and overseas markets (PDE
minus imports plus exports).

ducers. Consequently, as long as
domestic production is larger than
the domestic market, the domestic
industry benefits from trade. Only if
total domestic production drops below
the size of the domestic capital-goods
market could it be said that the domestic capital-goods industry was not
a net beneficiary from world trade.
Domestic production of PDE in total
has kept pace with the growth of the
domestic market between 1969 and
1979,even though imports were taking
a larger share of the domestic PDE
market, because export growth was
strong as well. This pattern has been
more or less true of all sectors, despite
a wide variation in domestic market
growth among sectors (see table 1).

7. For further discussion. see Thomas C. Lowinger,
"The Technology Factor and Export Performance of U.S. Manufacturing Industries;' Economic Inquiry. vol. 13, no. 2 (lune 1975).
pp.221-36.

9. The size of the world PDE market. usually
defined as total PDE exports of the largest (usually 18) capital-goods exporting nations. was not
computed for this study. Other research clearly
indicates. however. that the United States has
been losing its share of the world market because
of declining competitiveness. even though its exports have been growing. See. for example.
C. Michael Aho, Harry P. Bowen. and Joseph
Pelzman, "Assessing the Changing Structure of

8. See Irving B. Kravis, Robert E. Lipsey, and
Dennis M. Bushe, "Prices and Market Shares in
International Machinery Trade;' Working Paper
No. 521. National Bureau of Economic Research.
July 1980.

For example, the general industrial
machinery and vehicles sectors experienced near-parallel growth of domestic production (for both domestic and
foreign markets) and the domestic
market between 1969 and 1979_Production of specialized industry machinery and information-processing equipment expanded slightly faster than
their domestic market growth over
that period, while production of electrical equipment slightly lagged its
domestic market growth.
These variations are nevertheless
quite small compared to the growth
of the PDE market and the domestic
producers' share of that market. Only
when the dollar-dominated 1980s
are included, does domestic production consistently and substantially
lag domestic market growth. Indeed,
production more nearly paralleled
the growth of domestic producers'
share of the domestic market. In other
words, domestic producers were to
some extent successful in offsetting
losses in their domestic market with
gains in their foreign markets-until
the dollar's appreciation damaged
their world competitiveness in terms
of both imports and exports.
Although exports of domestically
produced capital goods continue to rise,
relative competitiveness of domestic
PDE producers has been declining
as evidenced by their declining share
of the world market? Rather than
capturing a larger share of the world
market, domestic producers have
merely ridden a rising wave of world

demand for capital goods. While the
largest proportion of exports has
gone to western European countries
(32 percent) and newly industrializing
countries (30 percent), only the latter
have been consistently increasing
their share of domestic exports since
1969. Domestic capital-goods producers seem to have been dependent
on strong growth in world demand,
particularly among newly industrializing countries, to offset their loss
of world market share.
While domestic capital-goods producers, for the most part, benefit
from trade, the trade patterns are not
encouraging for the years ahead.
Domestic producers most likely will
continue to lose their competitive
position in the world market. Even if
the dollar declines, market losses in
earlier years are unlikely to be reversed
easily. Regaining domestic market
share may be particularly difficult,
as auto and steel producers have
already discovered. As concerns about
quality of product and reliability of
service are resolved, price competition
intensifies, and many imports still
have the same labor-cost advantages
over domestically produced capital
goods that have troubled domestic steel
and auto producers. Once domestic
capital-goods buyers overcome the
threshold problems of finding reliable
trading partners, trade between the
partners could quickly expand.

u.s. Trade

nomic Discussion Paper II, U.S. Department of
Labor, Bureau of International Labor Affairs,
October 1980.

in Manufactured Goods: An Analysis
and Comparison of Various Indicators of Cornparative Advantage and Competitiveness;'
Eco-

Federal Reserve Bank of Cleveland
Research Department
P.O.Box 6387
Cleveland, OR 44101

Concluding Remarks
While the capital-goods industry is

still rightfully seen as one of the
strongest industries in the United
States, recent trends in capital formation raise concern about its potential for future growth. All three of
the capital-formation trends discussed
above have been detrimental to domestic capital-goods producers.
In some cases, such as the slowdown in capital formation, the trend
should not be considered irreversiblealthough some overbuilding of structures may have occurred in recent
years and may take a few years to
be absorbed. The 1982-84 boom in
information-processing equipment is
an encouraging sign for producers
of equipment. However, part of that
strength was linked to an expansionary phase of the business cycle and
presumably will weaken as the economy itself loses steam, as appears
to be happening in late 1984 and
early 1985.
The overall growth of the equipment market and its changing composition are part of the economic
environment in which capital-goods
producers must operate, but over
which they have little direct control.
The gradual decline in international
competitiveness, on which they might
have some influence, has been a far
more worrisome trend. If the capitalgoods industry is to remain strong
in an increasingly global market,
domestic producers must be aggressive in preserving their technological
leadership and in finding new ways
to expand their share of the world
market.

BULK RATE
U.S. Postage Paid
Cleveland, OR
Permit No. 385

Federal Reserve Bank of Cleveland

ISSN 0428·1276

ECONOMIC
COMMENTARY
Capital formation in the United States
has undergone dramatic changes since
the 1960s, particularly for domestic
capital-goods producers. Two of many
(often related) trends are the overall
slowdown in capital formation and
the shift in the mix of capital goods
being formed. A third major trend,
only recently gaining prominence, is
the expanding penetration of imported
capital goods into domestic capitalgoods markets.
Put in the perspective of domestic
capital-goods producers, capital goods
have not been experiencing the amount
of growth that they had in the early
post-World War II years, primarily
due to less construction of offices and
factories. However, even in some sectors of the equipment market, such
as the "traditional" goods-producing
machinery, demand has been diminishing. And now, to compound these
problems, domestic producers in virtually all sectors of the equipment
market are facing stiff foreign competition.
In this Economic Commentary, we
review the reasons for these three
trends in capital formation in order
to understand the extent to which
they represent long-term threats to
the future of the domestic capitalgoods industry.
Capital Formation Slowdown
Despite some concern that the nation
is deindustrializing, our stock of capital has not actually been shrinking.

Address Correction Requested: Please send
corrected mailing label to the Federal Reserve
Bank of Cleveland, Research Department,
P.O. Box 6387, Cleveland, OH 4410L

June 15, 1985

Robert H. Schnorbus is an economist at the Federal
Reserve Bank of Cleveland. The author would like
to thank Roger H. Hinderliter for his thoughtful
comments.
The views expressed herein are those of the author
and not necessarily those of the Federal Reserve
Bank of Cleveland or of the Board of Governors of
the Federal Reserve System.

Major Trends in
Capital Formation
by Robert H. Schnorbus

However, the overall growth of capital.
stock has slowed during the recessionprone 1970s and early 1980s as economic growth in general slowed.
Growth of capital stock, measured
by the average annual growth rate of
real gross business fixed investment,
declined from 4.8 percent during
the 1960s to 3.8 percent in the 1970s
and early 1980s.1 Much of the weakness until recently was concentrated
in all structures, especially factories
as opposed to office buildings.
Growth of producers' durable
equipment (PDE) spending was much
more stable (falling marginally from
5.5 percent in the 1960s to 5.3 percent in the 1970s), but then also weakened (4.1percent) in the early 1980s.
Although the growth of equipment
capital has outperformed structures,
domestic equipment producers have
not been able to take full advantage of
that better performance because of
rising imports, which will be discussed later.
The slowdown in the growth of capital stock primarily has two sourcesone reflects the sluggishness of the
national economy, rather than the
"deindustrialization" of the economy,
as is often alleged, and the other reflects the changing composition of capital goods? To begin with, durable
goods are particularly sensitive to the
business cycle. There were two backto-back recessions in the early 1970s
and the 1980s, but only one mild recession during the 1960s. Moreover, both
the 1973-75 recession and the 1982-83

recession broke post-Great Depression records for severity. The sluggishness of the economy is also evident in the steadily rising ratio of net
capital stock to gross domestic product from 0.73 in 1962 to 0.82 in 1983.
Net capital stock was expanding nipidly in the 1960s (6.0 percent between
1962 and 1971), but has slowed by
nearly a third in the 1970s and early
1980s, as growth in gross domestic
product slowed from 4.5 percent in
the 1960s to 3.8 percent in the 1970s
and early 1980s. The rising ratio,
could, therefore, imply that the economy has not been growing fast enough
to sustain earlier rates of capital
formation.
The deindustrialization issue is,
therefore, overemphasized.' Although
the manufacturing sector is not growing as fast as other sectors of the economy, its absolute size (including output, capital stock and, until recently,
employment) is expanding. Continuation of the slowing trend in capital
formation during the 1980s will depend, in large part, on how long the
current economic expansion continues.
Until this year, the expansion has displayed record PDE spending, which
has been largely associated with the
so-called computer revolution.
Another important source of the
capital formation slowdown has been
the shift from structures to relatively
short-lived producers' durable equipment. This shift, in effect, decreased
the growth rate of capital formation by
increasing its average depreciation

L To avoid distortions associated with different
phases of the business cycle, growth rates were
calculated between the years just preceding a
peak year. The growth rates representing the
1960s were computed between 1957 and 1969
and for the 1970s, 1969 and 1979. For the final
period, 1979-84, the end year was the latest data
available and was the second year of an exceptionally robust economic expansion. If the current

expansion continues through 1985, the cornparison for the 1979-84 period may understate the
strength of PDE growth. Based on a recent Data
Resources, Inc. forecast for 1985, however, real
PDE growth during this period would still show
a slowing (4.7 percent) from previous periods. See
Review of the U.S. Economy, Data Resources, Inc.,
May 1985.